Euro. J. History of Economic Thought 8:3 363–390 Autumn 2001 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory* Giuseppe Freni 1. Introduction As is well known, Sraffa’s 1926 Economic Journal article comprises two main parts. The second part contains a seminal contribution to imperfect competition theor y. The paper, however, rst summarizes the conclusions on competitive price theor y that the author had drawn in a longer paper published in Italian the previous year (Sraffa 1925). There, Sraffa had questioned the soundness of the non-constant supply curves, a key element of the Marshallian theory of competitive value that ‘is inspired by the fundamental symmetry existing between the forces of demand and those of supply’ (Sraffa 1926: 180; see also Sraffa 1925: 325). His conclusion, repeated in the 1926 EJ article, had been that ‘in normal cases the cost of production of commodities produced competitively [. . .] must be regarded as constant in respect of small variations in the quantity produced’ (Sraffa 1926: 186; see also Sraffa 1925: 363). Together with the contribution to imperfect competition, it was this thesis that after the publication of Sraffa’s 1926 article ‘generated a disproportionate amount of interest’ (Samuelson 1987: 458). The general equilibrium reasoning on which Sraffa’s criticism rests had, on the contrary, no impact on the literature of that time (see Panico 1991: 558, 561; and Samuelson 1967). In Samuelson’s words, it is ‘as a result of quite other historical in uences and developments, [that] general equilibrium thinking has swept the eld of analytical economics’ (Samuelson 1967: 116). Moreover, Sraffa’s 1925 argument has been overlooked for nearly 50 years afterward (for example, Garegnani 1984, contains no reference to Sraffa’s Address for correspondence Istituto di Studi Economici, Istituto Universitario Navale, Via Medina, 40, 80133 Napoli, Italy; e-mail: [email protected] The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought ISSN 0967-2567 print/ISSN 1469-5936 online © 2001 Taylor & Francis Ltd http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals DOI: 10.1080/09672560110062979 Giuseppe Freni 1925/26 papers). In the last twenty years, however, the content of Sraffa’s 1925 and 1926 related papers has been the subject of a small literature whose main aim is the reassessment of the links between Sraffa’s 1925 criticism and Production of Commodities (Sraffa 1960) (see e.g. Sylos Labini 1985; Maneschi 1986; Samuelson 1987, 1990a, 1990b, 1991; Garegnani 1990; Schefold 1990; Panico 1991; Panico and Salvadori 1994; Mongiovi 1996. For an earlier treatment see Talamo 1976). In this literature, no consensus has been achieved, so virtually ever y article contains a diffent interpretation – often based on different evidence. In any case, the want of references to the early work in Production of Commodities and Sraffa’s own statement that his 1960 method of analysis is ‘that of the old classical economists from Adam Smith to Ricardo’ (Sraffa 1960: v) give support to the prevalent view that endorses the existence of a remarkable discontinuity between Sraffa’s early competitive analysis and the method he employed in the 1960 book. Contrar y to this view, the present article contains a reinterpretation of Sraffa’s early work that emphasizes the elements of continuity with Production of Commodities in the method of analysis (see also Panico and Salvadori 1994). It also identi es the sources of the major changes that intervened during the short lapse of time separating the EJ paper from the rst drafts of Production of Commodities in the attempt to enhance the role of produced means of productions and in the shift to a new subject of analysis. The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, Sraffa’s Marshallian framework of analysis underlying the 1925 and 1926 works is identi ed. Section 3 contains a description of the characteristic way in which mutual interdependencies are treated in Sraffa’s 1925 contribution. The rst part of the section is dedicated to what Sraffa regarded in 1925 as ‘undiscarding’ interdependencies, i.e. the use of constant factors of production in common by different industries and external economies generated in an industr y, but not internal to the industr y itself. In the second part, the role of produced means of production in the 1925 paper is scrutinized. A model that rationalizes the main analytical points contained in Sraffa (1925) is introduced in section 4. In section 5, the elements that mark the transition to Production of Commodities are documented and what of the early Marshallian analysis survived in Production of Commodities is detected. Section 6 contains the concluding remarks. 2. Sraffa’s Marshallian framework of analysis Commentaries on Sraffa’s contribution to the ‘cost controversy’ either do not explicitly clarify Sraffa’s framework of analysis or specify different models. This may suggest that most of the controversies are simply due to 364 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory the lack of a single analytical focus, and that the search for Sraffa’s own framework may be worthwhile. It seems, in particular, that at least two classes of models are described in the secondar y literature.1 In the former, as in the usual Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson (HOS) model of trade, all factors are supplied inelastically (in particular, leisure does not appear among products). In the latter, as in Samuelson’s ‘Ricardo–Marshall’ speci c factors model (Samuelson, 1971), the amounts of all factors, apart from land, change with production (the models of this class involve a generalized possibility production frontier in which leisure may be seen as a produced good). Of course, working within the Marshallian tradition does not necessarily require a model belonging to the second class. Indeed, an alternative version of the partial equilibrium speci c-factors model in which labour is supplied inelastically is quite common in the trade literature (see e.g. Krugman and Obstfeld 1991, ch. 3) and the ‘external economies of scale’ counterpart of the same kind of model has been developed by Chipman (1970). Moreover, an entire stream of literature suggests that Marshall’s tenets refer to a single sector that constitutes an extremely small part of the overall economy (or of the ‘group’). Accordingly, a proper Marshallian model should take into account the effects of some ‘passing to the limit’ operations (see e.g. Vives 1987, that uses this procedure to derive decreasing demand curves). As regards the supply functions, a similar modelling style is present in some passages of Sraffa’s 1925 paper (e.g. Sraffa 1925: 350). Moreover, Pigou (1927, see also Pigou 1928) embraced this view and took the extreme position that partial equilibrium analysis can be applied only to ‘commodities which individually employ so small a proportion of each of several factors of production that no practicable changes in the scale of their output could sensibly affect the relative values of these factors’ (Pigou 1927: 192). Therefore, ‘only the laws of constant or decreasing supply price, as so conceived, are admissible’ (Pigou 1928: 256). Even with these quali cations, a model with elastically supplied factors seems to be part of the Marshallian tradition. Joan Robinson’s 1941 paper on rising supply price, for example, contains clear hints in this sense about the structure of the Marshallian framework commonly employed before the 1930s. The classical analysis, which gave rise to the Ricardian theor y of rent, dealt with the question of what happens when the supplies of labour and capital increase, and land remains xed. This clearly has nothing to do with rising supply price for a particular commodity. It belongs to the department of output as a whole. [. . .] The problem of the long-period supply curve of a particular commodity belongs to the department of the theory of value, which treats of relative prices of commodities. Marshall’s analysis appears to be a cross between the theory of value and the theory of output as a whole. For he seems most often to be discussing the problem 365 Giuseppe Freni of the change in the supply of a particular commodity which occurs in response to a net increase in demand. The demand for one commodity increases, but the demand for the rest does not decline. The additional factors, apart from land, employed in increasing the supply of the commodity are called into existence by the increase in demand. (Robinson 1941: 233–4) There is also some evidence that this model is what Sraffa used in his 1925 critique of Marshallian supply functions. First, consider the alternative HOS-like model. The fact that the production possibility frontier was developed as an analytical tool after 1930 has been pointed out several times (see Samuelson 1967: 29 and Newman 1987). So, even if an ante litteram use of the frontier by Sraffa cannot be ruled out, it seems at least unlikely. Furthermore, in Sraffa’s 1925 paper there is nothing suggesting that the rising of price in the ‘expanding’ industry may, in some way, depend on the structure of the presumed ‘contracting’ industries. Indeed, in cases of decreasing returns, Sraffa summarized his entire argument as follows: [T]he increase in production of a commodity leads to an increase in cost that has equal importance for that commodity and for the others of the group. (Sraffa 1925: 361; emphasis added) As regards the ‘small’ sector model, it is true, as remarked above, that Sraffa made some references to it. However, it is equally true that the ‘small’ sector case is always treated by Sraffa as a sub-case of a more general model (Sraffa 1925: 359–60, 362–3; see Panico 1991). This is especially clear in the treatment of increasing cost. Sraffa begins his argument with the case of a speci c factor: These conditions reduce to a minimum the range over which hypothesis of increasing costs are applicable to the supply curve of a product. They are satis ed only in those exceptional cases where the totality of a factor is used in the production of a single commodity. (Sraffa 1925: 359) Then, he examines two possibilities for the case of a factor used by a number of industries, ‘the one appropriate to the case in which we are dealing with a small number of commodities, and the other to a case dealing with a large number of commodities’ (Sraffa 1925: 359–60). A substantially identical argumentation is developed for the decreasing supply curve (Sraffa 1925: 362–3). The last bit of evidence in favour of the ‘Ricardo–Marshall’ model is the analysis of the intensive rent formation in §88 of Sraffa’s Production of Commodities (Sraffa 1960) – the only passage where changes in quantities are admitted – which is built along the same lines J. Robinson attributed to Marshall (see Panico and Salvadori 1994; infra section 5). 366 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory To summarize, the study of the conditions under which independent supply functions can be constructed around an equilibrium point in a ‘Ricardo–Marshall’ framework appears to be Sraffa’s main analytical interest in 1925. In addition, there is no clear evidence that the scope of the analysis was restricted to ‘small’ industries. 3. Interdependencies between industries In Sraffa’s 1925 paper, the interdependencies that are most remarkable for their absence are those arising from the presence of produced means of production (see Steedman 1988). In view of Sraffa’s complete inversion of emphasis in Production of Commodities (whose main propositions, it should be remembered, had been already elaborated in 1928, Sraffa 1960: vi), the following discussion is organized in two sub-sections entitled: ‘Pure supply–demand interdependencies’ and ‘Produced means of productions in Sraffa’s 1925 paper’. 3.1 Pure supply–demand interdependencies In 1925 Sraffa overlooked the interdependence of the demand functions though not as thoroughly as the capital-induced interdependence. As regards income effects, he simply accepted their exclusion as a legitimate approximation in the construction of demand functions (Sraffa 1925: 361). On the contrary, substitution effects were mentioned in considering the case of a factor used by a number of industries that produce different commodities (Sraffa 1925: 359–60). However, since these effects are not taken into account ‘in those exceptional cases where the totality of a factor is used in the production of a single commodity’ (Sraffa 1925: 359; see also pp. 361–2 for decreasing costs), it is as if Sraffa’s sought a role for substitution effects only if independent supply curves cannot be assumed. All demand-side interdependencies seem to belong, in summary, to the set of cases in which ‘a slight degree of interdependence may be overlooked without disadvantage’ (Sraffa 1926: 184). We are left, therefore, with mutual interdependencies of the supply functions. And, indeed, the analysis of the conditions in which Marshallian non-constant supply schedules can be constructed without violating the ceteris paribus assumption constitutes the core of Sraffa’s 1925 analysis and the basis for his criticism of the Marshallian theor y. Sraffa identi ed the conditions which a supply curve must satisfy in the following way: 367 Giuseppe Freni Since it represents only two variables, it is necessary to suppose that all the other conditions of the problem remain unchanged with the variation in the production of the commodity. It is necessar y, in particular, that the demand of consumer, and the conditions in which other commodities are produced, should not change. That is to say (1) the supply curve must be independent, both of the corresponding demand curve and also of the supply curves of all the other commodities; (2) the supply curve is valid only for slight variations in the quantity produced and, if we depart too far from the initial equilibrium position, it may become necessary to construct an entirely new curve, since a large variation would, in general, be incompatible with the condition ceteris paribus. (Sraffa 1925: 358–59) Then, he found two situations in which these conditions are met in the construction of increasing and decreasing supply curves. The rst occurs, as already noted, when all factors in short supply are speci c to a single industry (Sraffa 1925: 359). The second is the case when externalities generated in one industr y do not spill over into other sectors (in Sraffa’s terminology the increasing returns are in this case ‘external to the rm and internal to the industr y’) (Sraffa 1925: 361–2). As noted above, in spite of the existence of these two consistent cases of non-constant supply curves, Sraffa’s 1925 position was that Marshallian rising or decreasing supply curves can be derived only in exceptional cases (Sraffa 1925: 359 for decreasing returns, and pp. 361–2 for increasing returns). This led him to the conclusion that, ‘in the study of the particular equilibrium of an industr y [. . .], we must concede that, in general, commodities are produced under conditions of constant costs’ (Sraffa 1925: 363). The importance (in Sraffa’s work) and the soundness of this thesis have given rise to some controversies in the secondar y literature that we can usefully survey here. The various positions range from those of Eatwell and Garegnani, who approve of Sraffa’s argument (Eatwell 1990: 281; Garegnani 1990: 284), to that of Samuelson which is very critical about ‘the fatal 1926 error’ (Samuelson 1990b: 320; 1991: 572–3). In between, we nd more cautious positions, as that of Schefold (Schefold 1990: 311, 313). Since some aspects of this controversy have some bearings on the subjects of the next sections, we state about these aspects the following views: (A) From a historical point of view, Sraffa’s 1925 and 1926 conclusion (as opposed to his 1925 analysis) appears as an extraneous appendix in the corpus of Sraffa’s critique of Marshallian supply functions. In addition, it is almost irrelevant to Sraffa’s subsequent work. Samuelson’s opposite view that Sraffa spent all his life in ‘the attempt to emphasise the singular cases in which the theory of value happens to be dependent only on technology and costs independently of the composition 368 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory of demand’ (Samuelson 1991: 570; see also Samuelson 1987: 459), is so extreme an opinion as to be easy to reject. Indeed, when in chapter XI of Production of Commodities Sraffa contemplated changes in quantities (through a model that is no more than an elaboration of a model already present in the 1925 paper, see Panico and Salvadori 1994; infra section 5), changes in prices were explicitly involved (Sraffa 1960: 76 fn). Therefore, it seems likely that Sraffa never advocated, apart from partial equilibrium analysis, a quantity-independent theor y of competitive prices. Moreover, soon after 1926 (some time between 1927 and 1928), Sraffa abandoned the Marshallian partial equilibrium approach and embraced the intersectoral simultaneous approach to the analysis of value we nd in Production of Commodities. In particular, in the Preface of the 1960 book it is stated that ‘the central propositions had taken shape in the late 1920s’ (Sraffa 1960: vi) and that ‘in 1928 Lord Keynes read a draft of the opening proposition of this [book]’ (Sraffa 1960: vi). Therefore, the transition to a ‘general’ equilibrium analysis took place shortly after writing the 1926 EJ article and, given this temporal contiguity, it is seen by part of the literature (see e.g. Talamo 1976; Panico 1991; cf. Mongiovi 1996) as stemming from Sraffa’s lack of satisfaction with Marshall’s theor y. Finally, regarding his own early contribution, the Preface of Production of Commodities contains the somewhat critical statement: The temptation to presuppose constant returns is not entirely fanciful. It was experienced by the author himself when he started on these studies many years ago – and led him in 1925 into an attempt to argue that only the case of constant returns was generally consistent with the premises of economic theory. (Sraffa 1960: vi) (B) From an analytical point of view, I agree with Samuelson (1990b: 320) that Sraffa’s argument is weak. The irrelevance of non-constant supply curves, and thus constancy of costs as a ‘generic’ property, require a comparison of the relative importance of constant and non-constant costs when partial equilibrium analysis is valid. But this kind of analysis is not present in Sraffa’s papers. What can be found instead is a reasoned discussion showing how rarely the conditions for valid partial equilibrium analysis with nonconstant supply curve can be met in general (Sraffa 1925: 356–63, 1926: 180–7). Thus it seems that Sraffa sustained his conclusion by means of an argument in which a wrong space of parameters was employed. On the other hand, the ver y fact that various aspects of Sraffa analysis are loosely speci ed seems to weaken Samuelson’s other judgement (that Sraffa’s conclusion is false, Samuelson 1991: 573). Since what is ‘generic’ may depend on what we choose to utilize as parameters, how can we exclude that there is some competitive framework in which constant-cost response is the ‘generic’ rule? 369 Giuseppe Freni The results of this sub-section can be summarized in the following way. The incomplete framework in Sraffa’s 1925 article mainly encompasses supply relations. Demand functions are loosely speci ed and not integrated with the other part of the structure. In conclusion, Sraffa’s framework appears close to the supply side of a ‘Ricardian’ competitive model (i.e. produced quantities are treated as parameters). 3.2 Produced means of production in Sraffa’s 1925 paper Sraffa’s 1925 article contains some references to capital goods. The following are among the most signi cant passages. [L]et us call c the quantity of capital and labour that, on the same amount of land k, gives the maximum average product per unit of capital and labour. (Sraffa 1925: 331) When, having spent an annual sum on the cultivation of a given land, and wishing to spent another thousand lire, reference to the agricultural technology will indicate not only one way but a whole series of different ways, A, B, C, D, . . . , in which it is technically possible to spent the additional 1,000 lire. It will be possible to buy additional fertiliser, or make a deeper ploughing, or improve the quality of the seed, or one hundred other possible expenditures, or any combination of these. (Sraffa 1925: 333) However, there is no evidence that produced means of production were integrated in Sraffa’s scheme as they are in Production of Commodities (see Steedman 1988). This is particularly clear if we consider the fact that all the above passages refer to rising supply curves. And that, therefore, changes in the prices of produced commodities should have been involved in the process if, as in Production of Commodities, proportionality links between input and output prices were present in Sraffa’s framework. If we speculate on the reasons of the marginal role of produced inputs, then at least two alternative explanations can be offered. It seems possible either that Sraffa considered capital goods as ‘constant factors’ of which ‘marginal doses’ can be drawn from other industries without any increase in costs (Sraffa 1925: 360, 1926: 185), or that, as suggested in Panico (1991), he judged the interdependencies related to the common use of a given factor and to external economies as the most important, and thought of those related to produced inputs as being indirect. In any case, the fact remains that Sraffa’s 1925 framework is analytically equivalent to a model in which only primary factors are present. Historically, therefore, it seems plausible that input–output interdependencies became central in Sraffa’s work between the end of 1926 and 1928 when Keynes read a draft of the opening propositions of Production of Commodities (Sraffa 1960: vi). However, on the basis of the existing evidence, 370 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory how this change in perspective is connected with the development of Sraffa’s interest in classical theor y is not clear (examples of antithetical reconstruction are the two recent contributions by Panico and Salvadori 1994; Mongiovi 1996). In any case, the discussion contained in sub-section 3.1 suggests that the treatment of quantities as parameters is not too far from the procedure that Sraffa had already adopted in 1925. To sum up, the effects due to the existence of produced means of production, so central in Sraffa 1960 book, were ignored by Sraffa in 1925. The elements of Sraffa’s 1925 analysis can now be assembled in a consistent model. This is the task attempted in the next section. 4. A ‘Ricardian’ model of supply relationships In this section, we present a model comprising the main features of Sraffa’s 1925 analysis as they were identi ed in the previous sections. In particular, demand functions and produced means of productions will not be included in the model, given that Sraffa did not integrate the latter in the analysis and did not specify the former (section 3). Moreover, as in Joan Robinson’s Ricardo–Marshall framework (section 2), labour will be assumed to be available from the ‘leisure’ sector. The result is a model that in the decreasing costs part has some features in common with Chipman’s (1970) treatment of parametric external economies, while in the increasing cost part, it resembles Samuelson’s (1959) Ricardian model and, signi cantly, is consistent with Sraffa’s (1960) Ch. XI treatment of the intensive rent formation. In 1925, Sraffa used two rather different procedures for reaching the supply curves of increasing and decreasing costs industries. In the rst case, he well realized that a theory of rm is vacuous under global constant returns and that therefore, ‘[a]s far as the construction of this curve is concerned, we can consider the whole industry as a single rm which employs the whole of the “constant factor” ’ (Sraffa 1925: 341–2). In the second case, he used the U-shaped cost curve of a representative rm, probably in order to stress that the quantity produced in the industry is a parameter from the point of view of the single producer (Sraffa 1925: 348–55). Decreasing costs, however, can be subsumed under the rst approach provided we renounce any functional role for the dimension of the representative rm (this is consistent with Sraffa’s position. According to him, ‘[t]he point of maximum economy could be moved in any direction’ (Sraffa 1925: 352). Furthermore, he judged the case in which the equilibrium production of the representative rm is indeterminate as perfectly possible (Sraffa 1925: 351). As is well known, this requires that the technical coef cients be explicitly treated as functions of the amounts of production. Dealing with external economies, we will adopt this procedure in what follows. 371 Giuseppe Freni Now we study how the supply curve is linked to the ‘rent’ function when labour and a land of given quality are employed in the production of a single commodity. Assume that there are constant returns. Thus, a process of production (at the unitary level) can be de ned as the pair (l, k), where l ³ 0 gives the quantity of labour needed per unit of output, and k ³ 0 gives the corresponding land input. To begin with, assume that only a nite number m, m ³ 1, of processes are known, and call the nite set T = {(li, ki), i = 1, 2, . . . , m} the technology. If competitive conditions prevail, then in equilibrium the following relations hold: wli + rki ³ p, 1 £ i £ m [1] xi (wli + rki) = xi p, 1 £ i £ m [2] m x iki £ h [3] r x iki = rh [4] i=1 m i=1 xi ³ 0, 1 £ i £ m [5] w ³ 0, r ³ 0, p ³ 0 [6] where w is the wage rate, r is the rent rate, p is the price of the commodity, xi is the activity level of process i and h > 0 is the existing amount of land. Inequalities [1] and equations [2] are the pro t maximization conditions, while inequality [3] and equation [4] describe the outcome of the market for land services. Normalize the size of the available quantity of land to unity, h = 1, and choose labour as numeraire (we therefore preclude the analysis of the case w = 0). Then inequalities [1] and [6] de ne the convex set illustrated in gure 1. Furthermore, since inequalities [3] and [5] and equation [4] can be satis ed if and only if a point on the frontier of the set is chosen, then the equation of the frontier is linked to an overall solution of the system [1]–[6]. We are, therefore, interested in nding a way to represent analytically the frontier. To obtain this result, note that each point on the frontier minimizes the rent under the constraints [1] and [6]. Hence the equation we are looking for is simply given by the solutions of the family of problems: R(p) = min r s.t. li + rki ³ p, 1 £ i £ n p ³ 0, r ³ 0. 372 [P] Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory Figure 1 Now suppose that the ‘rent’ function R(p) is known. Note that its (generalized) derivative gives the product per unit of land associated with the equilibrium process. But, given the normalization above, this amounts to the whole production. Therefore, the supply curve can be obtained from the rent function by plotting its derivative against the price as in gure 2. External economies can be added to the frame by allowing the coef cients l and k to var y with the level of production. To make things easy, we assume the existence of a nite number of technologies, each associated to a threshold. Then we can plot all the supply curves together, selecting for each interval the relevant one. It is clear that the use of thresholds can induce discontinuities in the supply curve ( gure 3). The value function of problem [P] (i.e. when external effects are absent) can be smoothed by adding new viable processes to a given technology, and in the limit it could become differentiable (this means that the associated supply ‘function’ is univalued).2 In the rest of this section, indeed, safe for the point where it reaches the price axis, the rent function will be assumed to be smooth.3 At this point, the way the rent functions can be employed if different qualities of land can be brought into cultivation should be clear. A rent function can be constructed for each quality of land. Then, after the 373 Giuseppe Freni Figure 2 Figure 3 normalization of all lands sizes to 1, the supply curve can be obtained by summing up the (generalized) derivatives of these functions. Lands can also be classi ed in order of fertility on the basis of the minimum price that induces cultivation (Sraffa 1925: 339–40). The rent functions can be easily used also in the ‘general’ equilibrium framework that originates from the hypothesis that at least one piece of land can be employed by a number of industries. Assume there are s, s ³ 1, 374 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory qualities of land and n, n ³ 2, commodities. Now the rent functions are to be indexed both by the lands and the goods. Then let Rij(pi), i = 1, 2, . . . , n, j = 1, 2, . . . , s, indicate the rent function associated to commodity i and to land j, where pi is the price of good i. Assume that, with the possible exception of the root of Rij(pi) = 0, Rij(pi) is differentiable. At Rij(pi) = 0, the left derivative will be zero, R9 ij(pi)2 = 0, while the right derivative will be non-negative R9 ij(pi)+ ³ 0. If good i cannot be produced on land j, then put Rij(pi) = 0 (i.e. in this case, using land of quality j in production of commodity i amounts to allow land to go out of cultivation). Now the competitive equilibrium relations, analogous with the above conditions [1]–[6], are given by Rij(pi) £ rj, 1 £ i £ n, 1 £ j £ s [7] sijRij(pi) = sijrj, 1 £ i £ n, 1 £ j £ s [8] s ij £ 1, 1 £ j £ s i=1 n rj s ij = rj, 1 £ j £ s i=1 s s ij R9 ij(pi)+ = qi, 1 £ i £ n j=1 sij ³ 0, 1 £ i £ n, 1 £ j £ s [9] n [10] [11] [12] pi ³ 0, qi ³ 0, 1 £ i £ n [13] rj ³ 0, 1 £ j £ s [14] where rj is the rent (rate) on land of quality j, qi is the supply of commodity i, and sij is the share of land j employed in the production of good i. As before, inequalities [7] and equations [8] are the pro t maximization conditions, while inequalities [9] and equations [10] assert that the quantity of each land used in production does not exceed the existing quantity and that the rent (rate) is zero whenever a quality of land is in excess supply. Finally equations [11] de ne the supplied quantities. Given a non-negative price vector, then the system [7]–[14] determines a set of quantities that can be competitively produced at those prices. Conversely, if for each commodity i a rent function, Rij(pi), exists such that R9 ij(pi) ®¥ when pi ®¥, then, given a vector of quantities, the system determines a set of equilibrium supply price vectors.4 Assume an ‘equilibrium’ is reached. Then a relationship between pi and qi can be constructed around the equilibrium point by maintaining the initial values of all other quantities. Since a necessary and suf cient condition for valid partial equilibrium analysis is that the other markets are not to be disturbed by the new supply conditions, the key equilibrium relationships are 375 Giuseppe Freni those given by equations [11] that link the uses of lands to the intensities of cultivation. They x the limits within which an increase of production can be dealt with by means of a partial equilibrium analysis. First, if the increase can be accommodated by changing only the weights sij. In this case the costs are constant. Second, if the increase of production can be accommodated by a change of the price whose effects do not propagate to other sectors. This requires that the weights of the lands on which the cultivation of the isolated commodity will be intensi ed are all 1. These lands, in other words, are to be specialized in growing the single commodity at least in a neighbourhood of the equilibrium. Since interdependencies between sectors in the model arise only through the use of common factors, the elements of the model are arranged in such a way that linkages among sectors vanish whenever a one-to-one correspondence can be found between the set of commodities and a partition of the set of lands. Rather obviously, this correspondence exists in the case Samuelson analysed in 1971, where it is assumed that each land is a priori a speci c factor. And, as a matter of fact, the model boils down to the supply side of Samuelson’s (1971) model under this assumption. In particular, as regards the structure of relations [7]–[14], the speci c-factors assumption implies that for each j, 1 £ j £ s, only one of the weights sij can be positive. In terms of the maximization problem mentioned in footnote 4, it implies, instead, that the problem splits up into n independent problems, whose solutions are n supply curves of the kind we introduced above. Straightforward as it may be, this is not, however, the only way in which the general equilibrium relations [7]–[14] can be used in connection with partial equilibrium analysis. In the above discussion, for example, a different use was outlined. There, indeed, we suggested that the conditions under which partial and general equilibrium responses to parametric changes in quantities coincide locally can be found equally well through the system [7]–[14]. In other words, the system can be used to nd those parts of a ‘general equilibrium supply curve’ along which a partial analysis is appropriate. We are therefore led to the analysis of land specialization associated with the growth of production (see Schefold 1990: 313). The same kind of argument can be used if external effects are considered. If they are not (at least locally) speci c to the isolated sector, then ‘[w]ith the increase in production of a commodity, if it utilises a large part of the resources of a country, the prices of very many other commodities will decrease, and thus the static system which is a necessary premise of the supply curve is overturned’ (Sraffa 1925: 363). We began this section with the aim of offering a model that rationalizes the main analytical points contained in Sraffa (1925). A summar y of what has been achieved can now be presented. The ‘Ricardo–Marshall’ system 376 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory [7]–[14] is suitable for the analysis of the local effects of parametric changes in quantities. And this analysis, that amounts to sift out Marshallian supply functions, was, as we argued in the previous sections (see also Talamo 1976; Panico 1991; Panico and Salvadori 1994), the main aim of the Sraffa 1925 critique. Specialization of lands and external effects that do not spill over to other sectors, the conditions for valid partial equilibrium analysis that Sraffa identi ed in 1925, also emerge in the present model as key elements for reaching sectors insulation. Only Sraffa’s (1925) conclusion that cases of constant costs are in some sense more frequent than cases of land specialization does not seem to be supported by the model. However, a de nitive answer to this question requires a full speci cation of the functional space from which the rent functions are drawn, and is well beyond the limits of the present analysis. 5. Echoes of the early Marshallian analysis in Production of Commodities In sub-section 3.2, we suggested that paying full attention to the effects associated with the existence of produced means of production made a break in the developmental process leading Sraffa from his early Marshallian analysis to Production of Commodities. Had the above one been the only change involved in the process, no doubt Production of Commodities would have been replete with references to the feedbacks from the new elements to the early system. In fact, ver y few things in the 1960 book are inherent to the 1925 and 1926 articles. And of these, only two allude to the way the early analysis should be amended in order to accommodate capital goods (Sraffa 1960: 76fn, see this section below, and Sraffa 1960: 74, see point (C) below). This lack of references suggests, therefore, that other major changes took place during the few years that separate the EJ paper from the rst drafts of Production of Commodities. Some information about the involved changes can be obtained from the preface of Production of Commodities. There it is stated that in the book ‘[t]he investigation is concerned exclusively with such properties of an economic system as do not depend on changes in the scale of production or in the proportion of “factors” ’ (Sraffa 1960: v). By itself this change of the subject of the analysis would then be suf cient to justify the lack of references to the problems that were at the centre of the stage in the early work. It has to be recognized, however, that Sraffa linked the above change to a shift in the method of analysis from the ‘marginal’ one, in which change is fundamental, to ‘that of the old classical economists from Adam Smith to Ricardo’ (Sraffa 1960: v), in which the produced quantities are given. It is not surprising, therefore, that the prevalent view (see e.g. Garegnani 1984) deduces from the above statement that the assumption of given quantities 377 Giuseppe Freni and the focusing of attention on changes in distribution were the joint products of the process through which Sraffa revived the classical approach. In sections 2 and 3 we saw, however, that something akin to the method of given quantities had already been adopted by Sraffa in 1925, although it was not attributed to Ricardo, who was credited, at this stage, with a constant costs theory of value (Sraffa 1925: 354). But even if we are not ready to accept that the frame of the 1925 article has a lot in common with the schemes contained in Production of Commodities, the fact remains that in 1928 Sraffa had already avoided ‘the temptation to presuppose constant returns’, and this occurred more than two years before his appointment as editor of the Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo (see Panico and Salvadori 1994). In any case, therefore, a Marshallian origin of the assumption of given quantities seems plausible. The acceptance of the Marshallian derivation of the assumption of given quantities, while leading to see more continuity in Sraffa’s analytical work than is commonly believed, does not necessarily deny the classical in uence (see also Panico and Salvadori 1994). The fact that part of this in uence was mediated by Marshall does not constitute a problem if we accept that Marshallian analysis is, as suggested by J. Robinson, ‘a cross between the theory of value and the theory of output as a whole’ (Robinson 1941: 1). In summar y, the fact that only echoes of the early analysis are perceptible in Production of Commodities seems due more to the change of subject of analysis, than to a new analytical method. We can now look for the elements of the early Marshallian analysis that survived in Production of Commodities. Before that, however, we temporarily leave this essentially historical investigation by asking whether some elements in the 1960 book have explicit bearing on the themes of Sraffa’s early analysis. And, more generally, what the full integration of produced means of production implies for the partial equilibrium conditions we mentioned in section 4. In looking in Production of Commodities for what could directly refer to the local comparative statics analysis of the 1925 paper, we can restrict the search to the only section (§88) of the book in which a change in quantities is allowed. Section 88, in particular, describes the process of intensive rent formation that follows a progressive increase of production of a single agricultural commodity. Since Sraffa considered a nite technology (see Samuelson 1959; see also section 4 above) and xed the processes of industrial commodities, then generically either one or two processes for the production of the agricultural good are operated in such a way that: the existence side by side of two methods can be regarded as a phase in the course of a progressive increase of production on the land. The increase takes place through the gradual extension of the method that produces more corn at a higher unit cost, 378 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory at the expense of the method that produces less. As soon as the former method has extended to the whole area, the rent rises to the point where a third method which produces still more corn at a still higher cost can be introduced to take the place of the method that has just been superseded. (Sraffa 1960: 76) At a rst look, the process described in this passage appears to be the same that we had encountered in the analysis contained in section 4, if a ‘kinked’ rent function had been used there instead of a ‘smooth’ one. And, more importantly, it seems remarkably similar to the process that Sraffa himself in 1925 described in his critique of Wicksteed’s distinction between ‘genuine’ and ‘spurious’ margins (Sraffa 1925: 333–5; see Panico and Salvadori 1994). A main difference between the early and the new analyses is, however, clearly enunciated in a footnote appended to the word ‘superseded’, where it is stated: ‘The change in methods of production, if it concerns a basic product, involves of course a change of [the] Standard system’ (Sraffa 1960: 76fn). This implies that the prices of all basic commodities change with a change in methods and that, therefore, land specialization is no longer suf cient for valid partial equilibrium analysis. Given the existence of produced means of production, something more is required. No hints regarding these new conditions can be found in Production of Commodities. We have to look elsewhere, in one of Samuelson’s 1971 articles modelling speci c-factors, in particular, in order to nd something related to what we are looking for. In footnote 12 of this paper it is stated: One can admit capital goods in this model in the Von Neumann-Leontief fashion provided all intermediate goods used in any industry are producible from labour and the speci c lands of those industries. (Of course, one must also specify the interest rate in each country or the equations determining it.) (Samuelson 1971: 368fn) Thus, if the requirement that the set of capital goods can be partitioned among consumption goods is satis ed, in addition to the earlier condition that lands be speci c, then we have a set of suf cient conditions for valid partial equilibrium analysis. Moreover, the rule applies besides the ‘Austrian’ framework suggested by Samuelson (that is only one of the possible ways of introducing time-phasing in the system). And in particular in the case in which produced commodities are encompassed by means of the A commodity input matrix. Its use in this latter frame implies, however, that all commodities are non-basics. The conditions discussed above are global in nature. In section 4, however, it was ventilated that linking partial equilibrium analysis with local comparative statics may be a more appropriate procedure for mimicking Sraffa’s analysis.5 In the labour-lands model of section 4, in particular, land specialization, the local correlative of the notion of speci c lands, was both 379 Giuseppe Freni necessary and suf cient for sound partial equilibrium analysis. We already mentioned that, quite obviously, the condition is no longer suf cient when produced means of production are taken into account. What perhaps may be more surprising is that neither is it necessar y. The following example makes the point clear. Example : Assume two nal commodities (commodity 1 and commodity 2) and an intermediate commodity (commodity 3) can be produced under constant returns by means of the methods in table 1. Only 35 units of land of quality [I] and 15 units of land of quality [II] are available. The economy is stationar y and the rate of interest (pro t) is zero. 1 Assume the system is in a long-run equilibrium in which 10 units of the 1 rst commodity and 10 units of the second commodity are consumed. It is easily recognized that processes [1], [2], [3] and [4] are activated. Land of quality [I] is in short supply and a positive rate of rent is paid on it. The equilibrium price (in terms of labour) of commodity [1] is equal to 52 , while the price of the other commodity is 25 . 18 If the quantity consumed of the second commodity ‘rises’ to 15 , land [II] becomes scarce and process [5] has to be activated alongside the other four processes. In the new equilibrium, the price of the second commodity 25 ‘rises’ to 16 , but the price of the rst commodity is unchanged. In a sense, the market of commodity [1] is ‘not disturbed’ and a supply schedule, based on ceteris paribus, can be used. This occurs despite the fact that land (II), on which a positive rent arises, is not specialized in growing commodity [2]. Indeed, a decrease in the rent rate paid on land [I] exactly compensates for the increase in produced inputs costs.6 Now we can search for the building blocks of Production of Commodities that were already in place in 1925. In particular, the origin of the following three structural features of Production of Commodities will be discussed:7 (A) the absence of a theor y of the rm; (B) the mentioning of only two factors that can bring about variable returns; and (C) various concepts underlying the analysis of the process of diminishing returns. Table 1 Input-Output Patterns Processes [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] 380 Material inputs Land inputs [1] [2] [3] [I] [II] .3 .5 0 .1 .2 4.5 1.5 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 .1 .1 .1 .3 .1 0 0 0 Labour inputs Outputs [1] [2] [3] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 1 0 0 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory (A) No analysis of the relationship between rms and industr y is presented in Production of Commodities. In the book, indeed, price determination is discussed directly at the level of the industry, assuming a rm-independent process of cost minimization (Sraffa 1960: 81). As mentioned in section 4, Sraffa had already in 1925 explicitly adopted this procedure for the increasing costs industries (Sraffa 1925: 341–2). Hence, at that time, he had appreciated the fact that under perceived constant returns to scale ‘it is immaterial where we draw the boundaries of the rm or whether we draw them at all’ (Samuelson 1967: 27).8 For the decreasing costs industries, however, he had employed a different procedure that made use of the U-shaped curve of a ‘representative rm’. This discrepancy calls, therefore, for an explanation. In 1925, Sraffa not only aimed at the construction of the supply curve, but he was also interested in showing how ‘the general equilibrium is the result of the series of individual equilibria which the competing rms must reach independently of one another’ (Sraffa 1925: 342). So he judged that it was ‘necessar y to reconstruct the passage from the individual supply curve to the collective curve’ (Sraffa 1925: 342). It was with this end in view that he used the U-shaped cost curve of a ‘representative rm’ (whose position was a function of the industry level of production) for the decreasing costs industries (Sraffa 1925: 350–1), while for the increasing costs industries he had ‘recourse[d] to the stratagem’ that consisted in ‘supposing that the number of producers is xed, and that each of them, with the increase in his production, cannot increase the quantity used by him of the factor of which there exists a xed quantity’ (Sraffa 1925: 343). As a matter of fact, by the ‘recourse to the stratagem’ the two cases of increasing and decreasing costs were made uniform in respect to the shape of the individual costs curve, given that the attribution to each rm of a given quantity of a constant factor amounted to the introduction of a Ushaped cost curve, whose position was made dependent on the rent level and therefore on the industry level of production (see Viner 1931). Thus when the U-shaped cost curve was used with the horizontal rm demand curve in order to nd the supply price (it was required that the two curves were tangent), also the size of the ‘representative rm’ was implicitly determined (Sraffa 1925: 350–1). Therefore, as a by-product of the attempt ‘to reconstruct the passage from the individual supply curve to the collective curve’ (Sraffa 1925: 342), a new notion: ‘the size of the representative rm’ made its appearance in Sraffa 1925 analysis. It can be safely concluded, however, that Sraffa in 1925 did not attribute any meaning to this size. This follows from the statement that under increasing returns ‘[t]he point of maximum economy could be moved in any 381 Giuseppe Freni direction because of the change [in the industr y output], corresponding to larger or smaller individual outputs’ (Sraffa 1925: 352), and from the fact that in the decreasing returns analysis the exact amount of each rm’s share of the constant factor was totally irrelevant. In summar y, in the 1925 article, the rm was introduced only to clarify how the aggregate supply curve can be obtained from the individual curves. And the want of reference to the rm in the 1960 book can thus be explained by the absence of any interest in this theme. Adapting Samuelson’s dictum to this situation, the process determined the euthanasia of the concept of rm, but given its effective role in 1925, this ‘is actually an odd way of putting the matter since what need never exist cannot very well be said to wither away’ (Samuelson 1967: 27). (B) Both in the 1925 paper and in Production of Commodities non-constant returns are due either to changes in output or to changes in the proportions of factors of production. As regards Production of Commodities this is stated in the Preface: No change in output and (at any rate in Parts I and II) no changes in the proportions in which different means of production are used by an industr y are considered, so that no question arises as to the variation or constancy of returns. (Sraffa 1960: v) In the 1925 paper, on the other side, a more speci c statement is contained at the beginning of the section on increasing costs: It is necessary to point out that the ‘supposed circumstances’, which give rise to the variation of cost [. . .] are the same in the two cases. The circumstances are that, if we consider, for simplicity’s sake, only two factors, one remains constant while the other increases. This presupposes: (a) a modi cation in the proportion between the quantities of the two factors; (b) an increase in the size of the industry. (Sraffa 1925: 327) That the change in the proportions of factors (with one of the factors maintained constant) recurring in the above passage, which is generated by the process that has been analysed in section 4, is the source of decreasing returns also in 1960, is already clear from the analysis of the emergence of intensive rent (see above). Furthermore, this interpretation is strengthened by the observation that the various concepts used in 1925 for the analysis of the process were again employed in Production of Commodities (see point (C) below). Besides the mentioning in the Preface, nothing is said in Production of Commodities about decreasing costs. However, if in Production of Commodities the uniformity of the rate of pro ts is due, as it seems likely, to competitive markets, then, as in 1925, internal economies are to be excluded from the determinants of decreasing costs (Sraffa 1925: 344–5). Again external effects remain then the only admissible source of decreasing costs (see Panico and Salvadori 1994). 382 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory (C) In sections 86–9 of Production of Commodities, the plurality of lands under cultivation is described as the result of ‘extensive’ diminishing returns and the coexistence of two methods on the same quality of land as the result of a process of ‘intensive’ diminishing returns (Sraffa 1960: 76). The processes take place because land is scarce and are shaped by the costminimizing activity of the economic agents. It is this activity that in turn generates ‘spurious margins’ (Sraffa 1960: 76, vi). The order in which lands of different qualities are put into cultivation when agricultural output grows is called the order of fertility. This order, Sraffa adds, is dependent on pro t-wage distribution (Sraffa 1960: 75). Apart from the last remark about the order of fertility, both the tools and the conclusions of the analysis were already present in the 1925 pages. The conditions under which decreasing returns occur and the cause that produces this effect were carefully speci ed by Sraffa in the 1925 paper at the beginning of the section on increasing costs. Decreasing returns, he stated, take place when different doses of variable factors are combined with a ‘constant’ factor, whose quantity cannot be increased, although it can be typically reduced ‘at the wish of the person using it’ (Sraffa 1925: 327fn 11). Hence it is only because a larger quantity of the ‘constant’ factor would be demanded, if it existed, that the phenomenon occurs. Furthermore, given the appropriate technical conditions (some possibility of substitution between factors) and applying the principle of substitution: diminishing returns must of necessity occur because it will be the producer himself who, for his own bene t, will arrange the doses of the factors and the methods of use in a descending order, going from the most favourable ones to the most ineffective, and he will start production with the best combinations, resorting little by little, as these are exhausted, to the worst ones. (Sraffa 1925: 332) In connection with the problem of the cause of diminishing returns, Sraffa then contrasted his own ‘Ricardian’ position with the position he attributed to neoclassical authors, and in particular to Wicksteed, that made decreasing returns descend from a physical law (Sraffa 1925: 335). In both the conceptions, he said, downward sloping curves are constructed and the concept of marginal dose is used, but it is only the second kind of margin that Wicksteed accepted as the foundation of the theor y of distribution (Sraffa 1925: 336). This distinction, he concluded, is however groundless since ‘any decreasing curve with a general and not merely an accidental character, must be a “descriptive curve” ’ (Sraffa 1925: 337). The main elements of the 1960 analysis are in summary the same ones described in the initial part of the section on increasing costs of the 1925 article. As regards the order of fertility, in 1925 its independence from the 383 Giuseppe Freni intensity of cultivation was examined after the just mentioned criticism of the distinction between ‘functional’ and ‘descriptive’ curves: Having examined the objection that the decreasing order of fertility in which the various pieces of land are arranged is arbitrar y, let us go on to consider another objection – the denial of the possibility of classifying the pieces of land according to their fertility, such that the ordering does not change with the increase in the intensity of cultivation. It is clear that if this were true, the construction of the static curve of diminishing returns, based on the order of fertility of the pieces of land, would no longer be conceivable. (Sraffa 1925: 338) Then, having rejected the de nitions adopted by Marshall, Malthus and J. S. Mill, the following notion of order of fertility was given:9 [I]t is best to cultivate rst of all – and must therefore be considered the most ‘fertile’ – that piece of land which, at the point at which its marginal productivity is equal to the average productivity, has a productivity greater than all other pieces of land. (Sraffa 1925: 339–40) And it was remarked: The order of fertility thus determined does not change with the intensi cation of cultivation since the form of the two productivity curves [. . .] does not change with a change in the [number of doses employed]. (Sraffa 1925: 340) In Production of Commodities, mutatis mutandis, the same chain of reasoning was employed, so that with regards to a given ordering of lands it is stated: Note that the suf xes are arbitrary and do not represent the order of fertility, which is not dened independently of the rents. (Sraffa 1960: 75, latter italics added) In conclusion, the old model elaborated in 1925 was used for the treatment of decreasing returns in the 1960 book. Of course, the aim of the analysis was different and produced means of production were integrated in the framework. The old skeleton, however, remained unchanged and is clearly discernible in what appear to be one of the oldest parts of Production of Commodities . This point can be further strengthened by arguing that the integration of produced means of production in the diminishing returns schemes contained in Production of Commodities §§85–90 is incomplete. In particular, two circumstances point to this incompleteness. The rst reduces to the following fact: (1) an unwarranted relationship between the rent rate and gross agricultural product is postulated in the treatment of intensive rent contained in §87 of the 1960 book. The second, strictly linked to fact (1), is the following: (2) The treatment of multiple agricultural commodities is oversimpli ed. (1) Section §87 of Production of Commodities opens with the following paragraph: 384 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory If land is all of the same quality and is in short supply, this by itself makes it possible for two different processes or methods of cultivation to be used consistently side by side on similar lands determining a uniform rent per acre. While any two methods would in these circumstances be formally consistent, they must satisfy the economic condition of not giving rise to a negative rent: Which implies that the method that produces more corn per acre should show a higher cost per unit of product, the cost being calculated at the ruling levels of the rate of pro ts, wages and prices. (Sraffa 1960: 75) Hence this statement contains the following postulate: the fact that a method producing a higher quantity of corn per unit of land does incur extra costs at the prices, wages and pro t rate that are associated with a method producing a lower quantity of corn per unit of land is necessar y for economic compatibility of the two methods. This is certainly true for the model in section 4 (see gure 1), but, as we will see, it does not hold in general if produced means of production are involved in the framework. To evaluate the role of produced means of production in the simplest way, we now contrast the land–labour economy of section 4 with a simple land– labour–capital economy (in which all commodities are self-reproducing nonbasics). To this end the following straightforward generalization of the rent functions can be employed. If each commodity enters its own reproduction together with labour and lands, then section 2 de nition of a process has to be enlarged to encompass the new technological conditions. Process i is therefore the triplet ai, li, ki, where 1 > ai > 0 is the commodity input per unit of production. Assume that capital decays at the rate µi, µi ³ 010, and indicate with r, r ³ 0, the rate of pro t. Then the rent function can be updated by solving the following family of problems: R(p) = min r s.t. li + rki ³ [1 2 [P1] ai(µi + r)]p, 1 £ i £ n p ³ 0, r ³ 0. Now the (generalized) derivative of the function is neither the gross output per unit of land, nor the net output per unit of land. It is instead the hypothetical net output that would result if the depreciation rate were µi + r. It is therefore a lower bound of gross and net product that is constrained to grow with the price (and the rent rate). And, in principle, nothing can be said with regard to the behaviour of the above two variables. Therefore, two methods can be economically compatible even if the one that is ‘more costly’ produces a lower quantity of corn per unit of land. 385 Giuseppe Freni The above facts cannot of course prove our point. The circumstance that the statement opening section 87 is true when produced means of production are absent, while not holding in general, could however be more than a coincidence. (2) A similar argument can be advanced with reference to the treatment of the multiplicity of agricultural products. In section 89, after some remarks on cases in which multiple agricultural products are grown on lands of different qualities, Sraffa stated that ‘in the case of a single quality of land, the multiplicity of agricultural products would not give rise to any complications’ (Sraffa 1960: 77). As before, it is simple to rationalize this statement within the bounds of a land–labour model, but it seems untenable in more general models. Indeed, if for simplicity’s sake only two products, q1 and q2, are considered, then a linear frontier can be obtained from system [7]–[14] for each positive level of the rent rate (see Samuelson’s 1959 ‘land theory of value’, Samuelson 1959: 12). Moreover, the frontier shifts outwards whenever rent increases. The above discussion of the properties of rent functions in land–labour–capital models, however, immediately implies that this comparative statics property evaporates as soon as capital goods are taken into account. Again, Sraffa’s treatment of decreasing returns ts better an ‘atemporal’ production model than a ‘time-phased’ one. 6. Concluding remarks Sraffa’s 1925 critique of Marshallian analysis calls for a general equilibrium treatment of competitive markets and this route was taken by Sraffa in 1960. However, many elements of the early analysis survived in the new framework. In a sense, the main change was in the subject of analysis. While in 1925 Sraffa focused his attention on the conditions that grant the coincidence of Marshallian supply curves with ‘general equilibrium supply curves’, in 1960 he mainly concentrated on a single point of the latter curve in order to examine the problems of distribution. In this perspective Samuelson’s works on Ricardian economics appear as the natural complements to Sraffa’s analysis. Our nal suggestion is therefore: read Sraffa’s 1925 ‘Sulle relazioni fra costo e quantità prodotta’ with Samuelson’s 1959 ‘A Modern Treatment of the Ricardian Theory’ and 1971 ‘An Exact Hume–Ricardo–Marshall Model of International Trade’ as guides, and have a look to Samuelson’s 1975 ‘Trade Pattern Reversals in Time-Phased Ricardian Systems and Intertemporal Ef ciency’ in rereading Production of Commodities. Istituto di Studi Economici, IUN, Napoli 386 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory Notes * I am grateful to Carlo Panico and Neri Salvadori for helpful discussions at all stages of the research. I also thank Heinz Kurz and a referee for many useful comments. 1 A sample from some recent articles can help to make clear the point. Consider the following passages: As soon as two competitive goods involve different land/labour proportions, the production possibility frontier is curved and not straight in the fashion Sraffa needs. (Samuelson 1990a: 268–9) I here present an impeccable Marshallian model in which (a) each of n goods is produced by transferable labour and a specialised land speci c to itself, (b) every person’s demand function for each of the n goods is strictly independent of every other good’s price or quantity (strongly additive independent utilities), (c) for every person the marginal disutility of labour is a strict constant (‘objectively’ identi able from market data). The example glaringly contradicts Sraffa’s constancy of costs and obeys all partial equilibrium requirements (at the same time that it is a full general equilibrium model, a congruence Alfred Marshall never quite achieved). (Samuelson 1990a: 268–9) Where a large difference exists between the proportions in which the factors are employed in the industry expanding its output and the proportions in which the same factors are employed in the industries that will correspondingly have to contract their output [. . .], the increase in costs cannot be ignored in the expanding industr y, but for the same reason it will not be possible to ignore it either in those other industries in which the factors are used in a proportion close to that of the expanding industry [. . .] [W]here the proportions of factors in the expanding industr y are almost the same as in the contracting industries. Here, the effect on the costs of other industries using proportions of factors close to those of the expanding industry will be small, and so will the effect on the costs of the industr y in question. (Garegnani 1990: 285) 2 For each nite set of methods, if ki > 0 for each i, then the rent function is de ned on the interval [0, ¥). We assume that the application of the operator ‘limnumber of processes®¥’ is not associated with a discontinuity of the set on which the rent function is de ned. 3 This assumption has a purely historical justi cation. In 1925 Sraffa approached the construction of increasing supply curves by means of the productivity curves (Sraffa 1925: 327–32). Within this framework, the equivalent of the differentiability of the rent function is the fact that the marginal productivity curve decreases ever ywhere. Except for the rst part of the curve, it seems that Sraffa took this fact for granted (however, cf. Sraffa 1925: 333–5, where the technology is a nite set). But he considered as normal the existence of a constant initial part of the curve. The corresponding rent function would, therefore, be ever ywhere differentiable only in ‘the extreme case in which productivity is decreasing right from the start’ (Sraffa 1925: 340fn. 42). 4 Since it can be shown that there is equivalence between equilibria and solutions of the maximization problem reported below, a proof of this result, non provided here, amounts to showing that, under the conditions in the text, a solution of the problem 387 Giuseppe Freni max ( n piqi 2 i=1 s j=1 rj) s.t. Rij(pi) £ rj, 1 £ i £ n, 1 £ j £ s pi³ 0, 1 £ i £ n rj ³ 0, 1 £ j £ s, exists for each non negative vector [qi], 1 £ i £ n. 5 Sraffa attributed this position to Marshall (see Sraffa 1925: 358–9). 6 Note that locally commodity [1] is the only basic commodity. 7 We closely follow the analysis presented in Panico and Salvadori (1994) and reach in part their conclusions. 8 It is true that, in dealing with the case in which the size of the ‘representative rm’ is indeterminate, Sraffa followed his contemporaries ‘in supposing that with ever y rm in neutral equilibrium, there would be no penalty to having one expand indefinitely until it “monopolized” the industry’ (Samuelson 1967: 29), see Sraffa (1925: 351). Sraffa’s statement was, however, appended to a secondar y passage in which the Pigouvian notion of ‘simple competition’ was discussed. 9 Remember that, in terms of the rent functions used in section 4, the order of fertility is obtained by ordering the functions according to the level of price that corresponds to a zero rent rate. 10 If the production process is discrete, then µi £ 1. References Chipman, J. S. (1970). External economies of scale and competitive equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 3, LXXXIV: 347–85. Eatwell, J. L. (1990). Comment. In K. Bharadwaj and B. Schefold (eds) Essays on Piero Sraffa: Critical Perspectives on the Revival of Classical Theory. London: Unwin and Hayman, pp. 280–3. Garegnani, P. (1984). Value and distribution in the classical economists and Marx.Oxford Economic Papers, 36: 291–325. Garegnani, P. (1990). Comment. In K. Bharadwaj and B. Schefold (eds) Essays on Piero Sraffa: Critical Perspectives on the Revival of Classical Theory. London: Unwin and Hayman, pp. 283–301. Krugman, P. and Obstfeld, M. (1991). International Economics. Glenview: Scott, Foresman and Company. Maneschi, A. (1986). A comparative evaluation of Sraffa’s ‘The laws of returns under competitive conditions’ and its Italian precursor. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 10: 1–12. Mongiovi, G. (1996). Sraffa’s critique of Marshall: a reassessment. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 20: 207–24. Newman, P. (1987). Rising supply price. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Macmillan, pp. 200–1. Panico, C. (1991). Some notes on Marshallian supply functions. Economic Journal, 101: 557–69. Panico, C. and Salvadori, N. (1994). Sraffa on returns. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 1: 323–43. Pigou, A. C. (1927). The laws of diminishing and increasing cost. Economic Journal, 37: 188–97. 388 Sraffa’s early contribution to competitive price theory Pigou, A. C. (1928). An analysis of supply. Economic Journal, 38: 238–57. Robinson, J. (1941). Rising supply price. Economica, 8: 1–8. Samuelson, P. A. (1959). A modern treatment of the Ricardian economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1–2: VLLIII: 1–35, 217–31. Samuelson, P. A. (1967). The monopolistic competition revolution. In R. E. Kuenne (ed.) Monopolistic Competition Theory: Studies in Impact. Essays in Honor of E. H. Chamberlin. New York: Wiley. Reprinted in R. C. Merton (ed.) The Collected Scientic Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, Vol. III, 1972, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, pp. 18–51. Samuelson, P. A. (1971). An exact Hume–Ricardo–Marshall model of international trade. Journal of International Economics, 1: 1–18. Reprinted in R. C. Merton (ed.) The Collected Scientic Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, Vol. III, 1972, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, pp. 356–73. Samuelson, P. A. (1975). Trade pattern reversals in time-phased Ricardian systems and intertemporal ef ciency. Journal of International Economics, 5: 309–63. Samuelson, P. A. (1987). Sraf an economics. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Macmillan. Samuelson, P. A. (1990a). Revisionist ndings on Sraffa. In K. Bharadwaj and B. Schefold (eds) Essays on Piero Sraffa: Critical Perspectives on the Revival of Classical Theor y. London: Unwin and Hayman, pp. 263–80. Samuelson, P. A. (1990b). Reply. In K. Bharadwaj and B. Schefold (eds) Essays on Piero Sraffa: Critical Perspectives on the Revival of Classical Theory. London: Unwin and Hayman, pp. 317–30. Samuelson, P. A. (1991). Sraffa’s other leg. Economic Journal, 101: 570–4. Schefold, B. (1990). Comment. In K. Bharadwaj and B. Schefold (eds) Essays on Piero Sraffa: Critical Perspectives on the Revival of Classical Theory. London: Unwin and Hayman, pp. 301–17. Sraffa, P. (1925). Sulle relazioni tra costo e quantità prodotta. Annali di economia, II: pp. 277–328. References to this article are from the English translation by Eatwell and Roncaglia ‘On the relations between costs and quantity produced’. In L. L. Pasinetti (ed.) Italian Economic Papers, Vol. III, il Mulino and Oxford University Press, 1998. Sraffa, P. (1926). The laws of returns under competitive conditions. Economic Journal, 36: 535–50. Reprinted in G. J. Stigler and K. Boulding (eds) Readings in Price Theory, 1953, London: Allen and Unwin, pp. 180–97. Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. Cambridge: CUP. Steedman, I. (1988). Sraf an interdependence and partial equilibrium analysis. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 12: 85–95. Sylos Labini, P. (1985). Sraffa’s critique of the Marshallian theory of prices. Political Economy, 1: 51–71. Talamo, O. (1976). Piero Sraffa: su alcuni problemi di interpretazione. In M. C. Marcuzzo (a cura di) Problemi e storia delle teorie economiche. Milano: Mazzotta. Viner, J. (1931). Cost curves and supply curves. Zeitschrift für National ökonomie, 3: 23–46. Vives, X. (1987). Small income effects: a Marshallian theor y of consumer surplus and downward sloping demand. Review of Economic Studies, LIV, 177: 87–103. Abstract In this paper, Sraffa’s 1925 contribution to competitive price theor y is reconsidered. It is argued that Sraffa’s 1925 framework of analysis is a 389 Giuseppe Freni ‘general’ equilibrium model of the supply side of the economy with many Ricardian features. It is suggested that Samuelson’s 1959 Ricardian model and 1971 Marshallian speci c-factors model may help re-analyse Sraffa’s 1925 work along the lines outlined above. It is also contended that the elements of continuity between Sraffa’s early work and Production of Commodities are more pronounced than commonly believed. Keywords Sraffa, partial vs. general equilibrium, supply curves, speci c-factors models 390
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz