Capital Taxes When Firms Face Real and Financial Frictions Jason DeBacker October 13, 2008 1 Introduction Taxes on capital take many forms. Most common are taxation of capital gains, corporate profits, and dividends payments. The choice of tax instrument can affect corporate investment policy and so, even if a government finds it optimal to tax capital, it still must choose among these tax instruments. Beyond taxes, investment policy is also affect by the real and financial frictions that firms face when undertaking investment. In the following analysis, I study how real and financial frictions interact with tax policy in an economy with heterogenous firms. My study has three main parts. First, I undertake some comparative statics, understanding how tax policy affects investment decisions when firms face various frictions. Second, I estimate several models of real and financial frictions and find the model that best fits the data on the dynamics of firms. Finally, I use the estimated model to evaluate the long run impact of several changes in tax policy. This paper relates to three well-established literatures. Firm dynamics have an extensive literature in both economics and finance. Economists have largely focused on the role of real frictions in explaining investment behavior (e.g. Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006)) whereas finance has tended towards the use of financial frictions to explain the behavior of firms (e.g. Hennessy and Whited (2005)). There has been strikingly little overlap between these two strands ( Cooley and Quadrini (2001), Cooper and Ejarque (2003) and Bayraktar, Sakellaris and Vermeulen (2005)). The typical finance paper takes financial frictions seriously, but typically assumes the real frictions are quadratic in nature to support Q theory based regressions. Economists often ignore financial frictions, but allow for more flexible specifications of real costs of adjustment. I will try to span these two literatures, allowing for real and financial frictions to affect firm dynamics. Allowing for both real and financial frictions is potentially important in the evaluation of tax policy. For example, with the quadratic costs of adjustment that are typically used in the finance literature, firms’ investment is less elastic with respect to current cash flows, so tax policy will not have a large effect on aggregate investment. The economics literature that cites the importance of non-convexitites in capital accumulation decisions (e.g. Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006)), on the other hand, finds that cash flow can be very important in investment behavior (e.g. Miao (2008)). Similarly, financial frictions can increase the importance of cash flow because external financing is more expensive. The following also related to the long public finance and macroeconomics literature on the aggregate effects of capital taxation. Important in public finance literature are the two views on dividend taxation. The “traditional view” is that the marginal source of funds for investment is new equity and the returns are used to pay dividends. This means that dividend taxes are going to affect investment decisions since a dividend tax cut will lower 1 the user cost of capital and thus raise investment. The “new” view suggests that firms use internal funds to finance investment and so don’t issue new equity. In this view, dividend taxes do not influence the investment decisions of firms. Poterba and Summers (1985) analyze dividend taxation in a dynamic model and find support for the traditional view. However, the empirical results have been mixed, as Desai and Goolsbee (2004) find support for the new view. The model in this paper will next both views. Depending on the firm’s capital stock and productivity, its marginal source of funds may be internal or external. In what follows, I first show adjustment costs interact with tax policy using calibrated models. Following this exercise, I will estimate the nature and size of the adjustment costs that firms face- both real costs and financial frictions. Using the estimated model, I will then conduct several policy experiments. The policy experiments will include the tax changes brought forth by the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (JGTRRA), which changes the rates of dividend and capital gains taxes. The paper is organized as follows. 2 Investment Behavior Non-convex adjustment costs result in investment “bursts” as firms try to spread the fixed costs of adjusting their capital stock over a large investment. Such burst are apparent in Figure 1, which shows the investment rate ( ki ) for firms in the Compustat North America files over the 1988-2007 period. Over 25% of the observations have an investment rate higher than 30%. 0 .02 Fraction .04 .06 Distribution of Investment Rates 0 .2 .4 Investment Rate .6 .8 Source: Compustat Figure 1: PDF of Investment 3 Model Following Gourio and Miao (2008), I will present a general equilibrium framework with which to analyze tax policy. Gourio and Miao (2008) show that the effects of dividend taxation are very different in the GE model versus a PE model. Below, I outline each part of the economy. 2 3.1 Households Households hold shares in firms and a risk free bond. They supply labor (inelastically perhaps). Households are not heterogenous. The presence of a rise free bond helps to price the shares. Households solve: max {Ct }∞ t=0 ∞ X β t U (Ct ) (3.1) t=0 subject to: Ct +bt+1 + Z Pt θt+1 dµt = Z [(1−τd )dt +Pt0 −τg (Pt0 −Pt−1 )]θt dµt+(1+(1−τi )rt )bt +(1−τi )wt L̄+Tt (3.2) 3.2 Firms Firms choose equity issuance and dividends to maximize firm value. Firms buy capital and hire labor. Firms face idiosyncratic shocks to productivity, which means that a decrease in a tax on dividends can help out by improving the allocative efficiency of investment. The firm’s problem is represented by the following Bellman Equation: V (k, z) = max ′ k ,d,s 1 1 − τd d−s+ E ′ V (k′ , z ′ ) 1 − τg 1 + r(1 − τi )/(1 − τg ) z |z (3.3) Subject to the following constraints: k′ + (1 − δ)k + ψ(k′ − (1 − δ)k)2 + d = (1 − τc )π(k, z, w) + τc δk + s 2k (3.4) d≥0 (3.5) s≥s ¯ (3.6) π(k, z, w) = max{F (k, l, z) − wl} (3.7) Where the profit function is given by: l≥0 3.3 Government Governments run a balanced budget transferring tax revenues from taxes on income, capital gains, dividends, and corporate profits. The Government Budget Constraint is: T = τc Z (π(k, z; w)−δk)µ(dk, dz)+τd Z d(k, z; w)µ(dk, dz)+τi wL̄−τg Z s(k, z; w)µ(dk, dz) (3.8) 3 Table 1: Common Parameters Parameter δ β αk αl ρ σz Value 0.095 0.971 0.611 0.351 0.797 0.211 The for households to purchase shares, the expected return on a share on holding equity must be the same as the return on holding risk free bonds. This is the no arbitrage condition that determines the asset market equilibrium. The after tax return on a bond is (1 − τi )r. The expected return on equity is given by: Rt = 1 0 Et [(1 − taud )dt+1 + (1 − taug )(Pt+1 − Pt )] Pt (3.9) Asset pricing equilibrium implies that (1 − τi )r = Rt . I’ll want to analyze the long run effects and so look at the steady state. Equilibrium: Stationary Recursive Competitive Equilibrium: • Stationary dist of firms. • Firms max given prices. • HH max given prices. • Goods market clears. • Labor market clears. Using a GE framework is important because of the feedback of wages dampens the effect of tax policy. E.g. lower dividend taxes increases the capital stock and so increase the marginal product of labor and thus the wage. The higher wage means lowers the marginal product of capital. FIGURE: Show policy function- esp one that show different financing regimes. 4 Effects of Tax policy When Frictions are Present Figures: show have investment change of 1% decrease in the dividend tax rate, cap gains tax rate, and corporate profits when change parameters of frictions (real quad costs, real fixed costs, financing fixed cost, financing variable cost). 5 Data I use annual firm level data from Compustat. All the variables are readily available from this dataset. I drop financial and regulated firms (SIC codes 4900-4999 and 6000-6999) and those with missing values for the important variables (dividends, equity issued, capital, earnings). I 4 Table 2: Tax Changes Model Decrease τc by 1% ∆C ∆I ∆T ∆I Decrease τd by 1% ∆C ∆T Decrease τg by 1% ∆C ∆I No Cost ψ ψ, φ0 ψ, φ0 , φ1 ψ, F ψ, F , φ0 ψ, F , φ0 , φ1 also drop firms with less than one million dollars of capital and those with less than two million dollars in assets to avoid rounding errors. I have about 80,000 firm-year observations for the 1988-2002 period. I use this period to calculate all the moments that I estimate the model with. Summary Stats... Say something about how dividends issued change after tax changes... Figure 5 shows the fractions of firms in the various financing regimes before and after the 2003 tax cuts. As Chetty and Saez (2005) find, dividend issuance increases. Also notable, us increase in equity issuance. The two of these together mean that less firms are liquidity constrained. .01 .02 .03 Ratio .04 .05 .06 Equity−Capital Ratio Ratio .04 .045 .05 .055 .06 .065 .07 .075 .08 Dividend−Capital Ratio 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 Year 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 1988 Source: Computstat 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 Year 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Source: Computstat (a) Dividend-Capital Ratio (b) Equity Issuance - Capital Ratio Earnings−Capital Ratio .25 .15 .3 .16 .17 .35 Ratio Ratio .4 .18 .19 .45 .2 .5 Investment−Capital Ratio 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 Year 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 1988 Source: Computstat 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 Year 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Source: Computstat (c) Investment - Capital Ratio (d) Earnings - Capital Ratio Figure 2: Aggregate Corporate Investment and Financing Behavior. Figure 5 shows the number of firms in different financing regimes. In the equity issuance regime, the marginal source of funds is new equity (corresponding to the traditional view) in the dividend distribution regime, the marginal source of funds is retained earnings 5 ∆T Table 3: Data Moments Variable Corr Investment and Profit Shocks Serial Corr Investment Rate Serial Corr New Equity Issues a1 a2 a3 a4 Compustat Value 0.244 0.555 0.155 0.277 0.009 2.491 -0.012 Std. Error (0.001) (0.003) (0.003) (0.044) (0.001) (0.036) (0.000) (corresponding tot he new view). Dividend Distribution Regime .15 .2 .34 .36 .38 Fraction of Firms .25 .3 .35 Fraction of Firms .4 .42 .44 .46 .48 .5 .4 Equity Issuance Regime 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 Year 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 1988 Source: Computstat 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 Year 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Source: Computstat (a) Equity Issuance Regime (b) Dividend Distribution Regime .22 .24 Fraction of Firms .26 .28 .3 .32 .34 .36 Liquidity Constrained Regime 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 Year 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Source: Computstat (c) Liquidity Constrained Regime Figure 3: Financing Regimes. 6 6.1 Estimation Estimation of the Profit Function and Productivity Process Profit functions imply linear regression models and are estimated by OLS with time and firm fixed effects. Assuming that F (k, l, z) = zkαk lαl then corporate profits are given by π(k, z; w) = 1 αl (1 − αl )(zkαk ) 1−αl ( αwl ) 1−αl . Taking the natural log of the profit function one can form the following: ln(πi,t ) = α0 + α1 ln(ki,t ) + α2 ηi,t 6 (6.1) Table 4: Parameters Estimated Outside SMM Parameter αk ρ σz Value 0.297 0.761 0.312 Std Error (0.001) (0.003) (0.001) Table 5: Calibrated Parameters Parameter β δ αl Value 0.971 0.095 0.65 The error term, ηit has a common component, bt and a firm-specific component, ei t. Thus ηi,t = bt + ei,t . Then the log profits function becomes: ln(πi,t ) = α0 + α1 ln(ki,t ) + b̃t + ẽi,t (6.2) αk Running the regression specified by Equation 6.2 identifies the parameter α1 = (1−α . l) I set αl equal to 0.65, following Gourio and Miao (2008). Thus I find that αk = 0.297. To find the AR(1) process that is technology, I fit an AR(1) to zit = (1 − αl )ẽi,t : zi,t = ρzi,t−1 + σui,t (6.3) I find that ρ̂=0.761 and σ̂=0.312. The rate of time preference and the rate of depreciation are calibrated. β = 0.971, δ = 0.095. Taxes are set to the statutory rate or are set for at a rate for some representative household. subsubsectionStructural Estimation After the estimating the profit function and the process for the idiosyncratic productivity shocks, I use a simulated method of moments procedure (SMM) to identify the parameters of the cost functions. The parameters Θ = (ψ, F, φ0 , φ1 ) are estimated using a simulated method of moments (SMM) approach as described in McFadden (1989). The choice of SMM is because estimation based off the Euler equations cannot be done with non-convex costs of adjustment and because firms transition between financing regimes, another non-continuity in the decision rules. SMM estimation has the following algorithm. Given the parameters of the profit function and productivity process and a vector Θ, the dynamic programming problem (DPP) of the firms is solved. The solution to the DPP is a set of policy functions determining the firm’s optimal choice of investment, dividend distribution and equity issuance given their productivity and capital stock. The policy functions are used to solve for the stationary distribution of firms over capital and productivity. From the stationary distribution, I calculate a set of moments. Call the vector of simulated moments Ψs (Θ). The estimate, Θ̂, is the vector of parameters that minimizes the weighted distance between Ψs (Θ) and the vector of moments from the data, Ψd . Formally, Θ̂ solves: £(Θ) = minΘ [Ψd − Ψs (Θ)]′ W [Ψd − Ψs (Θ)] 7 (6.4) Table 6: Data Versus Model Moments Model Data No Cost ψ ψ, φ0 ψ, φ0 , φ1 ψ, F ψ, F , φ0 ψ, F , φ0 , φ1 Corr Investment and Profit Shocks 0.244 Serial Corr Investment Rate 0.555 Serial Corr New Equity Issues 0.155 Where W is the optimal weighting matrix , calculated as the inverse of the variancecovariance matrix of the moments, following Gourieroux, Monfort and Renault (1993). The variance-covariance matrix is found by bootstrapping the moments from the data. Using the SMM procedure with the optimal weighting matrix ensures consistent and efficient estimates of Θ. 6.1.1 Moments and Identification Identification of the real frictions, ψ, F and the financial frictions, φ0 , φ1 is achieved by use of the following moments: the serial correlation of investment rates, the correlation between the investment rate and productivity, the serial correlation of equity issuance, and the coefficients a1 , a2 , a3 , a4 from the following regression: Regression of investment rate on profits and equity issuance: πit πit sit sit iit = a0 + a1 + a2 + a3 + a4 + δt + ǫit kit kit kit kit kit (6.5) The serial correlation of investment rates, helps to pin down both the size and nature of the real costs of adjustment. If the costs of adjustment are quadratic, firms will try to spread investment out over several periods, leading to a higher serial correlation of the investment rate. On the other hand, if non-convexities are present, firms will make large investments in a single period, leading to a low serial correlation. If the correlation between investment and productivity is high, this means that the quadratic costs of adjustment are low or that there are non-convexities in the costs of adjusting capital. The serial correlation of equity issuance is important in identifying the fixed costs involved in issuing equity. Finally, the regression coefficients further identify the costs parameters. a1 and a2 help to identify the real costs, while a3 and a4 help to identify the financial frictions. 7 Results of Estimation 8 Policy Experiments Change of JGTRRA. Graph of transition to steady state for capital stock, consump, etc Table with changes to investment and consumption in the long run from the div tax change Proposed changed by Obama and McCain. McCain- lower max corporate profit tax from 35% to 25%. Obama- increase max capital gains tax from 15% to 20%. 8 a1 0.277 a 0.0 Table 7: Parameter Estimates from SMM Model No Cost ψ ψ, φ0 ψ, φ0 , φ1 ψ, F ψ, F , φ0 ψ, F , φ0 , φ1 ψ 0 F 0 0 0 0 φ0 0 0 φ1 0 0 0 0 0 0 Table 8: 2003 Dividend Tax Cuts Aggregate Variable Investment Capital Consumption Tax Revenue Pre-2003 τg = 0.20, taud = 0.25 Post-2003 τg = 0.15, τ d = 0.15 Table 9: McCain and Obama Plans Aggregate Variable Investment Capital Consumption Tax Revenue Baseline (Post-2003) τg = 0.15, τ d = 0.15, τc = 0.34 9 McCain τg = 0.15, τ d = 0.15, τc = 0.25 Obama τg = 0.25, τ d = 0.15, τc = 0.34 9 Long Run Costs of Various Tax Policy MCPF with div, cap gains, corp profits. Revenue equal change better than div tax cut? Elasticity of investment to various taxes. Table with % changes in I, C, for change in various taxes 10 Conclusion References Bayraktar, Nihal, Plutarchos Sakellaris, and Philip Vermeulen, “Real Versus Financial Frictions to Capital Investment,” European Central Bank Working Paper, 2005. Chetty, Raj and Emmanuel Saez, “Dividend Taxes and Corporate Behavior: Evidence From the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 2005, 120 (3), 791–833. Cooley, Thomas and Vincenzo Quadrini, “Financial Markets and Firm Dynamics,” American Economic Review, 2001, 91 (5), 1286–1310. Cooper, Russell W. and João Ejarque, “Financial frictions and investment: requiem in Q,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 2003, 10, 710–728. and John C. Haltiwanger, “On the Nature of Capital Adjustment Costs,” Review of Economic Studies, 2006, 11, 611–633. Desai, Mihir A. and Austan D. Goolsbee, “Investment, Overhand, and Tax Policy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2004, 2, 285–338. Gourieroux, C., A. Monfort, and E. Renault, “Indirect Inference,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, December 1993, 8 (Supplement: Special Issue on Econometric Inference Using Simulation Techniques), S85–S118. Gourio, Francois and Jianjun Miao, “Firm Heterogeneity and the Long-Run Effects of Dividend Tax Reform,” Boston University, Mimeo, 2008. Hennessy, Christopher A. and Toni M. Whited, “Debt Dynamics,” Journal of Finance, June 2005, 3 (60), 1129–1165. McFadden, Daniel, “A Method of Simulted Moments for Estimation of Discrete Response Models Without Numerical Integration,” Econometrica, September 1989, 57 (5), 995– 1026. Miao, Jianjun, “Corporate Tax Policy and Long-Run Capital Formation: The Role of Irreversibility and Fixed Costs,” Boston University, Mimeo, 2008. Poterba, James M. and Lawrence H. Summers, “The Economic Effects of Dividend Taxation,” NBER Working Paper, 1985. 10
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz