OPERATIONS RESEARCH informs Vol. 56, No. 5, September–October 2008, pp. 1247–1255 issn 0030-364X eissn 1526-5463 08 5605 1247 ® doi 10.1287/opre.1080.0562 © 2008 INFORMS Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions for an Assortment Goker Aydin Department of Industrial and Operations Engineering, The University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109, [email protected] Evan L. Porteus Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Stanford, California 94305, [email protected] We seek optimal inventory levels and prices of multiple products in a given assortment in a newsvendor model (single period, stochastic demand) under price-based substitution, but not stockout-based substitution. We address a demand model involving multiplicative uncertainty, motivated by market share models often used in marketing. The pricing problem that arises is known not to be well behaved in the sense that, in its deterministic version, the objective function is not jointly quasi-concave in prices. However, we find that the objective function is still reasonably well behaved in the sense that there is a unique solution to the first-order conditions, and this solution is optimal for our problem. Subject classifications: inventory/production: multi-item, pricing, stochastic; marketing: choice models, pricing, retailing, wholesaling. Area of review: Manufacturing, Service, and Supply Chain Operations. History: Received October 2003; revisions received December 2005, December 2006; accepted August 2007. 1. Introduction much attention is the effect of pricing on customer substitution within a set of similar products.” Indeed, even in our simple single-period setting for an assortment, we do not know the kinds of demand models that lead to tractable problems. In this paper, we aim to fill some of this gap in the literature. The research on pricing decisions for an assortment has remained primarily within the domain of marketing and economics. The usual assumption made in this research is that demand is deterministic or that production is to order, and, therefore, there are no inventory decisions to make. For example, Anderson and de Palma (1992), Besanko et al. (1998), and Aydin and Ryan (2000) show that if the demands for competing products are given by the multinomial logit (MNL) demand model, then the profit of the firm is maximized when the firm uses the same profit margin for all products. Starting with van Ryzin and Mahajan (1999), who consider the assortment-planning problem in the presence of inventory considerations (for the case of fixed retail prices), the MNL model has found frequent use within the operations management literature, as a way of incorporating consumer choice into operational models. See, for example, Cachon et al. (2005), Cachon and Kok (2007), Aydin and Hausman (2008), and Hopp and Xu (2005). Our demand model covers the MNL-type demand model as a special case. Under our demand model, the demand for any given product depends on the attractiveness of each and every product in the assortment, and each product’s attractiveness is a function of its own price (in addition to what we loosely More often than not, consumers make purchasing decisions that require them to choose from an assortment of substitutable products, e.g., choosing a flavor and container size when buying ice cream or choosing from different accessory packages when buying an automobile. Of course, the prices of the products influence customer choice. Hence, the prices of products in an assortment influence not only the size of overall demand, but also how the demand will be allocated among the products, thereby driving the inventory decisions. Therefore, ideally, inventory and pricing decisions should be made jointly for the entire assortment. In this paper, we consider such a pricing and inventory problem for an assortment of substitutable products. In particular, we consider the price-dependent newsvendor problem for an assortment, where a single firm faces single-period, stochastic demands for multiple products that compete on price and must set the inventory levels and prices for those products at the beginning of the period. The pioneers of research on joint inventory and pricing decisions for a single product were Whitin (1955), Mills (1959), and Karlin and Carr (1962). Petruzzi and Dada (1999) review and extend the research stream on the single-product price-dependent newsvendor problem, and our paper builds on theirs by adding customer choice among multiple substitutable products. In a recent review of the literature on coordination of production and pricing decisions, Yano and Gilbert (2005, p. 96) state that an “important practical consideration that has not received 1247 1248 call “the quality of the product”); hence, the demand for any given product depends on the prices of all products in the assortment. This demand model is motivated by market share models, such as MNL and multiple competitive interactions (MCI) models (e.g., Urban 1969), that have been tested empirically and used extensively in the marketing literature. We establish that the price-dependent newsvendor problem for an assortment is well behaved under our demand model. Hanson and Martin (1996) consider the special case of our problem where demand is deterministic, and they construct an example in which the profit function is not jointly quasi-concave in prices, which suggests that finding the optimal prices may require sophisticated search techniques. In our setting, where demand is stochastic, the profit function is not jointly quasi-concave in prices and inventory levels either. Nevertheless, we show that, assuming that unmet demands become lost sales, our problem is well behaved in the sense that there is a unique vector of prices and inventory levels that satisfy the first-order conditions, and this vector is optimal for our problem. Hence, simple search techniques should be sufficient to find the optimal solution. In related research, Mahajan and van Ryzin (2001) and Netessine and Rudi (2003) address setting the inventory levels for a given assortment, allowing stockout-based substitution. We add selection of prices, but drop stockout-based substitution. In addition, there has been some work on the decentralized, competitive version of the problem we consider, where independent firms select the inventory and price of one product each. Bernstein and Federgruen (2005) consider the decentralized problem under price-based, but not stockout-based, substitution. Zhao and Atkins (2008) add stockout-based substitution, which is independent of prices, to the same problem, under additive uncertainty. Hopp and Xu (2008) use an approximation to model both price- and stockout-based substitution to analyze inventory, pricing, and assortment decisions in centralized and decentralized problems. Zhu and Thonemann (2002) consider a multiperiod inventory and pricing problem for two products, whereas we consider a single-period problem for an arbitrary number of products. They assume that the expected demand for each product is linear in prices. In addition, they assume that all unmet demand in a period is backlogged and the expected holding and shortage cost does not depend on the retail prices. In our single-period setting, where we assume all unmet demands become lost sales, any induced holding and shortage cost function would depend on the retail prices. A closely related work is by Maddah and Bish (2004), who also consider the price-dependent newsvendor problem for an assortment. In addition to inventory and pricing decisions, they address the question of assortment selection. Their demand model is based on a normal approximation of Poisson arrivals of customers, each of whom chooses one of the products in the assortment in accordance Aydin and Porteus: Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions for an Assortment Operations Research 56(5), pp. 1247–1255, © 2008 INFORMS with the MNL model. To alleviate some of the technical difficulties associated with the inventory and pricing problem, they work with an approximation to the expected profit of the firm, and obtain several insights into the assortmentplanning problem. We consider the assortment to be fixed, and do not approximate the objective function. In the next section, we describe the inventory and pricing problem for an assortment, and we discuss the demand model in detail. Section 3 characterizes the optimal solution and builds certain comparative statics. Finally, we conclude in §4 with a discussion of future research directions. 2. Inventory and Pricing Problem In our price-dependent newsvendor problem for an assortment, the firm orders and prices the products at the beginning of the period (selling season), and the stochastic demand for a product is a function of the prices of all products. Unmet demands become lost sales, and leftover inventory has no value. Our model is more suitable for fashion and seasonal items than it is for grocery staples where multiple replenishments and price adjustments take place over a long period of time. We also assume no stockout-based substitution: once a product runs out of stock, customers who prefer that product do not switch to another product, but simply buy nothing. This is admittedly a restrictive assumption because we would expect to see some demand for the out-of-stock product to spill over to the ones that are still in stock. However, we believe that it is useful to characterize the problem and its solution for the simpler case addressed in this paper before introducing stockout-based substitution as well as price-based substitution. 2.1. Problem Formulation Let pi denote the unit selling price and ci the unit procurement cost of product i. Throughout the remainder of the paper, let p = p1 pn denote the vector of prices and y = y1 yn the vector of stock levels. We define Di p to be the demand for product i given price vector p; i p x and i p x are, respectively, the cumulative distribution function (c.d.f.) and the probability density function (p.d.f.) of Di p. We assume that i p x is strictly increasing in x. Given a real-valued function f defined on Rn , we use i f p to denote the partial derivative of f with respect to the ith component of its argument evaluated at the point p. Similarly, ij2 f p and ii2 f p denote the cross-partial and second partial of f , respectively. The firm wishes to maximize the following: py = n Epi minDi pyi −ci yi i=1 = n i=1 pi yi 0 xi pxdx +yi 1−i pyi −ci yi (1) (2) Aydin and Porteus: Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions for an Assortment 1249 Operations Research 56(5), pp. 1247–1255, © 2008 INFORMS Because p y is separable and concave in the yi s, the optimal stock level for product i, yi∗ p, is given for each given price vector p as the usual critical fractile solution pi − ci pi i p yi∗ p = (3) and the firm’s problem can be rewritten as maximizing the following induced profit function (see, for example, Porteus 2002): p = n i=1 pi 0 yi∗ p xi p x dx (4) One question of interest is how the optimal stock levels depend on the set of prices used. In the traditional newsvendor model (with a single product whose stochastic demand does not depend on price), if the retail price increases, then the stock level will increase as well because a price increase causes the unit underage cost to increase. However, common intuition suggests that the product’s demand will decrease when its retail price increases, and it is not intuitively clear which of the two opposite effects, the increase in underage cost versus the decrease in demand, dominates. To address this question, we work with a rather general model, summarized by Assumptions (A1)–(A3) below. (We shall specialize the model shortly to address additional questions.) Assumption (A1). For each given p, Di p and Dj p are (statistically) independent for each i = j. Assumption (A2). There exists a strictly increasing c.d.f., , and for each i, a function ti p x such that i p x = ti p x i = 1 n. Furthermore, we assume that ti p x is strictly increasing in x. Assumptions (A1) and (A2) will hold, for example, when Di p = i pi + i p and the i s are independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) with c.d.f. . In such a case, ti p x = x − i p/i p. In this instance, i p and i p can be interpreted as scaling the market size for product i given the vector of selling prices, p, and i is a random perturbation of that potential market. Note that the additive and multiplicative demand models follow as special cases. The following assumption imposes a structure on how demand distributions change as prices change. Assumption (A3). For each i, ti p x > 0, i ti p x > 0, and j ti p x < 0 for j = i. Furthermore, ti p x is supermodular in each pi x; i.e., 2 ti p x/xpi 0. The first part of (A3) is equivalent to assuming that Di is stochastically decreasing in pi and stochastically increasing in pj . The second part says that ti p x becomes more sensitive to changes in price at higher demand levels. When Di = fi p + i , the second part of (A3) is readily satisfied. When Di = fi pi , it is satisfied if and only if fi p is decreasing in pi , which is a very reasonable assumption. When pi increases, Di stochastically decreases, which tends to decrease yi∗ p and the critical fractile of product i increases, which tends to increase yi∗ p. In general, we do not know which of these effects dominates. However, the following proposition states that if is IFR, then yi∗ p is decreasing in pi at price points that are candidates for an optimal solution. (Recall that a c.d.f. (of a nonnegative random variable) is IFR if its failure rate hx = x/1 − x is increasing in x. This property is satisfied by many distributions including the normal distribution and the Weibull distributions with shape parameter greater than one. For more, see, for example, Barlow and Proschan 1965.) Proposition 1. Suppose that p satisfies i p = 0. If Assumptions (A1)–(A3) hold and is IFR, then i yi∗ p < 0. This result is useful when dealing with joint inventory and pricing problems. For example, in the context of a singleproduct inventory and pricing problem, Aydin and Porteus (2008) use this result to analyze the effect of rebates on the supply chain. Unfortunately, as we briefly discuss in our conclusion section, if the general model satisfies only Assumptions (A1)–(A3), then the inventory and pricing problem has some behavioral abnormalities. To further analyze the inventory and pricing problem for an assortment, we will work with a more specific demand model, described in the next section. 2.2. The Demand Model This demand model, defined by Assumptions (B1)–(B5), is motivated by demand functions commonly used in marketing, as we will illustrate in §2.3. It satisfies Assumptions (A1)–(A3) as well. See Appendix B in the online supplement for a proof. An electronic companion to this paper is available as part of the online version that can be found at http://or.journal.informs.org/. Assumption (B1). Di p = !qi pi for i = 1 n, where i s are i.i.d. and nonnegative with c.d.f. that is IFR. Assumption (B1) says that the realized demand for a product is a multiplicative random perturbation of the expected demand given by !qi p. The use of multiplicative randomness implies that the coefficient of variation of the demand for each product is constant. If the coefficient of variation of demand changes with price, then multiplicative randomness may not be appropriate. Throughout the remainder of the paper, we assume without loss of generality (using normalization) that ! = 1 and E = 1, so that qi p can be interpreted as the expected demand for product i at price vector p. n Assumption (B2). qi p = vi pi /v0 + j=1 vj pj vi · 0 for i = 1 n. 1250 Given Assumption (B2), vi pi can be interpreted as a positive measure of the attractiveness of product i, and the expected demand for each product is proportional to the product’s attractiveness. Furthermore, v0 can be interpreted as the attractiveness of the no-purchase option. This model is in line with the Luce choice model (Luce 1959). Throughout the remainder of the paper, we normalize the value of v0 and let v0 = 1. Assumpton (B3). vi pi is strictly decreasing in pi . In light of the interpretation of vi pi offered above, Assumption (B3) says that the attractiveness of a product is decreasing in the product’s price. This assumption implies that qi p is decreasing in pi and increasing in pj for j = i, which can be interpreted as saying that the expected demand of product i is decreasing in its own price and increasing in the prices of other products. Assumption (B4). pi i pi /i pi −1, where i pi = vi pi /vi pi . This assumption is rather technical and not very restrictive. For example, the assumption is satisfied whenever vi pi is log-concave in pi , which allows a large set of choices for vi functions. As we illustrate in §2.3, this assumption is satisfied for at least two different demand functions commonly used in the marketing literature, without imposing any constraints on the parameter values of those functions, thereby allowing a large set of choices for own-price and cross-price elasticities of demand. Assumption (B5). limpi → vi pi = 0, limpi → pi vi pi = 0, limpi → i pi > − , and Ei < for i = 1 n. This technical assumption guarantees that the expected demand is finite and a product’s contribution becomes zero as its price becomes arbitrarily large. Next, we discuss a number of attractive examples of the demand model specified by Assumptions (B1)–(B5). 2.3. Special Cases of the Demand Model Assumptions (B3)–(B5) govern the relationship between the price and the attractiveness of a product. The attractiveness functions of all products then combine, as specified by (B2), to determine qi p, the expected demand of product i. Although Assumptions (B2)–(B5) may seem restrictive, they are satisfied by two forms of demand functions used commonly in the marketing and economics literature, the logit demand function (based on the multinomial logit (MNL) consumer choice model) and the multiplicative competitive interactions (MCI) demand function. Below we state the attractiveness functions, i.e., vi pi s, that correspond to the logit and MCI demand functions. In addition, we offer a third form for vi pi that satisfies our assumptions, which is a plausible way of modeling a consumer population with multiple customer segments. See Appendix B in the online supplement for a proof that the following models satisfy Assumptions (B3)–(B5). Aydin and Porteus: Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions for an Assortment Operations Research 56(5), pp. 1247–1255, © 2008 INFORMS (D1) Logit Demand vi pi = exp$i − pi $i > 0 i = 1 n This demand function is based on the MNL consumer choice model used extensively in marketing. (See, for example, Guadagni and Little 1983.) Under the MNL model, the stochastic surplus of a customer for product i is given by $i − pi + %i , where $i can be interpreted as the customer’s expected utility for product i and %i is a Gumbel error term with shape parameter one. Then, with vi pi as defined by (D1), qi p gives the probability that a consumersurplus-maximizing individual will choose product i (out of all n products), which we treat as the expected demand for product i. For a detailed discussion of the use of consumer choice models in inventory management and their limitations, see van Ryzin and Mahajan (1998). (D2) MCI Demand −&i vi pi = $i pi $i > 0 &i > 1 i = 1 n Here, $i can be loosely interpreted as the quality of product i and &i as a measure of the consumer population’s price sensitivity for product i. The MCI demand function has been used extensively in the marketing literature to model market shares. See, for example, Urban (1969), who offers MCI demand as a model of market shares in dealing with product-line decisions. Nakanishi and Cooper (1974) discuss parameter estimation for MCI demand and provide empirical support. (D3) A Demand Model with Multiple Customer Segments vi pi = m k=1 m k=1 &k = 1 &k exp$ik − pi $ik > 0 &k > 0 i = 1 n The form of vi pi given by (D3) is a plausible way of incorporating customer segments into the demand model. Suppose that there are m customer segments, and a customer belongs to segment k with probability &k . Furthermore, assume that the attractiveness of product i for a customer in segment k is given by exp$ik − pi . Then, vi pi as defined by (D3) yields the expected attractiveness of product i. In the next section, we provide structural results on the joint inventory and pricing problem, assuming that (B1)– (B5) hold. 3. Characterizing the Optimal Solution In general, the difficulty in dealing with inventory and pricing problems for multiple products is that neither the profit function, p y in (2), nor the induced profit function, p in (4), is separately concave in the pi s, let alone jointly Aydin and Porteus: Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions for an Assortment 1251 Operations Research 56(5), pp. 1247–1255, © 2008 INFORMS 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 i p where 8.7 10.0 22.0 11.3 12.6 13.9 15.2 41.8 33.0 6.1 1 500 450 (7) In the rest of this section, we use the representation above to show a number of structural results on p under Assumptions (B1)–(B5). Proposition 2. Suppose that Assumptions B1–B5 hold. (a) If p satisfies i p = 0 for i = 1 n, then ii2 p < 0. (b) If p satisfies i p = 0 for i = 1 n, then ij2 p = 0 for j = i. (c) There exists a unique p that satisfies i p = 0 for i = 1 n. Furthermore, this p maximizes ·. Proposition 2 generalizes Petruzzi and Dada’s (1999) single-product version of this result, using a similar approach. Part (a) implies that p is strictly quasiconcave in each price. However, the joint optimization over the prices of multiple products is further complicated by the existence of cross-price effects. In fact, in the deterministic logit demand case (i.e., the case where vi pi is given by (D1) and i = 1 for i = 1 n), Hanson and Martin (1996) construct an example in which the profit function is not jointly quasi-concave in prices. Indeed, consider the twoproduct inventory and pricing problem with stochastic logit demand in which $1 = 10, $2 = 25, c1 = 6, c2 = 20, and the random error terms, 1 and 2 , are uniformly distributed between 100 and 500. Figure 1 depicts (from two different angles) the expected profit function for this two-product 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 13. Pr ice 2 9.1 20.6 zi p % d% 6.1 7.6 15. 1 6 12. 1 10. 1 6 ce i Pr 22.0 0 pi −ci /pi 25.8 36.2 i p = pi ice Pr (6) 31.0 i=1 41.4 n e2 Profit p = Pric 37.4 0 With this definition, zi p % is the demand that corresponds to the % fractile of i , given the vector p of selling prices, and, thus, yi∗ p = zi p pi − ci /pi Using this representation, the objective function in (4) can be written as 7.4 50 24.2 (5) 500 28.6 i p zi p % = % The expected profit from a two-product assortment, as a function of the prices, where the stock levels are chosen optimally at each price pair. 19.8 and substitute this in (4). This approach results in an induced profit function that is inconvenient to work with. In this paper, we find that the induced profit function takes on a more convenient form when we use the inverse demand functions. The inverse demand function zi p % is defined for i = 1 n (implicitly) by Figure 1. Profit concave. To obtain structural results on the maximization problem in (4), the standard approach would be to write yi∗ p in terms of the inverse of and substitute the resulting expression in p in (4). For example, when Assumption (B1) holds, using (3), we would write ∗ −1 pi − ci yi p = qi p pi inventory and pricing problem. (Recall that inventory levels at any combination of prices are determined uniquely by the critical fractiles.) In this example, which is typical of what we see with different parameter sets, there are two nearly perpendicular ridges in the profit function. If we pick a price point out on each ridge, then along the line that connects these two price points, the profit function would first decrease and then increase. That is, as Hanson and Martin (1996) observed in their example with deterministic demand, the expected profit function is not jointly quasiconcave in this stochastic demand example either. Nevertheless, Proposition 2(c) states that there is a unique price 1252 vector that satisfies the first-order conditions (FOCs), and that the price vector yields the optimal solution. The significance of Proposition 2 is that any hill-climbing algorithm will find the unique optimal price vector. (Such an algorithm stops only when the FOCs are satisfied, and Proposition 2(c) states that only the optimal point satisfies them.) In short, our problem is well behaved in the sense that the FOCs are necessary and sufficient for optimality even though the expected profit function is not jointly quasi-concave in prices. Given the recent popularity of price optimization tools (see, for example, Johnson et al. 2001 and Gustke 2002), this result is rather encouraging; it implies that logit and MCI demand functions, which provide attractive explanations for consumer behavior, result in reasonably well-behaved profit functions that can be optimized without too much difficulty. Another point of interest is how the optimal prices respond to changes in unit procurement costs and product quality. Here, we loosely define quality as a product attribute of which customers prefer more. Note that in the logit and MCI demand models given by (D1) and (D2), the parameter $i can be interpreted as the quality of product i. It is intuitively clear that when either cj or $j increases, the price of product j, pj , will increase as well, in one case as a reaction to the cost increase, and, in the other case, to take advantage of the increased quality of the product. How other products’ prices will respond to these changes is not so obvious. One can show that, under Assumptions (B1)–(B5), if the unit cost of one product increases, the optimal prices of all other products will decrease. Furthermore, under an additional nonrestrictive, technical assumption on how the attractiveness function vi pi depends on quality $i , one can show that if the quality of one product increases, then the optimal prices of all products will increase.1 4. Conclusion In this paper, we investigated a price-dependent newsvendor problem for an assortment. We worked with profit expressions written in terms of the inverse demand functions. This approach alleviates some of the technical challenges posed by price-dependent demand distributions. Under a demand model that follows from an attractive explanation of consumer choice behavior, we showed that the inventory and pricing problem is well behaved (i.e., optimized at the unique vector of prices and inventory levels that correspond to the stationary point). One line of analysis for future research is to extend the results to other demand models. For example, one might want to check if Proposition 2 holds under different forms of qi p, the expected demand for product i as a function of price vector p. We should note here that Proposition 2 does not hold under some commonly used alternative forms for qi p. Consider, for example, the Cobb-Douglas −& demand (i.e., qi p = $i pi i j=i pj ij &i ij > 0 i j = 1 n). Under Cobb-Douglas demand, one can construct Aydin and Porteus: Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions for an Assortment Operations Research 56(5), pp. 1247–1255, © 2008 INFORMS numerical examples that show that the profit function is not even separately quasi-concave in prices; i.e., Proposition 2(a) does not hold. Alternatively, one could check whether Proposition 2 continues to hold under additive randomness. If one assumes that the expected demand is given by the logit demand function and the additive random shock has zero mean, then one can show that Proposition 2 continues to hold. However, this introduces a new problem to the model: when the price of a product is set high, its expected demand will be low, resulting in a nonnegligible probability of negative demand due to the zero-mean additive shock. Another line of future research would be to compare the optimal prices under deterministic and stochastic demand scenarios (with identical expected demand functions). Previous research addressed this question in detail for the singleperiod inventory and pricing problem for a single product. See Petruzzi and Dada (1999) for a review. For example, Karlin and Carr (1962) showed that in the single-product case with multiplicative uncertainty, the firm’s optimal price under stochastic demand exceeds that for deterministic demand. In our model with multiple products, one can construct numerical examples to show that no such ordering exists. Nevertheless, it would be interesting to further analyze the effect of demand variability on prices. Although we model price-based substitution, we do not allow stockout-based substitution. Under stockout-based substitution, even when prices are fixed, the optimal stock levels are no longer independent from one another. (See, for example, Netessine and Rudi 2003.) Therefore, even when the prices of the products are fixed, the optimal stock levels are hard to characterize, which makes the joint inventory and pricing problem all the more difficult. It would be interesting to determine whether there are reasonable conditions under which the result of Proposition 2 continues to hold even when stockout-based substitution is allowed. Another simplifying assumption we made was to ignore external competition faced by a firm selling an assortment. In a more general setting, there would be multiple retailers, each of whom sells an assortment. Such a model could be used to address not only price competition, but also competition on the depth of assortment. Throughout the paper, we assumed that the retail prices were uniform for the entire duration of the selling season. Of course, in most retail settings, the retail price will change over time. Also, for many retail situations, a model where the retailer can place multiple orders over time would be more realistic. It would therefore be interesting to consider the inventory and pricing problem that arises with dynamic pricing and multiple ordering opportunities. 5. Electronic Companion An electronic companion to this paper is available as part of the online version that can be found at http://or. journal.informs.org/. Aydin and Porteus: Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions for an Assortment 1253 Operations Research 56(5), pp. 1247–1255, © 2008 INFORMS Appendix − We first state Lemmas 1–4 that are used for the proofs of the propositions. We then prove Propositions 1 and 2. See Appendix A in the online supplement for the proofs of the lemmas. Lemma 1. Suppose that (A2) holds. For yi∗ p implicitly defined by (3), we have 1 a i yi∗ p = pi n+1 ti p yi∗ phti p yi∗ p · 1 − pi i ti p yi∗ phti p yi∗ p b j yi∗ p = − j ti p yi∗ p >0 n+1 ti p yi∗ p for j = i a i qi p = i pi qi p1 − qi p < 0 b i qk p = −i pi qi pqk p > 0 d for k = i ii2 qk p i qi pi qk p − qk p qi pqk p i qk p i pi − i pi 2 qi p = qk p i pi ij2 qk p qk p i qj pj qk p j qi pi qk p − = 0 qj pqk p qi pqk p − a i p = pi −ci /pi 0 zi p % d% + ci ∗ y p pi i q p pk −ck /pk + pk i k zk p % d% qk p 0 k=1 n b ii2 p = i qi p q p i p + i i qi p qi p pi −ci /pi c · zi p % d% + i i yi∗ p pi 0 2 n ii qk p i qi pi qk p + pk − qk p qi pqk p k=1 · c ij2 p = 0 pk −ck /pk zk p % d% j qi p i qj p i p + p qi p qj p j 2 n ij qk p i qj pj qk p + pk − qj pqk p qk p k=1 pk −ck /pk 0 zk p % d% Proof of Proposition 1. First, we use integration by parts and Assumption (A2) to rewrite p in (4) as follows: p = n pj − cj yj∗ p − pj 0 yj∗ p tj p x dx Now, taking the partial derivative of p with respect to pi and using (3) to eliminate the terms involving i yj∗ p yields yi∗ p ti p x i p = yi∗ p − 0 yj∗ p n − pj i tj p xtj p x dx j=1 0 Using the definition of hx = x/1 − x, we can rearrange i p to yield i p = yi∗ p 0 1 − ti p x · 1 − pi i ti p xhti p x dx y∗ p j − pj i tj p xtj p x dx Lemma 3. Suppose that Assumptions B1–B4 hold. Then, for j = i Lemma 4. Suppose that Assumptions B1–B5 hold. Then, for p defined by (6) and (7): (a) i p > 0 when pi = ci , (b) i p → 0− as pi → . j=1 Lemma 2. Suppose that B2 and B3 hold, and let i pi = vi pi /vi pi . Then c · j qi pi qk p qi pqk p j=i 0 (8) By (A3), i tj p x < 0 for j = i. Suppose now that p satisfies i p = 0. Then, it follows from (8) that we must have 0 yi∗ p 1 − ti p x · 1 − pi i ti p xhti p x dx < 0 (9) For convenience, fix i and p, and define G temporarily by Gx = 1 − pi i ti p xhti p x. By (9), we must have Gx < 0 for some x between 0 and yi∗ p. (Otherwise, the integrand in (9) would be positive for all x between 0 and yi∗ p, leading to a contradiction.) Now, note that, by (A2), ti p x is increasing in x. Also, by (A3), i ti p x > 0 and 2 ti p x/pi x > 0. Furthermore, h· is increasing in its argument because we assume that is IFR. It follows that Gx is decreasing in x. Finally, using the facts that Gx < 0 for some x between 0 and yi∗ p, and Gx is decreasing in x, we conclude that Gyi∗ p < 0. Now, the result follows from part (a) of Lemma 1. Aydin and Porteus: Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions for an Assortment 1254 Operations Research 56(5), pp. 1247–1255, © 2008 INFORMS Proof of Proposition 2. (a) and (b). Substituting from Lemma 2(c) and (d) in Lemma 3(a) and (b), we obtain ii2 p = ij2 p = i qi p q p pi −ci /pi i p + i i zi p % d% qi p qi p 0 i pi − i pi 2 qi p ci ∗ + i yi p + pi i pi (10) n p −c /p k k k q p · pk i k zk p % d% qk p 0 k=1 j qi p i qj p p + p qi p i qj p j j = i Part (b) of the proposition follows directly from the above expression for ij2 p. To prove part (a), consider the following two cases: Case (i). i pi − i pi 2 qi p/i pi 0. We make the following observations: Observation 1. i qi p < 0 by Lemma 2(a). Observation 2. By Proposition 1, i yi∗ p < 0 when i p = 0. Observation 3. When i p = 0, from Lemma 3(a), it follows that n q p pk −ck /pk pk i k zk p % d% qk p 0 k=1 pi −ci /pi c zi p % d% − i yi∗ p < 0 (11) =− p 0 i Applying Observations 1–3 to (10) yields part (a) for Case (i). Case (ii). i pi − i pi 2 qi p/i pi < 0. We make the following observations: Observation 1. For k = i, we have i qk p > 0 by Lemma 2(b). Observation 2. By Proposition 1, i yi∗ p < 0 when i p = 0. Observation 3. We note that i qi p pi −ci /pi zi p % d% qi p 0 p − i pi 2 qi p i qi p pi −ci /pi + i i pi zi p % d% i pi qi p 0 i qi p i pi − i pi 2 qi p = 1+ pi qi p i pi pi −ci /pi · zi p % d% 0 q p p = i i 1 + i i pi − i pi qi ppi qi p i pi pi −ci /pi · zi p % d% < 0 0 where the inequality follows from 1 + i pi /i pi pi 0 and i < 0 (see Assumptions (B3) and (B4)) and i qi p < 0 (by Lemma 2(a)). Now, applying Observations 1–3 to (10) yields part (a) for Case (ii). (c). The idea underlying the proof of part (c) was used previously by Petruzzi and Dada (1999) in their analysis of the single-product price-dependent newsvendor problem. We formalize that argument and extend it to our n-product problem. Here, we provide only a sketch of the proof. See Appendix A in the online supplement for a formal proof. First, note that if p is a maximizer of p, then i p = 0 for i = 1 n due to Lemma 4. To conclude the proof, we will need to show that there exists a unique p such that i p = 0 for i = 1 n, and p maximizes p. Parts (a) and (b) together imply that the Hessian of p is negative definite in the neighborhood of any p such that i p = 0 for i = 1 n. Hence, any stationary point is a strict local maximum. Suppose now that there exist more than one, say two, stationary points of the function p. Because both those points need to be local maxima, the function should also have a local minimum somewhere in between, which is a contradiction to the result that all stationary points are local maxima. Endnote 1. The proofs are available from the authors upon request. Acknowledgments The first author’s research was supported in part by Ericsson AB under the Ericsson Supply Chain Research Grant to the Department of Management Science and Engineering at Stanford University. The authors thank the associate editor and two anonymous referees for their comments, which helped improve the paper. References Anderson, S. P., A. de Palma. 1992. Multi-product firms: A nested logit approach. J. Indust. Econom. 40 261–276. Aydin, G., W. H. Hausman. 2008. The role of slotting fees in the coordination of assortment decisions. Working paper, Department of Industrial and Operations Engineering, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Aydin, G., E. L. Porteus. 2008. Manufacturer-to-retailer versus manufacturer-to-consumer rebates in a supply chain. N. Agrawal, S. Smith, eds. Retail Supply Chain Management. Springer, Boston. Forthcoming. Aydin, G., J. K. Ryan. 2000. Product line selection and pricing under the multinomial logit choice model. Working paper, School of Industrial Engineering, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN. Barlow, R. E., F. Proschan. 1965. Mathematical Theory of Reliability. Wiley, New York. Bernstein, F., A. Federgruen. 2005. Decentralized supply chains with competing retailers under demand uncertainty. Management Sci. 51 18–29. Besanko, D., S. Gupta, D. C. Jain. 1998. Logit demand estimation under competitive pricing behavior: An equilibrium framework. Management Sci. 44 1533–1547. Cachon, G., A. G. Kok. 2007. Category management and coordination in retail assortment planning in the presence of basket shopping consumers. Management Sci. 53 934–951. Cachon, G., C. Terwiesch, Y. Xu. 2005. Retail assortment planning in the presence of consumer search. Manufacturing Service Oper. Management 7 330–346. Aydin and Porteus: Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions for an Assortment Operations Research 56(5), pp. 1247–1255, © 2008 INFORMS Guadagni, P. M., J. D. C. Little. 1983. A logit model of brand choice calibrated on scanner data. Marketing Sci. 2 203–238. Gustke, C. 2002. Prices and possibilities. Progressive Grocer. 18(1) 66–68. Hanson, W., K. Martin. 1996. Optimizing multinomial logit profit functions. Management Sci. 42 992–1003. Hopp, W. J., X. Xu. 2005. Product line selection and pricing with modularity in design. Manufacturing Service Oper. Management 7 172–187. Hopp, W. J., X. Xu. 2008. A static approximation for dynamic demand substitution with applications in a competitive market. Oper. Res. 56(3) 630–645. Johnson, C. A., L. Allen, A. Dash. 2001. Retail revenue management. The Forrester Report. Karlin, S., C. R. Carr. 1962. Prices and optimal inventory policies. K. J. Arrow, S. Karlin, H. Scarf, eds. Studies in Applied Probability and Management Science. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA, 59–172. Luce, R. D. 1959. Individual Choice Behavior: A Theoretical Analysis. Wiley, New York. Maddah, B., E. K. Bish. 2007. Joint pricing, assortment, and inventory decisions for a retailer’s product line. Naval Res. Logist. 54 315–330. Mahajan, S., G. van Ryzin. 1998. Retail inventories and consumer choice. S. Tayur, R. Ganeshan, M. J. Magazine, eds. Quantitative Models for Supply Chain Management. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, 491–552. Mahajan, S., G. van Ryzin. 2001. Stocking retail assortments under dynamic consumer substitution. Oper. Res. 49 334–351. Mills, E. S. 1959. Uncertainty and price theory. Quart. J. Econom. 73 116–130. 1255 Nakanishi, M., W. G. Cooper. 1974. Parameter estimation for a multiplicative competitive interaction model—Least squares approach. J. Marketing Res. 11 303–311. Netessine, S., N. Rudi. 2003. Centralized and competitive inventory models with demand substitution. Oper. Res. 51 329–335. Petruzzi, N. C., M. Dada. 1999. Pricing and the newsvendor problem: A review with extensions. Oper. Res. 47 183–194. Porteus, E. L. 2002. Foundations of Stochastic Inventory Theory. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA. Urban, G. L. 1969. A mathematical modeling approach to product line decisions. J. Marketing Res. 6 40–47. van Ryzin, G., S. Mahajan. 1998. On the relationship between inventory costs and variety benefits in retail assortments. Management Sci. 45 1496–1515. Whitin, T. M. 1955. Inventory control and price theory. Management Sci. 2 61–68. Yano, C., S. M. Gilbert. 2005. Coordinated pricing and production/procurement decisions: A review. A. Chakravarty, J. Eliashberg, eds. Managing Business Interfaces: Marketing, and Engineering Issues in the Supply Chain and Internet Domains. Springer, Boston, 65–103. Zhao, X., D. Atkins. 2008. Newsvendors under price and inventory competition. Manufacturing Service Oper. Management. 10(3) 539–546. Zhu, K., U. Thonemann. 2002. Coordinating pricing and inventory control across products. Working paper, Department of Industrial and Engineering Management, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Kowloon, Hong Kong.
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz