Lecture 3 Fall 2009 Referee Reports Referee Reports Housing Data U.S. Housing Data • Housing price movements unconditionally Census data Transaction/deed data (provided by government agencies or available via public records) Household data (PSID, Survey of Consumer Finances, etc.) Mortgage data (appraised value of the home) • Repeat sales indices OFHEO Case-Shiller Repeat Sales vs. Unconditional Data • House prices can increase either because the value of the land under the home increases or because the value of the structure increases. * Is home more expensive because the underlying land is worth more or because the home has a fancy kitchen. • Often want to know the value of the land separate from the value of the structure. • New homes often are of higher quality than existing homes. • Repeat sales indices try to difference out “structure” fixed effects – isolating the effect of changing land prices. * Assumes structure remains constant (hard to deal with home improvements). OFHEO/FHFA Repeat Sales Index • OFHEO – Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight FHFA – Federal Housing Finance Agency Government agencies that oversee Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac • Uses the stated transaction price from Fannie and Freddie mortgages to compute a repeat sales index. (The price is the actual transaction price and comes directly from the mortgage document) • Includes all properties which are financed via a conventional mortgage (single family homes, condos, town homes, etc.) • Excludes all properties financed with other types of mortgages (sub prime, jumbos, etc.) • Nationally representative – creates separate indices for all 50 states and over 150 metro areas. Case Shiller Repeat Sales Index • Developed by Karl Case and Bob Shiller • Uses the transaction price from deed records (obtained from public records) • Includes all properties regardless of type of financing (conventional, sub primes, jumbos, etc.) • Includes only single family homes (excludes condos, town homes, etc.) • Limited geographic coverage – detailed coverage from only 30 metro areas. Not nationally representative (no coverage at all from 13 states – limited coverage from other states) • Tries to account for the home improvements when creating repeat sales index (by down weighting properties that increase by a lot relative to others within an area). -5.00% Jan-92 Aug-92 Mar-93 Oct-93 May-94 Dec-94 Jul-95 Feb-96 Sep-96 Apr-97 Nov-97 Jun-98 Jan-99 Aug-99 Mar-00 Oct-00 May-01 Dec-01 Jul-02 Feb-03 Sep-03 Apr-04 Nov-04 Jun-05 Jan-06 Aug-06 Mar-07 Oct-07 May-08 Dec-08 Jul-09 OFHEO vs. Case Shiller: National Index 20.00% 15.00% 10.00% 5.00% 0.00% -10.00% -15.00% -20.00% -25.00% -30.00% CS Composite 10 CS Composite 20 OFHEO OFHEO vs. Case Shiller: L.A. Index 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 LA-CS LA-OFHEO 0.15 OFHEO vs. Case Shiller: Denver Index 0.1 0.05 0 -0.05 -0.1 -0.15 Denver-CS Denver-OFHEO 0.1 OFHEO vs. Case Shiller: Chicago Index 0.05 0 -0.05 -0.1 -0.15 -0.2 -0.25 Chicago-CS Chicago-OFHEO OFHEO vs. Case Shiller: New York Index 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 -0.05 -0.1 -0.15 NY-CS NY-OFHEO Conclusion: OFHEO vs. Case - Shiller • Aggregate indices are very different but MSA indices are nearly identical. • Does not appear to be the result of different coverage of properties included. • I think the difference has to do with the geographic coverage. • If using MSA variation, does not matter much what index is used. • If calibrating aggregate macro models, I would use OFHEO data instead of Case-Shiller – I think it is more representative of the U.S. A Note on Census Data • To assess long run trends in house prices (at low frequencies), there is nothing better than Census data. • Very detailed geographic data (national, state, metro area, zip code, census tract). • Goes back at least to the 1940 Census. • Have very good details on the structure (age of structure, number of rooms, etc.). • Can link to other Census data (income, demographics, etc.). Housing Cycles Average Annual Real Housing Price Growth By US State State AK AL AR AZ CA CO CT DC DE FL GA HI IA ID IL IN 1980-2000 -0.001 0.000 -0.009 -0.002 0.012 0.012 0.012 0.010 0.011 -0.002 0.008 0.004 -0.001 -0.001 0.010 0.002 2000-2007 0.041 0.024 0.023 0.061 0.066 0.012 0.044 0.081 0.053 0.068 0.019 0.074 0.012 0.047 0.030 0.020 Average 0.011 0.036 State MT NC ND NE NH NJ NM NV NY OH OK OR PA RI SC SD 1980-2000 0.003 0.008 -0.010 -0.002 0.014 0.015 -0.002 -0.005 0.020 0.003 -0.019 0.009 0.008 0.017 0.007 0.002 2000-2007 0.049 0.022 0.033 0.007 0.041 0.058 0.043 0.060 0.051 -0.001 0.019 0.051 0.042 0.059 0.025 0.025 17 Typical “Local” Cycle New York State: Real Housing Price Growth 0.200 0.150 0.100 0.050 0.000 -0.050 -0.100 -0.150 HPI-Growth-Real 18 Typical “Local” Cycle 0.250 California: Real Housing Price Growth 0.200 0.150 0.100 0.050 0.000 -0.050 -0.100 -0.150 HPI-Growth-Real 19 Housing Cycles: Part 1 U.S. Metro Area Data, (1980 - 1990 vs. 1990 - 2000) Real House Price Changes 0.60 0.50 0.40 y = -0.3798x + 0.0027 R² = 0.3804 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 -0.10 -0.20 -0.30 -0.40 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 20 1 Housing Prices and Housing Cycles (Hurst and Guerrieri (2009)) • Persistent housing price increases are ALWAYS followed by persistent housing price declines Some statistics about U.S. metropolitan areas 1980 – 2000 • 44 MSAs had price appreciations of at least 15% over 3 years during this period. • Average price increase over boom (consecutive periods of price increases): 55% • Average price decline during bust (the following period of price declines): 30% • Average length of bust: 26 quarters (i.e., 7 years) • 40% of the price decline occurred in first 2 years of bust 21 1976 1977 1978 1979 1981 1982 1983 1984 1986 1987 1988 1989 1991 1992 1993 1994 1996 1997 1998 1999 2001 2002 2003 2004 2006 2007 2008 OFHEO House Price Index Typical “Country” Cycle (US – OFHEO Data) 0.20 -0.10 U.S. Nominal House Price Appreciation: 1976 - 2008 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 -0.05 22 Typical “Country” Cycle (US – OFHEO Data) 0.12 U.S. Real House Price Appreciation: 1976 - 2008 0.09 0.06 0.03 0.00 -0.03 -0.06 -0.09 -0.12 23 Average Annual Real Price Growth By OECD Country Country 1970-1999 2000-2006 Country 1970-1999 2000-2006 U.S. Japan Germany France Great Britain Italy Canada Spain Australia 0.012 0.010 0.001 0.010 0.022 0.012 0.013 0.019 0.015 0.055 -0.045 -0.029 0.075 0.068 0.051 0.060 0.081 0.065 Netherlands Belgium Sweden Switzerland Denmark Norway Finland New Zealand Ireland 0.023 0.019 -0.002 0.000 0.011 0.012 0.009 0.014 0.022 0.027 0.064 0.059 0.019 0.065 0.047 0.040 0.080 0.059 1970-1999 2000-2006 0.012 0.046 Average 24 Country Cycles – The U.S. is Not Alone Real House Price Growth UK: 1978 - 2006 0.250 0.200 0.150 0.100 0.050 0.000 -0.050 -0.100 -0.150 25 Country Cycles – The U.S. is Not Alone Real House Price Growth Italy: 1978 - 2006 0.250 0.200 0.150 0.100 0.050 0.000 -0.050 -0.100 -0.150 26 Country Cycles – The U.S. is Not Alone Real House Price Growth Japan: 1978 - 2006 0.120 0.100 0.080 0.060 0.040 0.020 0.000 -0.020 -0.040 -0.060 -0.080 27 Housing Cycles: Part 2 OECD Country Level Data (1970 - 2000) Price Changes in Booms vs. Subsequent Busts 0 -0.1 y = -0.6185x + 0.0584 R² = 0.483 Size of Subsequent Bust -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 -0.6 -0.7 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 Size of Boom 0.8 28 1 Do Supply Factors Explain 2000-2008 Cycle .04 Change in Total Housing Units Against Change in Housing Price Adjusted for Population Changes (2000-2005, State Level) ND MN IN NC WI GA LA SCIA MS SD MI AL KS OH NE ID KY TN WV IL ARMO UT OK NM TX -.02 0 .02 CO NV VA FL WY WA DE VT PA ME NH MA OR NY AZ MT CT NJ MD CA RI DC -.04 AK HI -.2 0 Residuals .2 Residuals .4 .6 Fitted values 29 Do Supply Factors Explain 2000-2008 Cycle Change in Total Housing Units Against Change in Housing Price Adjusted for Population Changes (2005-2009, State Level) .02 NV FL .01 HI 0 MI RI -.01 CA AZ ND ME AL SC NJ ID MD VA NH VT DE MS GA WICO AR TN MNOH IL WA WV SD NC NE IA NM CT TX IN KY MO PA OR KS MA DC OK NY UT WY AK -.02 MT -.03 LA -.6 -.4 -.2 Residuals Residuals 0 .2 Fitted values 30 Homework Why Do Housing Prices Cycle? A Spatial Equilibrium Model Part 1 Model Particulars (Baseline Model): The City • City is populated by N identical individuals. • City is represented by the real line such that each point on the line (i) is a different location: i (, ) • nt (i ) : • ht (i ) : Measure of agents who live in i. Size of the house chosen by agents living in i. • • nt (i )ht (i ) 1 nt (i)di N (market clearing condition) (maximum space in i is fixed and normalized to 1) 33 Household Preferences Static model: max c(i ) h(i) > 0 and > 0 c(i ) R(i )h(i) Y normalize price of consumption to 1 ct , ht ,i Arbitrage implies: 1 Pt (i ) R(i ) Pt 1 (i ) 1 r Construction A continuum of competitive builders can always build a unit of housing at constant marginal cost . Profit maximization implies builders will build a unit of housing anytime: Pt Demand Side of Economy max c(i ) h(i ) [Y c(i ) R(i ) h(i)] c ( i ) h ( i ) c(i ) 1 h(i ) c(i ) c(i ) h(i ) 1 c(i ) h(i ) R (i ) h(i ) h(i ) h(i ) 1 c(i ) (Y R (i )h(i )) R(i ) (F.O.C. wrt c) (F.O.C. wrt h) Housing and Consumption Demand Functions 1 h(i ) Y ( ) R(i ) c(i ) ( ) Y Spatial Equilibrium Households have to be indifferent across locations: Consider two locations i and % i. Spatial indifference implies that: c(i ) h(i ) c(% i ) h(% i ) 1 1 Y Y Y Y % R (i ) R (i ) R(i ) R(% i) for all i and % i Equilibrium r R (i ) P (i ) (1 r ) Housing Demand Curve: 1 r 1 h(i )=h = Y r P Housing Supply Curve: P= Graphical Equilibrium ln(P) hD(Y) ln(κ) = ln(P*) ln(h*) ln(h) Shock to Income (similar to shock to interest rate) hD(Y1) ln(P) hD(Y) ln(κ) = ln(P*) ln(h*) ln(h*1) ln(h) Shock to Income (with adjustment costs to supply) hD(Y1) ln(P) hD(Y) ln(κ) = ln(P*) ln(h*) ln(h*1) ln(h) Some Conclusions (Base Model) • If supply is perfectly elastic in the long run (land is available and construction costs are fixed), then: Prices will be fixed in the long run Demand shocks will have no effect on prices in the long run. Short run amplification of prices could be do to adjustment costs. Model has “static” optimization. Similar results with dynamic optimization (and expectations – with some caveats) • Notice – location – per se – is not important in this analysis. All locations are the same. Equilibrium with Supply Constraints Suppose city (area broadly) is of fixed size (2*I). For illustration, lets index the middle of the city as (0). -I 0 I Lets pick I such that all space is filled in the city with Y = Y and r = r. 2I = N (h(i)*) 1 r 1 2I N Y r P N 1 r P Y 2I r Comparative Statics What happens to equilibrium prices when there is a housing demand shock (Y increases or r falls). Focus on income shock. Suppose Y increases from Y to Y1. What happens to prices? N 1 r P Y 2I r N 1 r ln( P ) ln ln(Y ) 2I r With inelastic housing supply (I fixed), a 1% increase in income leads to a 1% increase in prices (given Cobb Douglas preferences) Shock to Income With Supply Constraints ln(P1) ln(κ) = ln(P) hD(Y1) hD(Y) ln(h)=ln(h1) ln(h) The percentage change in income = the percentage change in price Intermediate Case: Upward Sloping Supply ln(P1) ln(κ) = ln(P) hD(Y1) hD(Y) ln(h)=ln(h1) ln(h) Cost of building in the city increases as “density” increases Implication of Supply Constraints (base model)? • The correlation between income changes and house price changes should be smaller (potentially zero) in places where density is low (N h(i)* < 2I). • The correlation between income changes and house price changes should be higher (potentially one) in places where density is high. • Similar for any demand shocks (i.e., decline in real interest rates). Question: Can supply constraints explain the cross city differences in prices? Topel and Rosen (1988) “Housing Investment in the United States” (JPE) • First paper to formally approach housing price dynamics. • Uses aggregate data • Finds that housing supply is relatively elastic in the long run Long run elasticity is much higher than short run elasticity. Long run was about “one year” • Implication: Long run annual aggregate home price appreciation for the U.S. is small. Comment 1: Cobb Douglas Preferences? • Implication of Cobb Douglas Preferences: 1 h Y R Rh Y (expenditure on housing) Implication: Constant expenditure share on housing Implication: Housing expenditure income elasticity = 1 ln(Rh) = 0 1 ln(Y ) Estimated 1 should be 1 Use CEX To Estimate Housing Income Elasticity • Use individual level data from CEX to estimate “housing service” Engel curves and to estimate “housing service” (pseudo) demand systems. Sample: NBER CEX files 1980 - 2003 Use extracts put together for “Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure” and “Conspicuous Consumption and Race” Restrict sample to 25 to 55 year olds Estimate: (1) (2) * * * ln(ck) = α0 + α1 ln(tot. outlays) + β X + η (Engle Curve) sharek = δ0 + δ1 ln(tot. outlays) + γ X + λ P + ν (Demand) Use Individual Level Data Instrument total outlays with current income, education, and occupation. Total outlays include spending on durables and nondurables. 51 Engel Curve Results (CEX) Dependent Variable log rent (renters) log rent (owners) log rent (all) Coefficient S.E. 0.93 0.84 0.94 0.014 0.001 0.007 * Note: Rent share for owners is “self reported” rental value of home Selection of renting/home ownership appears to be important 52 Demand System Results (CEX) Dependent Variable rent share (renters, mean = 0.242) rent share (owners, mean = 0.275) rent share (all, mean = 0.263) Coefficient S.E. -0.030 -0.050 -0.025 0.003 0.002 0.002 * Note: Rent share for owners is “self reported” rental value of home Selection of renting/home ownership appears to be important 53 Engel Curve Results (CEX) Dependent Variable log rent (renters) log rent (owners) log rent (all) Coefficient S.E. 0.93 0.84 0.94 0.014 0.001 0.007 * Note: Rent share for owners is “self reported” rental value of home Selection of renting/home ownership appears to be important Other Expenditure Categories log entertainment (all) log food (all) log clothing (all) 1.61 0.64 1.24 0.013 0.005 0.010 X controls include year dummies and one year age dummies 54 Demand System Results (CEX) Dependent Variable rent share (renters, mean = 0.242) rent share (owners, mean = 0.275) rent share (all, mean = 0.263) Coefficient S.E. -0.030 -0.050 -0.025 0.003 0.002 0.002 * Note: Rent share for owners is “self reported” rental value of home Selection of renting/home ownership appears to be important Other Expenditure Categories entertainment share (all, mean = 0.033) 0.012 food share (all, mean = 0.182) -0.073 clothing share (all, mean = 0.062) 0.008 0.001 0.001 0.001 X controls include year dummies and one year age dummies 55 Comment 1: Conclusion • Cannot reject constant income elasticity (estimates are pretty close to 1 for housing expenditure share). • Consistent with macro evidence (expenditure shares from NIPA data are fairly constant over the last century). • If constant returns to scale preferences (α+β = 1), β ≈ 0.3 (share of expenditure on housing out of total expenditure). Comment 2: Cross City Differences “On Local Housing Supply Elasticity” Albert Siaz (QJE Forthcoming) • Estimates housing supply elasticities by city. • Uses a measure of “developable” land in the city. • What makes land “undevelopable”? Gradient Coverage of water • Differences across cities changes the potential supply responsiveness across cities to a demand shock (some places are more supply elastic in the short run). Comment 3: Are Housing Markets Efficient? • Evidence is mixed • Things to read: “The Efficiency of the Market for Single-Family Homes” (Case and Shiller, AER 1989) “There is a profitable trading rule for persons who are free to time the purchase of their homes. Still, overall, individual housing price changes are not very forecastable.” Subsequent papers find mixed evidence: Transaction costs? Comment 4: Can Supply Constraints Explain Cycles? “Housing Dynamics” (working paper 2007) by Glaeser and Gyrouko Calibrated spatial equilibrium model Match data on construction (building permits) and housing prices using time series and cross MSA variation. Find that supply constraints cannot explain housing price cycles. Their explanation: Negatively serially correlated demand shocks. What Could Be Missing? • Add in reasons for agglomeration. • Long literature looking at housing prices across areas with agglomeration. • Most of these focus on “production” agglomerations. • We will lay out one of the simplest models – Muth (1969), Alonzo (1964), Mills (1967) • Locations are no longer identical. There is a center business district in the area where people work (indexed as point (0) for our analysis). • Households who live (i) distance from center business district must pay additional transportation cost of τi. Same Model As Before – Except Add in Transport Costs Static model: max c(i ) h(i ) ct , ht ,i > 0 and > 0 c(i ) R (i )h(i ) Y i Still no supply constraints (unlimited areas) Demand Side of Economy max c(i ) h(i ) [Y i c(i ) R(i ) h(i )] c ( i ) h ( i ) c(i ) 1 h(i ) c(i ) c(i ) h(i ) 1 c(i ) h(i ) R (i ) h(i ) h(i ) h(i ) 1 c(i ) (Y i R (i ) h(i )) R (i ) (F.O.C. wrt c) (F.O.C. wrt h) Housing and Consumption Demand Functions 1 h(i ) (Y i ) ( ) R (i ) c(i ) ( ) (Y i ) Spatial Equilibrium Households have to be indifferent across locations: Consider two locations i and % i. Spatial indifference implies that: c (i ) h(i ) c(% i ) h(% i ) Y i % i R (% i ) R (i ) Y % When i > % i, R(i) < R(i) Equilibrium Equilibrium Result: All occuppied neighborhoods i will be contained in [-I,I]. Define R(I) and P(I) as the rent and price, respectively, at the boundary of the city. Given arbitrage, we know that: r R(I) = (1 r ) Y i Y I r R (i ) (1 r ) Complete Equilibrium: Size of City (Solve for I) Remember: h(i)n(i) = 1 and n(i ) di N i 1 2 di N h(i ) i 0 I h(i ) 1 r 1 r Y I (Y i ) Some Algebra (if my algebra is correct…) I 1 2 1 r 1 i 0 (Y i ) Y I r I N (Y i ) di 2 i 0 di N 1 r 1 r Y I N 1 r 1 1 1 2 r 1 I (Y ) N 1 r 1 2 r 1 Prices By Distance (Initial Level of Y = Y0) P κ 0 I0 i Linearized only for graphical illustration Prices fall with distance. Prices in essentially all locations exceed marginal cost. Suppose Y increases from Y0 to Y1 P κ 0 I0 I1 i Even when supply is completely elastic, prices can rise permanently with a permanent demand shock. A Quick Review of Spatial Equilibrium Models • Cross city differences? Long run price differences across cities with no differential supply constraints. Strength of the center business district (size of τ) drives long run price appreciations across city. • Is it big enough? • Fall in τ will lead to bigger cities (suburbs) and lower prices in center city (i = 0).
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz