Journal of the Korean Physical Society, Vol. 44, No. 3, March 2004, pp. 672∼676 Effects of Smartness, Preferential Attachment and Variable Number of Agents on Herd Behavior in Financial Markets Sungmin Lee Department of Physics and Research Institute of Basic Sciences, Kyung Hee University, Seoul 130-701 Yup Kim∗ Department of Physics and Research Institute of Basic Sciences, Kyung Hee University, Seoul 130-701 and Korea Institute for Advanced Study, Seoul 130-722 (Received 8 October 2003) We study the effects of various factors on stochastic formation of opinion clusters, modelled by an evolving network, and herd behaviors in financial markets. The first factor considered is the smartness of an agent, such that the agent does not choose a linking partner from among members of the same cluster to which the agent belongs. The second factor is preferential attachment, such that a larger linking probability is assigned to a partner with more assigned links. The third factor considered is the variation of the number of agents in the market. It is found that smartness and preferential attachment enhance the herd behavior in a market with a fixed number of agents. In a market with a variable number of agents, we find two characteristic herding behaviors. In a market with a relatively low average number of agents, we find a relative increase in the probability of relatively small returns. In a market with a relatively large average number of agents, we find nearly the same behavior as with a fixed number of agents. PACS numbers: 05.65.+b, 05.45.Tp, 87.23.Ge, 02.50.Le Keywords: Herd behavior, Financial crashes, Financial markets, Price return posed a model for opinion cluster formation and information dispersal by agents in a random network. In this model, they considered a random dispersion of information, agents sharing the same information from a group that makes decisions as a whole, and, whenever a group performs an action, the network necessarily adapts to this change. When the information dispersion is much faster than trading activity in the model, the distribution of the number of agents sharing the same information shows a power law in which the distribution of return shows a power-law decay and an exponential cutoff. On the other hand, when the dispersion of information becomes slower, a smooth transition to truncated exponential tails and a relative increase in the probability of extremely high returns are proved. The relative increase in the probability of return is argued to be the signal for ‘financial crashes’ [11]. Even though the EZ model explained many important characteristics of financial markets rather well, the model missed some key factors in the real markets. In their model, the number of agents is fixed. In contrast, the number of agents is variable, because participating agents can leave the market or new agents can participate in the market. When the opinion cluster is formed in the EZ model, the randomly selected agent is linked to other randomly chosen agent without considering the I. INTRODUCTION Recently, there have been various studies in order to understand economical and social phenomena based on physical methods [1–5]. Similar characteristics have been found between financial markets and physical systems with a large number of interacting units, such as the existence of long-term volatility correlation [2, 3, 6], the fast decay of linear correlation [7], fat tails in the distribution of price change [2,3,7,8], switching from one strategy group to another [9], and mutual interactions among market participants through herding and imitation behaviors [8, 10]. Among such studies, there have been many interesting studies on the analysis of price change [8, 10–13]. Especially, the phenomena that the distribution of return R and the logarithmic change of the market price have enhanced tails larger than in a Gaussian distribution have drawn much attention. For the fat tail distribution, several microscopic models have been suggested, such as the dynamic multiagent model [14,15], the herd behavior model [11–13,16], a static percolation model [10] and a self-organized model [17]. Recently, Eguiluz and Zimmermann [EZ] [11] pro∗ Corresponding Author Email: [email protected] -672- Effects of Smartness, Preferential Attachment· · · – Sungmin Lee and Yup Kim -673- specific properties of the agent. However, an agent in the real market should have an inclination not to be linked to any other member in the same opinion cluster to which the agent belongs. Furthermore, an agent should want to link with an other agent with greater information power (or more links). In this paper, we therefore make modified EZ models in which the key factors missed in the EZ model are included. We also aim to see how differently these modified models explain the characteristics of herding behaviors, as compared with the original EZ model. II. MODIFIED MODELS WITH THE NUMBER OF AGENTS FIXED In this section, we introduce modified models in which the specific properties of the agent mentioned in Section I are considered. Here, we think only models with the number of agents fixed. The specific properties considered are the following two factors. The first is that an agent selects the linking partner only from among those who are not a member of the same opinion cluster to which the selecting agent belongs. From now on, we will call such an agent a smart agent. In contrast, we call an agent who selects the linking partner without considering the clustering properties a normal agent. In the EZ model, only normal agents are considered. The second is related to the probability assignment of a selecting linking partner among those possible. The simplest one is random selection, i.e., to give equal probability to each possible partner, as in the EZ model. The other possibility, which considers the information power or number of links, is to assign the probability in proportion to the links which the partner already has. Let us assume a number of possible linking partners Np (t) and a number of links of some partner i Li (t) at a certain time t. Then, the linking probability Pi (t) of an agent to the partner i can be assigned as Pi (t) = Li (t)/ Np X Lj (t). (1) j=1 The assignment in Eq. (1) is called the preferential attachment in the recently-developed complex network theories [18–20]. Now, we will describe our modified model with a fixed number of agents in detail. A market is composed of N agents. There are three states Φl of each agent: an inactive state is Φl = 0 (waiting) and an active state is either Φl = +1 (buying) or Φl = −1 (selling). Initially, all the agents are waiting and have no links [11]. A network of links among agents evolves dynamically in the following way: at each time step ti (I) first an agent k is randomly selected. (II) Next, with probability (1 − a), the agent k chooses a linking partner and makes a link between them. If k is a smart agent, then the possible partners are the Fig. 1. Log-log plot of the distribution P (R) against return R for a modified EZ model with only smart agents and preferential selection. The plot is for N = 1000 and a = 0.01. The inset is the same plot for a = 0.20. The solid lines represent the relation P (R) ' R−α with α = 1.6. agents who are not members of the cluster to which the agent k belongs. If k is a normal agent, possible partners are all the other N − 1 agents in the market. The probability of choice of a partner from among possible ones can be assigned either preferentially or randomly. During the linking process, the chosen agent remains inactive (Φk = 0). (III) With probability a, the state of k becomes active by randomly choosing the state +1 or −1, and all other agents who are in the same cluster as k follow the same action. The aggregate state of the marP ket si = s(ti ) = j=1,N Φj is measured. Then all the agents in the active cluster become isolated with no links and inactive. From s(ti ) we get the time series data of prices similar to price index data in real markets. We follow the evolution of price P (ti ) introduced in Ref. 21 as P (ti+1 ) = P (ti ) exp(si /λ) , (2) where λ is a parameter which controls the size of the updates and provides a measure of the liquidity of the market [11]. We set λ = 50000 as in Ref. 11. The price return R(ti ), the logarithmic change of the market price, is defined as R(ti ) = ln[P (ti+1 )] − ln[P (ti )] . (3) To see the effects of smartness and preferential attachment, we obtain the time series of s(ti ) and R(ti ) for our modified models by simulations. The simulations are performed for the number of agents N = 100, 1000, 10000 and for various values of a. In Fig. 1 we show the distribution P (R) of price return R for the modified model with only smart agents and preferential selection. At a = 0.01 this shows ‘financial crashes’: a relative increase in the probability of high returns is observed. There is a critical value a∗ which varies with the kind of agent and the method of selection. For a < a∗ , ‘financial crashes’ -674- Journal of the Korean Physical Society, Vol. 44, No. 3, March 2004 Fig. 2. Plot of critical value a∗ against the number N of agents. NR means the model with normal agents and random selection. NP means the model with normal agents and preferential selection. SR means that with smart agents and random selection. SP means that with smart agents and preferential selection. a∗ ’s are estimated for N = 100, 1000, 10000. The doted line represents the relation a∗ (N ) = a∗o + A exp(−N/No ) with a∗o = 0.042, A = 0.259 and No = 4.488 ∗ 102 . The solid lines between data points are obtained by simple interpolations. This figure can also be the estimated phase diagram for the crash-possible phase and the no-crash phase. occur in P (R) as in Fig. 1. For a > a∗ , P (R) shows a power-law decay and an exponential cutoff as in the inset of Fig. 1. The solid lines in Fig. 2 show a power law R−α with exponent α = 1.6. Note that one can observe power-law decay in a range of returns, regardless of the relative increase in P (R). This result is consistent with Ref. 11. The exponent α does not change with or without preferential attachment. The distribution of returns is related to the distribution of clusters. If P (s), the probability distribution of clusters of size s, satisfies the power law P (s) ' s−β , then P (R) is equal to P (s) times the probability of choosing a given cluster that is proportional to s: P (R) ' R−α ' s ∗ s−β [11], but the effect of the preferential attachment is not enough to change the distribution of clusters, because all the agents in the active cluster become isolated with no links and inactive after trading. Only preferential attachment makes clusters grow effectively and rapidly. So the distribution of return shows the power law and crashes at relatively large a with preferential attachment. We estimate the critical value a∗ that is dependent upon the kind of agents and the method of selection for N = 100, 1000, 10000 (Fig. 2). The solid lines between data points are from simple interpolations. From this, we can estimate the phase diagram for the crash-possible phase (below the lines) and no-crash phase (above the lines). In Fig. 2 it is clearly seen that the effects of the difference between preferential selection and random selection exist, even for large N . In contrast, the effects of the difference between smart agents and normal agents become relatively weak as N increases. However, we can see from Fig. 2 that preferential selection and smartness enhance the herd behavior for financial crashes. For the estimation of a∗ in the limit N → ∞, we have tried to fit the best functional form to the data for the model with normal agents and random selection. The best functional form we obtained is a∗ (N ) = a∗o + A exp(−N/No ) with a∗o = 0.042, A = 0.259 and No = 4.488 ∗ 102 . From this functional form we can estimate a∗ (N → ∞) ' a∗o (6= 0). This result means that the crash-possible phase still exists in the limit N → ∞ for the model with normal agents and random selection. This kind of estimation for a∗ (N → ∞) is possible for other models, and thus the crash-possible phase should exist in the limit N → ∞. III. MODIFIED MODELS WITH A VARIABLE NUMBER OF AGENTS In this section, we consider the effects of variation of the number of agents. For the sake of simplicity, it is assumed that one new agent at a time can participate in the market and all active agents leave the market after trading. The details of the modified model with a variable number of agents are as follows: at each time step ti (I) with probability q, a new agent participates in the market. (II) With (1 − q), an agent k in the market is selected at random. (III) With probability (1 − a), the agent k chooses a linking partner and makes a link between them. Of course, k can be either a smart agent or a normal agent. The probability of choice of a partner among possible ones can be assigned either preferentially or randomly as in the models in Section II. During the linking process, the chosen agent remains inactive (Φk = 0). (IV) With a, the state of k becomes active by randomly choosing the state +1 or −1, and all the agents who are in the same cluster as k follow the same action. P The aggregate state of the market si = s(ti ) = j=1,N Φj is measured. Then, all active agents leave the market. By the process (I), the number of agents in the market increases. In contrast, the number decreases by the process (IV). For small q, we can expect that the volume of trading or si is small. The reason is that the expected average number of agents in the market is small, and then the size of the opinion cluster is also small. The typical herding behavior for small q (q = 0.1) is shown in Fig. 3. For small q and large a, any opinion cluster among the relatively small average number of agents cannot grow enough to show herding behavior. That is why P (R) for a = 0.3 decreases monotonically with R (See the inset of Fig. 3). Furthermore, P (R) for small q and large a manifests exponential decay as P (R) = A exp(−R/Ro ) as shown in the inset of Fig. 3. The exponential decay behavior for small q is somewhat peculiar, compared to Effects of Smartness, Preferential Attachment· · · – Sungmin Lee and Yup Kim Fig. 3. Log-log plot of P (R) against R for q = 0.1 and a = 0.0005. Symbols for the data points are the same as those in Fig. 2. The inset is the semi-log plot of P (R) against R for q = 0.1 and a = 0.3. The solid line in the inset represents the relation P (R) = A exp(−R/R0 ) with A = 0.4 and R0 = 1.4 × 10−5 . Fig. 4. Log-log plot of P (R) against R for q = 0.5 and a = 0.01. The inset is the same plot for a = 0.3. The solid line of the inset represents the relation P (R) ' R−α with α = 1.5. the power-law behavior (Fig. 1) for the models with a fixed number of agents. In contrast, the herding behavior for small q and small a is completely different from that for small q and large a. The typical behavior for small q and small a (a = 0.0005) is shown in Fig. 3. The relative increase of P (R) occurs for relatively small R as in Fig. 3, which should be some kind of signal of a deeplycorrelated herding behavior in a small group of agents. This kind of behavior can be expected from the fact that information sharing occurs frequently for the small average number of agents and the opinion cluster can grow almost maximally to show the deeply-correlated herding behavior. As can be seen in Fig. 3, the effects of the smartness and the preferential attachment on P (R) are negligible for large R, even though the effects can be seen for small R. -675- For large q, we can expect the average number of agents in the market to be large enough to form a large opinion cluster. The volume of trading, or si , is also expected to be large. Typical behavior of P (R) for large q (q = 0.5) is shown in Fig. 4. The results for P (R) for large q are generally quite similar to those for the models with a fixed number of agents in Fig. 1. For small a (a = 0.01), this shows the relative increase in P (R) at high R. For large a (a = 0.3), P (R) shows a powerlaw decay as P (R) = R−α with α = 1.5. (See the inset of Fig. 4). The same power-law decay of P (R) exists for small a before the relative increase of P (R) appears. (See the main part of Fig. 4). In the main part of Fig. 4, we can also see that smartness enhances the relative increase of P (R) at high R, but preferential attachment does not seem to perform this crucial role. IV. SUMMARY AND DISCUSSION In the modified models with a fixed number of agents, it is found that preferential selection and smartness enhance the herd behavior, but the effects of the difference between smart agents and normal agents become relatively weak as N increases. In the model with a variable number of agents, we find two regimes. For small q, we find the behavior of exponential decay P (R) for large a and a relative increase in P (R) at relatively small R for small a. For large q, P (R) is nearly the same as that for the model with a fixed number of agents. As can be inferred from Figs. 3 and 4, the effects of smartness and preferential attachment are not so clear for the models with a variable number of agents. For clarity of the effects, we must estimate the phase diagram of the crash-possible phase and the no-crash phase in the q − a parameter space as in Fig. 2. The estimate of the phase diagram needs an enormously large computing time. So, we leave the estimate of the phase diagram for future studies. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This research was supported in part by Grant No. R01-2001-000-00025-0 from the Basic Research Program of KOSEF. REFERENCES [1] See, e.g., S. Moss de Oliveira, P. M. C. de Oliveira, and D. Stauffer, Evolution, Money, War and Computers (Teubner, Stuttgart-Leipzig, 1999). [2] J.-P. Bouchaud and M. Potters, Theory of Financial Risk (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2000). -676- Journal of the Korean Physical Society, Vol. 44, No. 3, March 2004 [3] R. Mantegna and H. E. Stanley, An Introduction to Econophysics : Correlations and Complexity in Finance (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1999). [4] Y. Kumagai, J. Korean Phys. Soc. 40, 1100 (2002). [5] Y. Nakajima, J. Korean Phys. Soc. 40, 1096 (2002). [6] J. D. Farmer, Computing in Science and Engineering 1, 26 (1999). [7] R. N. Mantegna and H. E. Stanley, Nature 376, 46 (1995). [8] For a recent empirical study of financial market indices, see, e.g., P. Gopikrishnan, V. Plerou, L. A. Nunes Amaral, M. Meyer and H. E. Stanley, Phys. Rev. E 60, 5305 (1999); and for individual companies see, e.g., V. Plerou, P. Gopikrishnan, L. A. Nunes Amaral, M. Meyer and H. E. Stanley, Phys. Rev. E 60, 6519 (1999), and references therein. [9] T.Lux, Appl. Financial Economics 6, 463 (1996). [10] R. Cont and J.P. Bouchaud, Macroeconomic Dynamics (in press) and e-print cond-mat/9712318. [11] V. M. Eguiluz and M. G. Zimmermann, Phys. Rev. Lett. 85, 5659 (2000). [12] R. Topol, Econ. J. 101, 768 (1991). [13] A. Bannerjee, Rev. Econ. Studies 60, 309 (1993). [14] T. Lux and M. Marchesi, Nature (London) 376, 46 (1999). [15] P. Bak, M. Paczuski and M. Shubik, Physica (Amsterdam) 246A, 430 (1997). [16] Y. Xie, B-H. Wang, H. Quan, W. Yang and P. M. Hui, Phys. Rev. E 65, 046130 (2002). [17] Z. F. Huang, Eur. Phys. J. B 16, 379 (2000). [18] S. N. Dorogovtsev, J. F. F. Mendes, Advances in Physics 51, 1079 (2002). [19] R. Albert and A. L. Barbasi, Rev. Mod. Phys. 74, 47 (2002). [20] H.-J. Kim, I.-M. Kim, Y. Lee and B. Kahng, J. Korean Phys. Soc. 40, 1105 (2002). [21] J. D. Farmer, e-print adap-org/9812005.
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz