CASE NO. 8715 1__ I. INTRODUCTION Q. PLEASE STATE YOUR NAME AND BUSINESS ADDRESS. A. My name is John W. Mayo. My address is Department of Economics, The University of Tennessee, Knoxville, Tennessee. Q. ARE YOU THE SAME JOHN W. MAYO WHO FILED DIRECT TESTIMONY IN THIS PROCEEDING? A. Yes. Q. WHAT IS THE PURPOSE OF YOUR TESTIMONY? A. I have been asked by AT&T to review and comment on the testimonies of the other parties in this case. testimony will focus on In particular, my key areas that were either insufficiently or incorrectly addressed by the other parties to this case in their direct testimony. To do so, I will first offer several general observations that may be gleaned from the direct testimonies in this case. Second, I will address arguments made by various parties that either (1) it is unnecessary to establish efficient carrier access rates in this proceeding, or (2) the prevailing access rates are in any sense defensible. Third, I will address the adequacy of the "safeguards" that have been proposed in the various alternative regulation proposals that have been proffered. Finally, I will address some miscellaneous concerns that stem from the testimony of other parties. II. Q. GENERAL OBSERVATIONS IS THERE AGREEMENT THAT ANY ALTERNATIVE REGULATION PLAN FOR BELL ATLANTIC-MARYLAND (BA-MD) SHOULD BOTH PROMOTE AND PROTECT COMPETITION? A. Yes. In my direct testimony, I pointed out that a competition enabling policy -- one that acts both to promote and protect competition -- is vital to the development of a successful alternative regulation policy. This view is predicated upon the belief that policies designed to promote effective competition and to protect the competitive process are ultimately the most desirable and most likely to best promote the public interest in Maryland. Several other witnesses expressed support for these underlying tenets of my testimony. For example, Staff witness Mr. Waldau states "the goal of price cap regulation should be to promote economic efficiency, which includes regulating prices so that they emulate economic performance of competitive markets as closely as possible until effective competition exists.1 The goal should also be to encourage the transition to competition where feasible."2 Similarly, BA-MD witness Professor Kahn notes that the Commission should "continue its efforts to create the necessary conditions for competition ubiquitously in telecommunications and to be prepared to abandon direct regulation wherever those efforts succeed."3 Dr. Johnson, who testifies on behalf of OPC, also notes that "effective competition does not always prevail in our 1 See Direct Testimony of Geoffrey Waldau ("Waldau Direct") at 13. 2 3 Id. See Direct Testimony of Dr. Alfred E. Kahn ("Kahn Direct") at 7. economy, but it represents an ideal to strive towards, since it provides a high degree of efficiency and equity."4 Q. DO THE PARTIES TO THIS CASE AGREE THAT THE MERITS OF AN ALTERNATIVE REGULATION PLAN DEPEND CRITICALLY UPON THE STARTING RATES THAT ARE ESTABLISHED FOR BA-MD? A. Yes. The consideration of an alternative regulatory plan for BA-MD provides a golden opportunity for the Commission to fully avail itself of the opportunity to promote and protect competition by establishing an efficient, competitive-like set of prices at the outset of the price cap plan. In the case at hand, there is disagreement about what those beginning prices should be, but there appears to be a virtual consensus on the importance of establishing a suitable set of beginning prices for the alternative regulatory plan.5 Q. A. DO THE PARTIES AGREE THAT SAFEGUARDS SHOULD BE AN IMPORTANT ELEMENT OF ANY ALTERNATIVE REGULATION PLAN THAT IS ADOPTED IN MARYLAND? Yes, while there is disagreement about the speed or conditions under which the Commission may safely move to eliminate direct regulation of the services of BA-MD, there appears to be little disagreement with the proposition that an adequate set of competitive safeguards are necessary for any successful alternative regulatory plan. I discussed the need for, and nature of, such safeguards at some length in my direct 4 See Direct Testimony of Ben Johnson, Ph.D. ("Johnson Direct") at 8. See, e.g., Affidavit of Alfred E. Kahn, p.11; Johnson Direct at 25-26; Waldau Direct at 22-23. 5 testimony.6 Other parties also acknowledge the need for such safeguards. For example, Mr. Waldau notes that "Competitive safeguards are needed to ensure that new competitors have a fair opportunity to compete."7 Similarly, Dr. Johnson of OPC notes the need for safeguards 8. BA-MD implicitly acknowledges the importance of competitive safeguards by including the claim that the safeguards embedded in the BA-MD proposal will "encourage the growth of full and fair competition...."9 MCI's economist, Dr. Cornell, also acknowledges that "[c]ompetitive safeguards are an absolute necessity if the prices for essential monopoly input functions are not set at direct economic cost."10 Safeguards are nothing new to this Commission, since appropriate safeguards have been a part of each flexible regulation plan since 1988.11 I will discuss the adequacy of the proposed safeguards later in my testimony. For the moment though, it is important to recognize the consensus that any Commission plan for alternative regulation must embody an adequate set of competitive safeguards if the new regulatory 6 7 8 9 See Direct testimony of John W. Mayo ("Mayo Direct"), pp. 8-20. Waldau Direct at 22-23. Johnson Direct at 85-86. See Direct Testimony of Daniel J. Whelan ("Whelan Direct"), at 16. See Supplemental Direct Testimony of Dr. Nina W. Cornell ("Cornell Supplemental Direct") at 89. Perhaps, inadvertantly, the implication of Dr. Cornell's passage may be taken to mean that, if prices are set at economic cost, then competitive safeguards are unnecessary. While this is true of imputation, other competitive safeguards (e.g., unbundling and resale) remain necessary. 11 See In the Matter of C&P of Maryland Proposal for Regulatory Reform Trial, Case No. 8106, Order No. 68115, June 30, 1988. 10 regime is to accomplish the goals established in the guiding legislation. III. CARRIER ACCESS PRICING Q. HAVE YOU REVIEWED THE PROPOSED ADJUSTMENTS TO CARRIER ACCESS PRICING THAT ARE EMBEDDED IN THE VARIOUS ALTERNATIVE REGULATION PLANS? A. Yes. Both the Staff and MCI plans make significant adjustments to the price of carrier access central to their proposals for alternative regulation. In contrast, BA-MD proposes to retain the current access charge rates until 1998 and allow for price increases after that time by up to the annual rate of inflation less 1.5 percent. Finally, the OPC plan acknowledges a need for carrier access charge reductions, but balks at the prospect for the changes advocated by Staff and MCI. Q. WHAT IS THE RATIONALE FOR THE REDUCTIONS IN CARRIER ACCESS RATES PROPOSED BY STAFF AND MCI? A. The rationale is severalfold. As Mr. Waldau notes, reductions in switched access rates to the levels embodied in the rates for local call termination will promote economic efficiency and reduce retail rates.12 My only quibble here is that, while it is true that there will be "long-run" benefits from the competition sparked by competitive input pricing, consumers will also clearly benefit in the short run as reductions in carrier access charges lead directly to reductions in toll rates for Maryland consumers. Similarly, Dr. Cornell notes that "Unless [the rates for the monopoly switched access functions] are set at direct economic cost, interexchange markets cannot bring rates for interexchange offerings down to social cost, but will 12 Waldau Direct at 94. continue to hold rates for these services above that level."13 The approach adopted by these parties is highly congruent with the economic guideposts that I offered in my direct testimony. In particular, I pointed out that by reducing the price of carrier access services to reflect its underlying incremental costs, several specific benefits inure to consumers, including the promotion of allocative efficiency, the sending of correct price signals to consumers, and the generation of efficient signals to potential investors regarding the costs that are being incurred by incumbent firms to provide the service. In sum, the proposed adjustments to the price of carrier access charges being proposed by Staff and MCI are entirely warranted on economic grounds. Q. WHAT POSITION HAS OPC TAKEN WITH RESPECT TO THE PRICE OF CARRIER ACCESS CHARGES? A. OPC, too, recommends that access charges be reduced. The rationale proffered by OPC is, however, somewhat peculiar and is atavistic in its treatment of carrier access charges. Specifically, rather than viewing the establishment of efficient carrier access prices as a necessary prerequisite to the promotion of economic efficiency, competition, and the realization of consumer benefits, OPC seems to view the desire for access charge reductions simply to spring from its belief that BA-MD is in a position of overearning. Consequently, and without specific justification, OPC recommends that the prices of essentially all BA-MD services, including carrier access, be 13 Cornell Direct at 38. dropped by the same 23 percent across the board.14 The result of this exercise is that the price recommendation for carrier access by OPC fails to fully promote economic efficiency, competition, universal service, and the consequent realization of consumer benefits that stem from these goals. Q. HOW DO YOU EVALUATE THE NOTION BY OPC THAT, ON THE BASIS OF COST ALLOCATIONS, THE PRICING OF CARRIER ACCESS AT PREVAILING OR ONLY MODESTLY REDUCED LEVELS CAN BE DEFENDED? A. The notion of establishing prices based upon allocated, or fully-distributed, cost which is embraced by OPC, has been thoroughly rejected by the mainstream economics profession.15 Indeed, there are a variety of reasons for this rejection. First, such allocations are inherently arbitrary and would only coincide with economically efficient prices by the most remote random possibility.16 Second, in the event that regulated markets are opened to entry, cost allocation-based pricing is quite likely to lead to distortions in competition. Specifically, cost allocation-based-pricing methods force a deviation of prices from incremental cost that sends inappropriate and inaccurate signals to both consumers and prospective new entrants regarding the costs of incrementally providing the service. Third, because Johnson Direct at 73, lines 7-10. See, e.g., Ronald R. Braeutigam "An Analysis of Fully Distributed Cost Pricing in Regulated Industries," Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 11, 1980, pp.182-96; George Sweeney "Welfare Implications of Fully Distributed Cost Pricing Applied to Partially Regulated Firms," Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 13, 1982, pp.525533; and William J. Baumol, et al., "How Arbitrary is 'Arbitrary?' -or, Toward the Deserved Demise of Full Cost Allocation," Public Utilities Fortnightly, September 3, pp. 16-21. 14 15 16 Ibid. such allocations are based upon the judgment of the analyst, the resulting prices are more likely to reflect the philosophical beliefs of the analyst regarding a "fair" set of end-user prices than if such allocations were excluded from the analysis.17 As a result, any Commission that begins down the path of fully distributed cost must be prepared to engage in endless debates to determine the "fair" allocation of loop costs to be borne by the price of subscription. The alternative view, I believe embraced by most economists, is that not only is economic efficiency most clearly tied to marginal (or as it is typically measured in the telecommunications industry, incremental) cost pricing, but that it is also arguably "fair" for consumers to pay for the costs that they cause to be incurred through the act of becoming and remaining subscribers to the public switched network. Thus, the argument that such cost allocations are necessary or desirable is surely incorrect as a logical proposition. Moreover, the cost allocations that have historically kept carrier access charges high has been shown Given the judgmental features of such allocations, one can, independent of sound economic reasoning, question particular applications as problematical if they do not yield the outcome one desires. For example, according to OPC, one of the problems with requiring telecommunications subscribers to pay for the costs caused by that subscription (which include the cost of the loop) is that such cost-causative pricing limits the extent of price reductions that are available for local exchange customers. See Prepared Testimony of Trevor R. Roycroft ("Roycroft Direct") at 21. 17 empirically to have virtually no beneficial effects on the achievement of universal service.18 See David L. Kaserman, et al., "Cross-Subsidization in Telecommunications: Beyond the Universal Service Fairy Tale," Journal of Regulatory Economics, Vol. 2, September 1990, pp. 231-251. 18 Q. BUT WHAT ABOUT OPC'S CLAIM THAT THE COSTS OF THE LOCAL LOOP IS A JOINT COST AND THEREFORE THESE COSTS MUST NECESSARILY BE RECOUPED THROUGH AN ALLOCATION MECHANISM? A. I disagree. It is well-known in the economic analysis of the telecommunications industry that there is a well-defined demand for, and supply of, access to the telecommunications network. The costs of providing that access can, and should, be borne by the consumers that cause these costs to be incurred. Q. DOES THE USE OF "SHAPLEY VALUES" RECTIFY THESE PROBLEMS? (ROYCROFT DIRECT AT 26-28) A. No. I am unpersuaded that employing the concept of "Shapley Values" circumvents any of the well-known problems with other fully distributed cost methodologies. For instance, while the development of "Shapley costs" are alleged to "create an incremental cost estimate," it is clear that such estimates are based upon cost allocation methods that have nothing to do with the key concept of incremental cost analysis -- cost causation. Instead, costs are allocated to various services based upon the assigned probabilities of a consumer subscribing to a particular service. Given Dr. Roycroft's two-service assumption, each service is "assigned" 50 percent of the shared loop costs. This allocation is, of course, no more defensible from an economic perspective than the allocation of such costs to a particular service on the basis of relative revenues, minutes of use, occurrence of directly attributable costs, income of the subscriber or any other allocator. It is because of this arbitrary nature of such allocation schemes that the economic profession has been so critical of their use for pricing particular services. Q. HOW DO YOU RESPOND TO THE CHARGE THAT, IF ALL SERVICE PRICES OF A LOCAL EXCHANGE CARRIER WERE SET EQUAL TO DIRECT ECONOMIC COSTS, THE FIRM WOULD NOT BE FINANCIALLY VIABLE? (ROYCROFT DIRECT AT 13) A. It is important to put this discussion in perspective. In my direct testimony, I pointed out that there are a number of benefits from establishing competitive-like prices. Where competition is effective, this task is best left to market forces. Thus, any alternative regulatory mechanism adopted by the Commission should permit BA-MD the opportunity to demonstrate that a service faces effective competition and, once having made such a showing, permit it to enjoy price flexibility. Where, however, services continue to be supplied under conditions of significant monopoly power, market forces cannot be relied upon to generate competitive prices. In such cases, direct regulation of prices -- with a competitive market guidepost of incremental cost -- provides a very compelling target upon which to base prices. Indeed, it is firmly established that in competitive markets prices are driven toward, and in long run equilibrium to, marginal cost.19 I have earlier described a host of economic benefits from such a pricing philosophy, including, inter alia, See, for example, Paul A. Samuelson and William Nordaus, Economics, Twelfth Edition, McGraw-Hill Book Company, New York, 1985, pp. 480-488. 19 the promotion of economic efficiency, competition, and proper investment and entry signals.20 The issue raised by OPC, then, must be seen not as a rebuttal of these benefits, which are, I believe, essentially incontrovertible, but rather a challenge to incremental cost-based pricing on practical grounds. Specifically, it is asserted that if the prices charged for all the firm's services are set equal to incremental cost, the financial viability of the regulated firm may come into question. To my knowledge, however, none of the proposals in this case, including both Staff and MCI's plans, propose setting all of the firm's products equal to their respective incremental costs. It is my understanding that the Staff and MCI plans call only for the establishment of incremental cost-based prices for carrier access that remains subject to supply under conditions of significant monopoly power. Moreover, under both the Staff and MCI plans, increased incentive to earn profits and the latitude to retain those profits is afforded BA-MD, as it is able to operate in a price cap environment. Specifically, under any of the proposed alternative regulatory regimes, BA-MD will be able to retain earnings and will be able to transition effectively competitive services into widespread pricing In this vein, see also, Samuelson and Nordaus, ibid, who state "Only when price of goods are equal to marginal cost is the economy squeezing from its scarce resources and limited technical knowledge the maximum of outputs." 20 flexibility. Also, as noted by Mr. Wood and Mr. Dionne, the amount of contribution in excess of the incremental costs incurred by BA-MD remains high and the financial viability of BA-MD is not seriously challenged by adopting efficient pricing of carrier access.21 21 Wood Rebuttal at 10 ; Dionne Rebuttal at 14. Q. A. ARE THERE OTHER TECHNICAL REASONS WHY DR. ROYCROFT IS TROUBLED BY THE IDEA OF ESTABLISHING THE PRICE OF CARRIER ACCESS TO REFLECT ITS INCREMENTAL COST? Yes. Another, somewhat technical, issue raised by Dr. Roycroft (p. 13) centers around whether local exchange companies remain subject to pervasive economies of scale and scope. If such economies exist to the point of creating natural monopoly supply conditions, as appears to be Dr. Roycroft's belief, then it is true that establishing all of the firm's services at their incremental costs will result in a revenue shortfall for the firm. With respect to this potential for natural monopoly, I am, however, considerably more agnostic than Dr. Roycroft. In particular, recent economic evidence has appeared to suggest that the local exchange companies are not subject to pervasive economies of scale and scope and that, as a result, they are not natural monopolies.22 Presumably, policymakers also agree with this assessment, as they have increasingly embraced the notion of the desirability of competition in telecommunications markets. Given the prospect that the market is capable of sustaining competitive-like prices, it would seem to be unnecessary for this Commission to maintain contributionladen carrier access prices to protect the financial viability of a firm under a "natural monopoly theory" of revenue shortfall. Indeed, a significant risk of such a See Richard T. Shin and John S.Ying, RAND Journal of Economics, "Unnatural Monopolies in Local Telephone," Vol. 23, Summer 1992, pp 171-183. 22 strategy is that by ladening such input prices with such "make-whole" revenues, the incumbent firm is essentially protected from having these revenues and any excess costs that lie behind them competed away. The result of such an approach, then, would be that the incumbent would be "made whole" but at the cost of diminishing, or even removing, the prospects for competition. I cannot imagine that such a policy is what the Maryland Legislature had in mind when it indicated that an alternative regulation plan adopted by the Commission should be one that "encourages the development of competition."23 Q. A. IS OPC CORRECT IN ITS CLAIM THAT PRICES FOR LOCAL EXCHANGE SERVICE THAT FULLY REFLECT THE COST CAUSED BY SUBSCRIPTION WILL CAUSE PRICES FOR LOCAL SERVICE TO BE INFLEXIBLE? (ROYCROFT, P. 22) No. The establishment of a price cap regime, which is embodied in the plans of Staff, MCI, BA-MD, and OPC all allow for price flexibility of local exchange services. The lower bound on such price decreases is properly determined by the TSLRIC (or, as necessary, an imputed price floor). Q. DR. JOHNSON ARGUES THAT RATE INCREASES FOR TERMINATING ACCESS COULD "FUND A REDUCTION IN ORIGINATING RATES." DO YOU AGREE? A. No. The notion that the Commission can address the problems caused by the present level of access charges simply by raising some carrier access prices and reducing others is a throwback to a time when the rates of a regulated monopoly could 23 Md.Code Ann. art.78, Sec. 69(e) (1995) be manipulated to accomplish perceived social goals without distorting competition. That time is gone.24 The solution today to the problem of inefficient pricing of carrier access is not to tweak the rate structure of carrier access charges in hopes of either (1) preserving revenue flows to the incumbent LEC, or (2) making it more difficult for competition to work to reduce interexchange prices. Rather, the solution is straightforward -- to establish a set of price levels that accurately reflect the incremental cost imposed by additional purchases of carrier access service. Q. DR. JOHNSON ARGUES THAT INCREASES IN COMPETITION "SHOULD EVENTUALLY DRIVE DOWN THE OVERALL LEVEL OF SWITCHED ACCESS RATES."25 CAN YOU COMMENT? A. costs. Yes. Competition does act to drive prices toward The problem with Dr. Johnson's apparent advocacy of a market-based solution to the overpricing of carrier access, however, is that, as he correctly acknowledges elsewhere "The evidence suggests that access markets are characterized by monopoly conditions...."26 Moreover, Dr. Johnson similarly acknowledges that "'bypass' never grew as rapidly as predicted" Indeed, the underlying logic employed by Dr. Johnson here in advocating a rate design fix to the carrier access problem is precisely the logic against which he objects when it is employed by BA-MD to justify "rate rebalancing." Specifically, it is the belief that it is acceptable to raise prices where competitive pressure is lax (here, terminating access) to "fund" reductions in other rates (here, originating access). 24 25 26 Johnson Direct at 47. Johnson Direct at 47. despite years of pricing access well in excess of its incremental cost.27 Thus, to this point, there is essentially no evidence that market forces can provide the competitive pressure necessary to achieve efficient prices of switched access charges. To the extent, then, that the present condition of the access market is one of significant monopoly power, the assurance that competition will "eventually" provide improvements in access charge rates is small consolation to those who prefer to see an alternative regulatory mechanism encourage competition as embraced by the Maryland statute. Q. BA-MD HAS PROPOSED THAT CARRIER ACCESS RATES FACE A HARD CAP UNTIL 1998. THEN RATES MAY INCREASE ACCORDING TO THE INDEXED PRICE FORMULA. DO YOU AGREE WITH BA-MD'S PROPOSAL? A. No. The present rates for carrier access are many multiples of their corresponding incremental cost.28 Economic efficiency can be readily and immediately promoted by reducing these rates, so the idea embedded in the BA-MD plan to freeze these rates would simply have the effect of locking in a set of distortionary, economically inefficient rates. Q. MR. WHELAN APPEARS TO DEFEND THE PRESENT SET OF ACCESS CHARGE RATES BY NOTING THAT THEY ARE "PRESUMED REASONABLE UNDER THE LAW."29 DO YOU FIND THE PRESENT LEGALITY OF SUCH RATES TO BE A BASIS UPON WHICH TO RETAIN SUCH PRICES? A. No. I am not a lawyer and, therefore, cannot offer a legal opinion. However, I would note that a variety of economically indefensible rates and practices have historically been legitimized under monopoly regulation as "reasonable." 27 28 29 Id. at 56. Wood Rebuttal at 10-11. Whelan Direct at 18. It seems altogether obvious that such rates and practices that may have been held to be reasonable under a monopoly regulation regime become unreasonable under a public policy standard of promoting competition. Moreover, I am surprised at Mr. Whelan's defense of the present rate structure on the grounds that it is consistent with history.30 In particular, Mr. Whelan argues that, historically, regulatory bodies have "devised numerous mechanisms to subsidize basic telephone rates and thus promote universal service" and that "basic residential rates have also been set residually.31" While this characterization of the historical pattern of pricing telephone services is true, it is precisely these practices that must now be eliminated if competition is to develop. Indeed, Mr. Whelan implicitly acknowledges this fact when he notes that it is these historical methods of pricing that have led to a situation where "the rates BA-MD now charges are out-of-balance in relation to costs."32 Professor Kahn, too, appears to embrace the proposition that historical regulatory policies preclude efficient pricing on a forward-going basis. See Affidavit of Alfred E. Kahn at 16. To the extent that Professor Kahn is correct that historical policies have kept rates below their economically efficient levels, then the direct solution would seem to be to take this opportunity to fix those rates rather than perpetuating the current economically inefficient pricing of carrier access rates. 30 31 Whelan Direct at 20. Whelan Direct at 21. To the extent that rates are "out-ofbalance" with costs, and if, as claimed, rates for basic exchange service in some areas are below their costs, then the public policy merits of BA-MD's proposed price cap plan become even more questionable since it fails to fix the problem. 32 IV. SAFEGUARDS Q. MR. WHELAN CLAIMS THAT THE BA-MD PLAN ENCOURAGES THE DEVELOPMENT OF COMPETITION THROUGH THE IMPOSITION OF COMPETITIVE SAFEGUARDS. CAN YOU COMMENT? A. Yes. Several aspects of the BA-MD proposal fall short of the standard of encouraging the development of competition. Most notably, BA-MD's failure to significantly adjust carrier access prices misses the present opportunity to as fully as possible "encourage the development of the competition." As I have stressed throughout my direct and reply testimonies, it is unacceptable to maintain the present, grossly overpriced level of carrier access charges as a baseline for the initiation of an alternative regulation plan. These services, that remain subject to supply under conditions of significant monopoly power, are priced at levels that are many multiples of their incremental costs and, under the BA-MD proposal, there is no assurance that such prices will ever approach their economically efficient levels. AT&T witness Mr. Darrah discusses in detail the specific safeguards proposed by BA-MD witness Vaden, and the safeguards that should be a part of any alternative regulatory plan for BA-MD. Q. CAN YOU COMMENT ON MR. WHELAN'S CLAIM33 THAT COMPETITION IS NOT HARMED BY THE RETENTION OF THE EXTANT CARRIER ACCESS CHARGE RATES BECAUSE BA-MD IS "SUBJECT TO PAYMENT OR IMPUTATION OF THE SAME [ACCESS] CHARGES" AS IXCS? 33 Whelan Direct at 19. A. claim. There are at least two problems with Mr. Whelan's First, the carrier access charges IXCs pay to BA-MD are very real, explicit payments across companies that constitute costs to the IXCs whether or not those costs are justified from an economic perspective. In contrast, the "payment" of such charges by BA-MD to itself is not an explicit cost and therefore is not in any real sense a payment to itself for the provision of access. Because such charges are not real costs to BA-MD, but rather only an accounting fiction, it provides little solace on the "competitive safeguards" front to say, as does Mr. Whelan, that BA-MD is subject to the same payments as are the IXCs. Indeed, the difference between the high price of access and its much lower incremental cost flows to the benefit of BA-MD and its shareholders. Second, the assurance by Mr. Whelan that BA-MD is subject to imputation is problematic given that the particular imputation standard BA-MD proposes is inadequate. Specifically, my understanding of the imputation requirement proposed by BA-MD requires only that the prices charged will cover "the access charges it imposes on interexchange carriers...."34 Yet, it is by this time well established that for services where imputation is appropriate, the retail rates should recover both the access charge and the incremental cost of its own retail operations. By omitting these latter costs from the imputation standard, BA-MD has erred in the development of adequate competitive safeguards. Attachment B to Petition of Bell Atlantic - Maryland, Inc. for Adoption of a Price Cap Form of Alternative Regulation ("Petition") at 4. 34 Q. A. IN YOUR DIRECT TESTIMONY, YOU ADDRESSED THE NEED FOR, AND THE GUIDEPOSTS TO, THE DETERMINATION OF THE LEVEL OF COMPETITION. HAVE OTHER PARTIES SIMILARLY NOTED THE NEED TO ESTABLISH A STANDARD FOR THE DETERMINATION OF EFFECTIVE COMPETITION? Yes. There is widespread agreement that where competition is effective, BA-MD should enjoy, and consumers will benefit from, essentially all of the marketplace freedoms of competitors with no significant market power.35 At the same time, however, there is also widespread agreement that the time has not yet arrived when BA-MD faces widespread effective competition for the large majority of its services. As a result, several other parties have acknowledged the need to adopt an effective competition standard for the movement of services into a "competitive" basket. Q. A. WHAT SPECIFIC STANDARDS FOR THE DETERMINATION OF EFFECTIVE COMPETITION HAVE BEEN OFFERED BY BA-MD? BA-MD has proposed a three-part showing to categorize a new service or reclassify an existing service as "competitive." ("Competitive Service Standard"36) Specifically, BA-MD proposes to show that (a) entry into the market for the service is unimpeded by technical or legal constraints; (b) there are economically viable competitors for the provision of the service; Note though that the presence of significant monopoly power in the provision of some of its services and effective competition in others will require that competitive safeguards (e.g., unbundling and resale) remain in place. 35 36 Attachment B, Petition at 1 and (c) like or substitutable services are available at rates and terms of service which allow the market to assure that rates for the service will be just and reasonable. Q. A. CAN YOU COMMENT ON THE ADEQUACY OF THESE PARTICULAR CRITERIA? Yes. The economic merits of classifying a service as "competitive" turn upon an accurate determination of whether a service faces effective competition or not. In this regard, the proposed criteria are a step in the right direction toward creating such a filter. They do not, however, fully reflect the requirements for effective competition that spring from the antitrust economic literature. For example, while correctly pointing the Commission toward an examination of technical and legal barriers to entry, the BA-MD proposed criteria are essentially silent on the matter of economic barriers to entry. Additional marketplace information, suggested by the economic literature on market power, point toward a more thorough set of competitive criteria than are presently embodied in the BA-MD "Competitive Service Standard." Because of this looseness in the BA-MD criteria, I believe that a more complete set of indicators may be developed and implemented to determine whether a particular service provided by BA-MD is provided subject to effective competition. Q. WHAT SPECIFIC CRITERIA PROVIDE A RELIABLE BASIS UPON WHICH A DETERMINATION OF "EFFECTIVE COMPETITION" CAN BE REACHED? A. The general guideposts for the determination of "effective competition" were laid out in my direct testimony.37 A specific set of criteria that I believe would provide the Commission with a reliable basis upon which to determine whether a service offered by BA-MD is effectively competitive include (1) a determination of the breadth of the relevant market; (2) market share characteristics of BA-MD in the relevant market;38 (3) available evidence on the ease of entry and exit; (4) factors that facilitate or inhibit the ability of entrants and competitors to expand capacity and capture sales; (5) factors that facilitate or inhibit the willingness to switch providers; (6) the price elasticity of demand in the relevant market; and (7) market data on the percent of customers for whom choices are available and the percentage who have availed themselves of such choice. I should note here that Staff has alluded to a similar set of competitive filters such as the "supply and demand elasticities, ease of competitive entry, availability of comparable competitive services, customer awareness of competitive choices, the amount of customer switching service providers and fluctuations in market share, pricing trends, and LEC pricing below price cap allowed levels."39 Q. 37 HAS THE STAFF OFFERED ADDITIONAL COMPETITIVE STANDARDS? Mayo Direct at 9-10. The need to exercise extrordinary caution in the interpretation of market share statistics is well known. See, e.g., William M. Landes and Richard A. Posner, Market Power in Antitrust Cases, 94 Harv. L. Rev. 937 (1981). 39 Waldau Direct at 83. 38 A. The Staff has pointed toward the application of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) as a mechanism to determine whether a BA-MD service is competitive under any new price cap regulation. Q. CAN YOU COMMENT ON THE STAFF'S APPLICATION OF THE HHI TO DETERMINE WHETHER A SERVICE PROVIDED BY BA-MD FACES EFFECTIVE COMPETITION? A. Yes. Although the HHI has a longstanding history of use in the antitrust arena, I am reluctant to embrace its application in the context of a proceeding to determine whether a firm (in this case BA-MD) enjoys significant monopoly power or, alternatively, faces effective competition. In particular, the use of the HHI by the Department of Justice is primarily in the context of merger analysis which is driven by Section 7 of the Clayton Act. That statute is, however, widely perceived by antitrust scholars to be a prophylactic law that is designed to halt the development of market power in its incipiency.40 Such an "incipiency" standard and the corresponding concentration thresholds embodied in the DOJ/FTC Merger Guidelines are, therefore, less applicable to an analysis of unilateral market power held by an incumbent LEC. V. MISCELLANEOUS ISSUES Q. MR. WALDAU PROPOSES TO CONSIDER THE ADOPTION OF A COMPREHENSIVE UNIVERSAL SERVICE FUNDING MECHANISM IN A SEPARATE PROCEEDING. CAN YOU COMMENT? See Roger D. Blair and David L. Kaserman Antitrust Economics, Richard D. Irwin, 1985, p. 226. 40 A. Yes. The adoption of an alternative regulatory mechanism provides a golden opportunity to take tangible steps toward moving to an efficient universal service mechanism and it is, therefore, vital that progress toward that effort not be deferred. In this regard, I am heartened to note that the proposal by Staff recommends a three-part phase-down of the illconceived historical source of "funding" universal service. Moreover, the reductions in long distance rates and the stimulation to competition that will result from the modifications to the historically distorted access charge rates will act to stimulate household subscription in Maryland. Thus, the proposal by Staff, as well as the proposal of MCI, make tangible and well-reasoned progress on the universal service front. The key in this regard is that the Commission take this opportunity to end the grossly inefficient and ineffective method of funding universal service that has historically imposed distortions on the prices of upstream inputs that must be purchased by downstream competitors. In light of this progress, the Commission could then take up additional universal service issues, specifically the design of an efficient funding and targeting mechanism in a separate proceeding. If, however, the Commission chooses to move forward with a universal service funding and distribution mechanism at this time, I strongly recommend that it follow the criteria for an efficient universal service mechanism that I proffered in my direct testimony.41 41 Mayo Direct at 25-32. Mr. Wood has begun to describe in his testimony the tangible steps that are necessary to operationalize these criteria.42 Q. DR. JOHNSON ARGUES THAT IT WILL NOT PRECLUDE COMPETITION IF THE PRICE OF AN UNBUNDLED LOOP SOLD TO LOCAL EXCHANGE COMPETITORS IS GREATER THAN THE RETAIL PRICE OF LOCAL EXCHANGE SERVICE. DO YOU AGREE? A. No. Indeed, I am really quite surprised by Dr. Johnson's logic here. Unbundled local loops are potentially a very important input into the provision of local exchange service by competitors to BA-MD. Yet, Dr. Johnson appears to be saying that the viability of competition is unaffected if the price of that input exceeds the retail rate for local exchange service. He argues, in essence, that a set of input prices (i.e., the price of the local loop) may be greater than retail rates because new entrants can make up the difference by "other sources of revenue". The flaw in this reasoning, however, is at least two-fold. First, a vertical price squeeze is defined by a situation in which a vertically integrated provider establishes a set of prices for an upstream input such that the firm could not profitably sell the downstream service (here, basic exchange service) at prevailing rates if it were made to pay the same price for the input that it is charging its rivals. Thus, Dr. Johnson's belief that unbundled loop prices in excess of retail basic exchange rates are competitively acceptable is squarely at odds with the concept of an anticompetitive vertical price squeeze. 42 Second, the prospect of depending on revenue from other Wood Rebuttal at 22-24. "sources of revenue" may have been possible in a monopoly environment, but is no longer acceptable in an era when public policy must be driven to "encourage the development of competition." Public policy must allow for the emergence of competition on its merits in individual service offerings through the pricing of those offerings. It is a huge stretch in this situation to argue that competition is not denied because revenues from other services may be used to make up the shortfall caused by pricing unbundled loops at prices that exceed retail rates. Q. DOES THIS CONCLUDE YOUR TESTIMONY? A. Yes.
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz