Graphs & Algorithms: Advanced Topics List Coloring Uli Wagner ETH Zürich List Coloring/Choosability Definition Let G be a graph. I Suppose for every vertex v ∈ V (G ), we are given a list of colors L(v ). A properSlist coloring of G (with the given lists) is a map f : V (G ) → v L(v ) such that f (v ) ∈ L(v ) for all v ∈ V (G ) and f (v ) 6= f (w ) whenever {v , w } ∈ E (G ). I G is k-choosable or k-list-colorable if every assignment of k-element lists permits a proper list coloring. I List chromatic number or choice number χ` (G ) := min{k : G is k-choosable} Observation I χ` (G ) ≥ χ(G ) I χ` (G ) ≤ ∆(G ) + 1 (Greedy coloring; works more generally for ∆-degenerate graphs.) List Chromatic Number vs. Chromatic Number Examples I χ` (Kn ) = n = χ(Kn ). I χ` (K2,2 ) = 2 = χ(K2,2 ). Is the case where all lists are equal the hardest? NO! Example χ` (K3,3 ) > 2 = χ(K3,3 ). Proposition Kn,n is not k-choosable if n = 2k−1 k . χl (G ) − χ(G ) can be arbitrarily large. Exercise. Edge (List) Colorings and (List) Chromatic Index Definition I Let G = (V , E ) be a graph, and let a list L(e) of colors be given for every edge eS∈ E . A proper edge list coloring of G is a map c : E (G ) → e L(e) such that c(e) ∈ L(e) for all e ∈ E and c(e) 6= c(e 0 ) whenever e and e 0 share a vertex. I G is k-edge colorable if G admits a proper edge coloring if we are given the same list L(e) = {1, 2, . . . , k} of k colors for every edge. The chromatic index of G is defined as χ0 (G ) := min{k : G is k-edge colorable}. I G is k-edge list colorable if every assigment of lists of k colors to the edges admits a proper edge list coloring. The list chromatic index of G is χ0` := min{k : G is k-list edge colorable}. I Equivalently, if χ0 (G ) and χ0` (G ) are the chromatic number and the list chromatic number, respectively, of the line graph L(G ). List Coloring Conjecture Theorem (König, 1916) G bipartite ⇒ χ0 (G ) = ∆(G ) (maximum degree). Exercise. Theorem (Vizing, 1964) For every graph G , ∆(G ) ≤ χ0 (G ) ≤ ∆(G ) + 1. (Proof omitted) Conjecture (Vizing; Gupta; Albertson; Collins; 1985) For every graph G , χ0` (G ) = χ0 (G ) Theorem (Galvin, 1995) G bipartite ⇒ χ0` (G ) = χ0 (G ) = ∆(G ). Kernel-perfect digraphs and choosability Definition I A kernel of a digraph D is an independent set S ⊆ V (D), such that for every v ∈ V (D) \ S there is w ∈ S, such that ~ ∈ E (D). vw I A digraph is kernel-perfect if every induced subdigraph has a kernel. I Let G be a graph and f : V (G ) → 0 a function. G is f -choosable if it has a proper list coloring for any family of lists {L(v )}v ∈V (G ) with |L(v )| ≥ f (v ) for every v ∈ V (G ). N Lemma (Bondy-Boppana-Siegel) Let D be a kernel-perfect orientation of G . Then G is f -choosable with f (v ) = 1 + dD+ (v ). Proof of the Bondy-Boppana-Siegel Lemma Induction on |V (G )| (generalize greedy coloring for d-degenerate graphs). I Induction base: |V (G )| = 0. Nothing to prove (empty coloring). I Induction step: Let |V (G )| > 0 and let D be a kernel-perfect orientation of G . Let {L(v )}v ∈V (G ) be the given assignment of lists, and let a be a color that appears in at least one list. I W := {w ∈ V (G ) : a ∈ L(w )}, D 0 := D[W ]. I By assumption, D 0 has a kernel U. Color the vertices in U with a. Remove a from all lists L(w ), w ∈ W . Since each w ∈ W \ U has an outneighbor in U, the graph D − U with + the modified lists L0 (v ) satisfy |L0 (v )| ≥ 1 + dD−U (v ) for all v ∈ V (G ) \ U. I Thus, by induction, G − U can be properly list colored with colors from the lists {L0 (v )}v ∈V \U . Together with the coloring of U by a, this yields the desired list coloring of G . Proof of Galvin’s Theorem (1) Theorem (Galvin, 1995) G bipartite ⇒ χ0` (G ) = χ0 (G ) = ∆(G ). Proof. I I Let G = (A ∪ B, E ) be the given bipartite graph and let L = L(G ) be the line graph of G . Suppose χ(L) = χ0 (G ) = k. We need to show that χ0` (G ) = χ` (L) ≤ k (“≥” is trivial). Let c : E → [k] be a proper edge coloring of G . Proof idea: Exhibit a kernel perfect ori1 entation D of L with dD+ (e) ≤ k − 1 for 7 all e ∈ E = V (L). 3 2 If e and e 0 share a vertex v and c(e) < c(e 0 ), then orient the corresponding edge of L from e 0 to e if v ∈ A and from e to e 0 if v ∈ B. c(e) = 5 A 4 8 6 B Proof of Galvin’s Theorem (2) I I Out-degrees in D: Suppose c(e) = i. Any out-neighbor e 0 of e in D must have c(e 0 ) ∈ {1, 2, . . . , i − 1} if e ∩ e 0 ∈ A and c(e 0 ) ∈ {i + 1, . . . , k} if e ∩ e 0 ∈ B. Since c is a proper coloring of L, we have dD+ (e) ≤ k − 1. Kernel-perfectness: Let E 0 ⊆ E and D 0 = D[E 0 ]. Show that D 0 has a kernel, by induction on |E 0 |. If a ∈ A is incident to some e ∈ E 0 , let ea ∈ E 0 be the edge incident to a with minimal color c(ea ), and let U := {ea : a ∈ A incident to E 0 }. −→ Every e ∈ E 0 \ U meets some e ∈ U in A, and e 0 e in D. Thus, if U is independent then it is a kernel. So suppose e, e 0 ∈ U are adjacent in D. By definition of U, e ∩ e 0 ∈ B. W.l.o.g. − → c(e) < c(e 0 ), so ee 0 in D. By induction, D 0 − e has a kernel U 0 . If e 0 ∈ U 0 , we are done. Else, there is e 00 ∈ U 0 such that −− → e 0 e 00 in D. If e 0 ∩ e 00 ∈ X then c(e 00 ) < c(e 0 ) 6∈ U, contradiction. Thus Y 3 e 0 ∩−→ e 00 = e ∩ e 0 and c(e 00 ) > c(e 0 ) > c(e), hence ee 00 in D, so U 0 is a kernel for D 0 . Aside: Stable Matchings Definition Suppose we have n women and n men, each with a (totally ordered) preference ranking of the members of the opposite gender. Suppose we have a perfect matching in the complete bipartite graph of men and women (married couples). Bonnie and Clyde are an unstable pair if I Bonnie and Clyde are currently not a couple, I Bonnie prefers Clyde to her current partner, and I Clyde prefers Bonnie to his current partner. A perfect matching (of n women and n men) is a stable matching if it yields no unstable pair. Theorem (Stable Marriage Theorem, Gale-Shapley, 1962) For any preference rankings of n men and n women there is a stable matching. The Proposal Algorithm Proposal Algorithm (Gale-Shapley, 1962) Input. Preference ranking by each of n men and n women. Iteration: Each man proposes to the woman highest on his list who has not previously rejected him. IF each woman receives exactly one proposal, THEN stop and report the resulting matching as stable. ELSE every woman receiving more than one proposal rejects all of them except the one highest on her list. Every woman receiving at least one proposal says “maybe” to the most attractive proposal she received. ITERATE until there is a matching or some proposal list is empty. Theorem (Gale-Shapley, 1962) The Proposal Algorithm produces a stable matching. The Proposal Algorithm—Proof of Correctness I Whenever a man gets rejected, the total length of the remaining proposal lists decreases. Thus, the algorithm eventually terminates. Lemma During the execution of the algorithm, no man can ever be rejected by all women. (Exercise.) I Thus, the algorithm terminates with a perfect matching M. We need to show that M is stable. Observation The sequence of proposals made by each man is nonincreasing in his preference ranking, and the list of men to whom a woman says ”maybe” is nondecreasing. I If M is not stable, there is an unstable pair (a, b) with (a, x) ∈ M and (y , b) ∈ M, say. Thus, a can never have proposed to b. But also, a would never have proposed to x without previously proposing to b. Contradiction!
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz