A POST-KEYNESIAN MACRODYNAMIC SIMULATION MODEL FOR AN OPEN ECONOMY Marcelo de Oliveira Passos José Luís Oreiro Marcelo de Oliveira Passos PhD student at Department of Economics of Federal University of Paraná. (UFPR). Project Development Analyst of Regional Development Bank of Extreme-South of Brazil (Banco Regional de Desenvolvimento do Extremo Sul – BRDE). Professor of Tuiuti University of Parana State (Universidade Tuiuti do Paraná – UTP). E-mail: [email protected]. Website: http://marcelo-passos.sites.uol.com.br. José Luís Oreiro Phd in Economics (Federal University of Rio de Janeiro – UFRJ). Professor at Department of Economics at Federal University of Paraná (UFPR). Researcher of National Conseul of Technological and Scientific Development (Conselho Nacional de Desenvolvimento Científico e Tecnológico – CNPQ). E-mail: [email protected] and [email protected] Website: http://www.joseluisoreiro.ecn.br. 1 ABSTRACT: The objective of this article is to present the structure and first simulation results of a post-keynesian macro-dynamic model for an open economy with floating exchange rates and imperfect mobility of capital. The model to be presented integrates both the real and financial aspects of post-keynesian economics in a dynamic framework where real output is demand determined, investment is driven by Minsky´s two price theory, money is endogenous, technical progress is determined by a Kaldorian technical progress function and net exports are an important component of aggregate demand. Domestic capitalists can store their wealth in foreign bonds, so there is imperfect mobility of capital. After the presentation of the basic structure of model, one can perform its computational simulation and, then, infer the dynamic trajectories of endogenous variables. Simulated trajectories reflect some general features of the dynamic of capitalists economies, especially the existence of irregular fluctuations of the growth rates of real output. The analysis of the external sector of the economy shows that the long-run dynamic interaction between the real exchange rates and the net exports generates a real exchange rate appreciation, a fall in net exports and also a reduction in the volatility of current account balance. Another important result that was obtained from the model is the increasing share of financial assets in national wealth. In other words, the model provides an economic result that suggests a growing share of financial assets in the capitalists` aggregate wealth of this economy. KEYWORDS: Open Economy Macroeconomics, Computational Economics, Simulation Models, Post-Keynesian Economics. JEL CODES: E12; F43, E37. 2 1. Introduction The objective of this paper is to present a post-keynesian macro-dynamic simulation model for an open economy with a floating exchange rate regime and imperfect mobility of capital. After the presentation of the theoretical structure of the model, we will proceed to a computational simulation in order to calculate the dynamic paths of endogenous variables. Simulated paths replicate some general features of capitalist dynamics as the occurrence of cyclical growth. An interesting result obtained from the model at hand is the existence of a long-run tendency for increasing the share of financial assets in total wealth. The present article is structured in four sections, including the present introduction. In the second section, we will present the six building blocks of the model at hand. This model is an extension of the model originally developed by Oreiro and Ono (2007). Third section is dedicated to the presentation of the results of computational simulation. Fouth section concludes the paper. 2. A Macrodynamic Simulation Model for an Open Economy In this section we will structure a macro dynamic multisectoral model with a productive and a financial sector in open economy with governmental activities. There are two available production factors: capital and labor (both are homogeneous). Therefore, there is no asymmetry in the capital lifetime neither differences in worker’s qualifications. Only one good is produced, consumed and invested in this economy. This model will be built starting from seven interconnected modules: (i) module 1 - the components of the effective demand; (II) module 2 – the determination of the production level, the income and the technological progress; (III) module 3 – income the determination of income distribution; (IV) module 4 – inflation and monetary policy (v) module 5 – financial system; (vi) module 6 - foreign sector, and (vii) module 7 – assets and debts of private sector. The model admits recursive solutions. So, the values of the dependent variables in the t period can be all expressed in terms of values of these same variables in the period t-1. We can compute time-paths to all the dependent variables of the model, given the parameters values of the dynamic equations as well the initial values of the dependent variables. We highlight two points on the model: i) The time-paths are not determined by attractors or pre-certain tendencies. By this way, the model does not assume the existence of any kind of equilibrium in the economic system. So, there is no “asymptotic position”or “steady state” in the model; and ii) the inclusion of a sixth module (the foreign sector), makes the model include some variables related to the balance-of-payments: price-elasticity’s of demand for imports and for exports; income-elasticity’s of demand for imports and for exports; foreign real interest rate; foreign real exchange rate and the growth rate of the rest of world income. The exchange rate is treated as endogenous. In short, the model is a complex system of simultaneous difference equations, with the exogenous variables being determined by a Monte Carlo process of random numbers` generation. 2.1. Module 1: Effective demand. We initially assume that government consumption grows, in each period, by an exogenous rate (hC). This consumption is autonomous in comparison to the current level of economic activity. Thus, we can write the following equation: GtC 1 h c GtC1 (1) Where: GCt is the government consumption in t period . Public investment is pro-cyclical. It experiences greater values when the economy grows. So we have: 3 GtI h I Yt 1 (2) Where hI represents the induction factor of variations in the economic activity level of t-1 period, whereas public investment is made in t period. By hypothesis, we have 1>hI>0. To enlarge the existing productive capacity, private investment is determined by a two-stage process. In the first one, this process determines the investments chosen by businessmen, given their expectations regarding future revenues of capital equipment, the state of confidence and the liquidity preference (witch is given by a discount factor applied to the capital new equipment futures revenues). In the second stage, businessmen compare their expected investments with the financial restriction to invest. This restriction is given by the firm’s maximum sustainable level of debts. On the one hand, if the desired investment is superior to the feasible investment1, firms will only be able to invest the amount permitted by their financial restriction. On the other hand, if the desired investment is lower than the feasible investment, the firm will be able to invest the amount that it wants. The difference between desired capital stock in the current period and effective capital stock in previous period is, by definition, the desired investment. Desired capital stock has two components. The first one 0Yt 1 - K t 1 , denotes the accelerator effects of changes in the level of production over investment decision. Thus, 0Yt 1 represents the production that the businessmen believe that they will be able to sell in the current period. This expectation depends on the sales executed in the previous period ( Yt 1 ) and of a sales projection coefficient ( 0 ). This coefficient is a random variable with uniform probability distribution, defined in the interval [15, 20]. This random variable captures investors' animal spirits. Thus, in each period, the businessmen will act with different values for the sales projection coefficient, expressing the animal spirits` influence in investment decisions. The second term ( K t 1 ) represents the higher firm’s available production capacity. Therefore, the expression 0Yt 1 - K t 1 can be understood as a proxy of the expected utilization of productive capacity in the current period. Pt D 1 . It incorporates Pt The second component describes the stock of desired capital, 1 S investment decision in to a general theory of portfolio choice. In this setting, purchase of capital goods is seen as one of possible forms of wealth accumulation along time. The capital goods purchase attractiveness depends on its profitability vis-à-vis the profitability of other forms of wealth accumulation. With effect, the stock of desired capital depends on the ratio between demand price of capital equipment and the offer price of this equipment. Desired investment and desired capital stock can be expressed by: I tD K tD K t 1 (3) K tD Pt D S 1; se Pt D Pt S Y K 0 t 1 t 1 1 Pt 0Yt 1 K t 1 , caso contrario (4) onde : 0 0 ; 1 0 Where is the social productivity of the capital (the inverse of capital-product ratio). . 1 Feasible investment is provided by firm’s financial restriction. 4 Assuming a conventional behavior in expectations formation, one can compute the present value of capital equipment’s expected revenues (the demand price of capital equipment). Future profits will be equal to profits obtained in the last period (POSSAS, 1993). Therefore: Pt D (1 )mt 1 Pt 1Yt 1 dt (5) Where: is the tax rate over business profits , mt-1 is the profit share in the income of the period t-1, Pt-1 is the general level of prices in t-1, Yt-1 is the real income in t-1 and dt is the discount rate applied to expected revenues of capital equipment. The equipment replacement cost (or the supply price of equipment) is equal to the value of capital stock evaluated at current prices of this equipment. Since output is a homogenous good, the supply price of capital goods is equal to the general level of prices. So, we have: Pt S Pt 1 K t 1 (5a) The discount rate, applied to expected revenues of capital equipment, depends on two elements: (i) The rate of interest of bank loans ( a proxy for opportunity cost of investment projects, it-1); and (ii) the borrower’s risk, a weighted mean of the insolvency risk (t-1) and liquidity risk (ft-1). So we have i Lt 1 L dt it 1 t 1 (1 ) t 1 it 1 t 1 (1 ) ft 1 Pt 1Kt 1 mt 1Pt 1Yt 1 (6), Where: θ is the weight factor of insolvency and liquidity risk (it indicates the degree of managerial aversion to the risk of insolvency vis-à-vis to liquidity risk); Lt is the total amount of debts with the banking sector; is the amortization coefficient of debts; t-1 is the ratio between firms` total debts and their capital stock; and ft is a coefficient of financial fragility, given by the ratio between firms´ financial debts and their operational profits. Once determined the expected investment, firms should evaluate the real chance of implementation of their investment decisions. The firms should determine: (i) the amount of new loans that they can contract with the banking sector, having in mind the maximum level of debts that they are willing to accept; and (ii) the amount of retained profits that are disposable for the financing of their investment decisions. We suppose that government does not tax retained profits. Thus, the financial restriction to investment is the sum of the increase in the level of indebtedness that firms are willing to accept and retained profits. With effect, the investment, at the t period, that firms can support is determined by: Ft max Pt 1 K t 1 Lt 1 Pt 1Yt 1 wt 1 N t 1 it 1 Lt 1 (7). Where: is the profits retention coefficient. The equation (8) details the realized investment at the t period: I t min I tD , Ft (8) Regarding the consumption expenses, we suppose the existence of different propensities to consume on, respectively, wages and profits (KALDOR, 1956 and PASINETTI,1962). Specifically, we consider that “workers spend everything they earn” (their propensity to save is equal to zero). On the other hand, we assume that productive capitalists (in other words, the non-financial company owners) have a propensity to save on their operational profits equal to sc. These capitalists own a stock of foreign assets2 that is inherited from previous period (A*t-1). Supposing that i * t 1 is the interest rate paid over foreign bonds, than productive capitalists receive a foreign income equal to At*1it*1 measured in 2 Evaluated in foreign currency. 5 foreign exchange and E t At*1it*1 measured in domestic currency, where E t is nominal rate of exchange at t period. Finally, we suppose that financial capitalists (i.e., the banks owners) have a propensity to save over net receipts of financial intermediation (sf) Thus, the nominal expenses of consumption in the period t are determined by the following expression: Pt Ct wt 1 N t 1 1 sc 1 1 Pt 1Yt 1 wt 1 N t 1 it 1 Lt 1 At*1it*1 Et 1 s 1 .L .i t 1 t 1 f (9) Pt The effective demand at the t period is determined by: Z t Ct I t Gtc GtI X t M t (10) Where: Xt is the quantum of exports at the t period; Mt is the quantum of imports at the t period, et Et Pt * Pt is the real rate of exchange; Pt is the domestic price level; Pt * is the international price level. We suppose that (11) determines the quantum of imports: Et 1 Pt*1 Yt 1 (11) M t j Pt 1 In which: j is a positive constant; is the income-elasticity of demand for imports (positive); is the price-elasticity of demand for imports (negative); Pt is the price of exports (in domestic currency) . The exports function, in a similar manner, is E P* X t t 1 t 1 Yt*1 (12) Pt 1 In which we have: x as a positive constant; as the income-elasticity of demand for exports (positive); as the price-elasticity of demand for exports (positive); and Yt *1 representing the external demand defined in the previous period. 2.2. Module 2: Production, Income and Technological Progress. According to the principle of effective demand, the production level is determined by effective demand for goods and services (PASINETTI, 1997, p.99). This occurs if and only if there is no full utilization of productive capacity (i.e, there is a “idle” capacity). We suppose that firms attend to the change in demand for their products with change in production. The limit to aggregate production is given by the economy production potential level. However, there are two limitations to determine the potential output: (i) the manpower available; (ii) the maximum level of capacity utilization. With regard to the first limitation, there is a minimum level to the unemployment rate. This rate (Umiin) will determine the full-employment level of output Yt max, l given by, Yt max, l Nt 1 U min qt (13), Where qt is labor requirement per-unit of output. 6 The variable qt is not constant, but changes through time due to the occurrence of technical progress, which will be modeled here by means of a Kaldorian technical progress function (KALDOR, 1957) as the one written above: (1 ) K t 1 I t Gti qt qt 1 0 1 qt 1 (14) i (1 ) K t 2 I t 1 Gt 1 In expression (14), we can see that any increase in the stock of aggregate capital will reduce the labor requirement per unit of output, i.e. will increase the productivity of labor. The uncertainty surrounding the process of technical change will be modeled by means of a random variable ( ), which is assumed to have a uniform distribution in interval [-1;1]. Another assumption, just as emphasized by STEINDL (1952), is the existence of an upper limit to the level of capacity utilization. Firms wish to operate with a certain level of idle capacity (in the long-term) due to the indivisibilities in investment decision. Hence, the growth of installed capacity is larger than the demand growth. So the maximum output compatible with the normal level of capacity utilization is given by: Yt max, c u max Yt 1 (15) In equation (15), umax is the normal level of productive capacity utilization; Yt max, c is the level of output compatible with a normal level of capacity utilization and Yt 1 is the potential output at period t-1. Potential output Yt 1 is given by: Yt 1 K t 1 (15a) In which is “social productivity of capital”, a technical coefficient that describes the amount of product that can be obtained through the utilization of one unit of capital. In this context, the maximum level of output compatible with both restrictions will be the smaller value between (13) and (15): N Yt max min t 1 U min ; u max Kt 1 (16) qt If the level of output is smaller than the maximum level of output - determined by equation (16a) - than real output in period t will be determined by the effective demand of this same period given by equation (10). However, we have to consider another restriction. Real output cannot increase between periods at any rate. In fact, there is a maximum rate of increase of real output between periods due to the existence of adjustment costs. These costs are related to selecting, contracting and training new workers. Therefore, we will consider the existence of a maximum real GDP growth rate between periods, gmax. In this way, the production level at the t period will be determined by: Yt min Z t , Yt max , 1 g max Yt 1 (16a) 2.3. Module 3: Income distribution According to a classical-marxist view, in an industrial economy, just as the one supposed by the model at hand, national income should be conceived as the wealth expressed in material terms (products) and created along a certain period. Hence, there are only two kinds of income in an industrial economy: wages and gross profits. The government and the financial sector do not create wealth, because they do not create added value. They just appropriate of a share of the profits (constituted by 7 taxes and interests). Taxes and interests do not affect the profits amount. By this perspective, the income evaluated in nominal terms and generated along the period t is just wages plus gross profits. So, we have: Pt Yt wt N t rt Pt K t (17) Where rt is the profit rate and w is the nominal wage rate. Profit rate rt can be seen as the product between profits share in the income (mt), the level of productive capacity utilization (ut) and the “social productivity of capital” (σ). Thus, we can re-write the expression (17): mt 1 Vt qt (18) , Where: Vt is the real wage rate. Equation (18) shows that, given the labor productivity, there is an inverse relationship between real wage and profits share. 2.4. Module 4: Inflation and Monetary Policy In order to determine the rate of inflation of the economy at hand, we will suppose that: (i) Exports and imports are made only with final goods. So, variations in nominal exchange rate do not have any direct impact upon production costs of firms; (ii) International mobility of labor is zero so that nominal and real wages are determined only in accordance with the conditions prevailing in domestic labor markets. (iii) Domestic firms operate under an oligopolistic market structure, so they have market-power. In other words, firms are price-makers in goods market. (iv) Due to the existence of uncertainty regarding the level of demand for their products (which is the direct result of strategic interaction between price-decision of firms under oligopoly), firms fix the prices of their products by means of a mark-up rate over unit direct costs. Based on this discussion, we have: Pt 1 ztf wt qt (19). Where: zft is the mark-up rate set by firms of the productive sector. The prices fixed by productive firms change according to: (i) variations of wages between periods; (ii) variations of mark-up rates between periods; and (iii) variations of unitary requirement of labor between periods. So, inflation rate in period t is given by: 1 t 1 ztf wt qt Pt Pt 1 1 ztf1 wt 1 qt 1 (20) Where: is the inflation rate in the t period. The first step to determine the inflation rate at the t period t is to compute the wage inflation (in other words, the rate of variation of the nominal wages between period t and the period t-1). Then, we suppose that the nominal wages are the result of a bargaining process among firms and unions. In this negotiation process, unions demand higher wages to cover the inflation losses of the previous period and to increase the real wage rate to a certain target rate. This target rate is determined by the conditions prevailing in the labor market and by productivity growth. Greater is the bargaining power of unions, greater will be the target real wage in the determination of nominal wages. In this sense, we have: 8 wt wt 1 Pt 1 Pt 2 Vt Vt 1 wt 1 Pt 2 (21) Where: Vt is the target real wage in the period t. Target-real wage is determined by: Vt 1 0U t 1 2 1 (21a) q Using (19), (21) and (21a) in (20), we arrive at the following expression: 1 z 0 z1f u t 1 z 2f t 1 1 t t 1 1 1 0U t 1 2 Vt 1 f f q 1 z 0 z1 u t 2 z 2 t 2 1 K t 1 I t Gti 1 0 1 1 1 K I G t 2 t 1 t 1 (20a) Equation (20a) is a kind of Phillips curve for the economy at hand. In fact, inflation rate at period t is, among other variables, a function of unemployment rate at period t-1. We have also to notice the presence of inflation inertia since inflation rate at period t depends on inflation rate at period t-1. Finally, we have to notice that changes in capacity utilization and the aggregate stock of capital also cause changes in the rate of inflation. Regarding the operation of monetary policy we will suppose that monetary policy is conducted in a Inflation Targeting Regime by means of fixing the short-term interest rate according to a Taylor's Rule (TAYLOR, 1993). The equation for interest rate rule is given by: it* 1 it*1 0 t 1 * 1 gt 1 2 (22)3. Where: i* is the basic interest rate determined by the Central Bank; is the interest rate inertia factor4; The coefficients 0>0 and 1>0 represents, respectively, the given weight, in interest rate composition, to the divergence of inflation rate of the previous period concerning the “natural” growth rate (); and the to the divergence of the growth rate of real output (at the previous period) concerning the natural growth rate. 2 is a constant. 2.5. Module 5: Financial sector and Fiscal Deficit. Just as in the case of the productive sector, we suppose a oligopolistic structure of the banking sector. Thus, banks are price-makers too. Therefore, they fix the interest rate of their loans to the productive sector. The commercial banks define the interest rate charged by their loans (it) through the application of a mark-up (zbt) over the short-term interest rate fixed by the Central bank (ROUSSEAS, 1986, pp.51-52). Thus, we have the equation: it 1 ztb it* (23) Banking mark-up is not constant through time. It varies between periods according to the economic conjuncture and/or to the banks market power. Just as ARONOVICH (1994), we suppose that banking mark-up is countercyclical, varying in the opposite direction of productive capacity utilization. In fact, increases in the level of productive capacity utilization are related to sales increase and, by 3 The only restriction to the application of equation ( 22) as a rule for fixing the short-term interest rate is that nominal interest rates can never be negative. So we can define a roof for the short-term interest rate. We will define this minimum value for short-term interest rate as i*min, so the value of short-term interest rate in period t is given by: * it* max imin ; 1 it*1 0 t 1 * 1 g t 1 2 4 According to BARBOSA (2004), Central Banks operate monetary policy in a manner to smooth interest rate changes over time. This interest rate smoothing generates a certain level of inertia in interest rate determination. 9 extent, to a reduction of productive sector`s firms default risk. This reduction allows to banks reduce their spreads. Other assumption in this module: increases in the inflation rate induce the commercial banks to increase mark-up's rate. The intuition here is a higher inflation forces the Central Bank to increase the short-term interest rate. Such action is accomplished in the attempt to prevent a divergence between current inflation and inflation target. But it increases the volatility of the short-term interest rate, contributing for an increase of “interest risk” (ONO et alli, 2005). In response to this increase, commercial banks charges higher spreads. Banking mark-up is described just as it follows: b ztb max zmin ; z1but 1 z2b t 1 (24) Once fixed the loans interest rate, commercial banks attend the entire demand for loans of the productive sector. That means that there is no kind of credit rationing, just as we see in new-keynesian macroeconomic models. Therefore, the effective volume of credit conceded by commercial banks at the t period is entirely determined by credit demand. Such assumption is in consonance with the hypothesis of endogenous supply of money (KALDOR, 1986 and Moore, 1988). Creation of demand deposits is, therefore, determined by expansion of banking credit. So, we have: Dt Dt 1 Lt Lt 1 (25) Where Dt is demand deposits at period t. The government's fiscal deficit (DGt), by hypothesis, is entirely financed by the expansion of the monetary base (Ht) at period t: DGt H t H t 1 (26). 2.6. Module 6: External sector The economy considered in the model at hand is a small open-economy with a floating exchange rate regime that operates in a setting of imperfect mobility of capital. With regard to the degree of openness of capital account, we adopt the assumption that only capitalists of productive sector are authorized by law to use a part of the distributed profits by their firms to buy foreign assets. Direct investment is the only way by which the capitals can flow out the domestic economy. There is no interest-rate arbitrage5 . Hence, the prices and the international inflation are determined by the next equations: Pt* (1 * t ) Pt*1 (27) *t * t (28) In which: t is a white noise and * is the inflation of the rest of the world (an exogenous and random variable with constant average and variance). The average rate of growth of the world economy is given by g t* , as follows: Yt * (1 g t* )Yt *1 (29) g t* g * t (30) In which t is the term of white noise related to the growth process. Similarly, we suppose that the international interest rate fluctuates in random manner around a constant value (an exogenous variable): it* i * t (31) 5 So, the transfer of liquid funds from one monetary center (and currency) to another to take advantage of higher rates of return or interest is prohibited by law. 10 where: i * is the prevalent average interest rate in international economy and t is a white noise associated with the international interest rate movements. The current account balance is given by: (32) STC Et Pt* X t M t Et it*1 At*1 Since savings of productive capitalists are always positive, the economy in consideration is a capital exporter. So, capital account balance will be always negative. The result of the capital account is determined by: SKC Et At* At*1 (33) We assume the existence of a pure floating exchange rate regime. Because of that, the result of the balance-of-payments is necessarily equal to zero, once the monetary authorities do not intervene in the exchange market. So, we can write: Et Pt* X t et M t Et it*1 At*1 Et At* At*1 (34) Productive capitalists allocate their savings in foreign assets, so that capital account balance can be written as: Et At* At*1 s c 1 1 Pt 1Yt 1 wt 1 N t 1 it 1 Lt 1 Et it*1 At*1 (35) Combining the expressions (11), (12) and (35) in (34), with some calculus we have: E P* Et 1 Pt*1 * * t 1 t 1 Y t 1 j Yt 1 it*1 At*1 1 Et Pt Pt 1 Pt 1 1 Pt 1Yt 1 wt 1 N t 1 it 1 Lt 1 Et it*1 At*1 (36) In the equation (36) the nominal rate of exchange (at the t period) is the variable that adjusts the result of current account balance to the result of capital account in order to maintain the equilibrium in the balance of payments. Solving the equation (36) to Et, we obtain: Et 1 1 Pt 1Yt 1 wt 1 N t 1 it 1 Lt 1 E P* * t 1 t 1 Yt *1 Pt P t 1 E P j Pt 1 * t 1 t 1 Yt it*1 At*1 (37) We use the Monte Carlo method to generate the random values for the exogenous variables of the model. The determinations of model`s parameters and the fixation of initial conditions follows Samuelson´s Correspondence Principle (SAMUELSON, 1947) and the method of calibration (HANSEN and HECKMAN, 1996, p.2). Below, the table 1 describes the exogenous variables of the model (most of then generated by Monte Carlo method). Inflation of the rest of the world is constant (equal to 0,025). The values of white noises were also generated by Monte Carlo method (from an interval of [0; 0,01]).The terms used for white noises were: , and 11 Table 1 – Exogenous variables obtained by the Monte Carlo Method t g*t i*t Inflation of the rest of world (fixed at 0,025) Growth rate of international economy (random numbers generated from the [0,005; 0,045] interval). International nominal interest rate (random numbers generated from the [0,01; 0,12] interval). Price elasticity of demand for exports (random numbers generated from the [-0,55; 0,7 ] interval). Price elasticity of demand for imports (random numbers generated from the [-0,7; 0,85] interval). Income elasticity of demand for exports (random numbers generated from the [1,85; 1,95] interval). Income elasticity of demand for imports (random numbers generated from the [1,65; 1,51] interval). 2.7 Module 7: Private Sector`s Assets and Debts The private sector of the economy has three social classes: productive capitalist, financial capitalists and working class. Working class` propensity to save is zero. Workers have only their own capacity to work; they do not have any other kind of wealth. Productive and financial capitalists own, respectively, productive firms and banks, which existence is totally independent and distinguishable of their owners. In this way, assets and debts of firms and banks are completely separated of the personal wealth of their owners. Productive firms own only capital stock as asset. It is financed by retained profits (net wealth, F Wt ) and bank loans (Lt). Therefore, their balance sheet can be expressed by: Pt K t Lt Wt F (38) Bank assets are represented by loans to productive firms and by bank reserves. Bank liabilities are composed by net wealth ( Wt B ) and demand deposits (Dt). In algebraic terms: Lt Rt Dt Wt B (39) The productive capitalist use its savings for the purchase of foreign currency assets. Thus, we have: Et At* Wt cp (40). Where Wt cp is the wealth of productive capitalists. Finally, financial capitalists allocate his wealth ( Wt cf ) in two assets: demand deposits and cash ( M t ). So, we can write: Dt M t Wt cf (41) Aggregating all assets and debts, we have: Wt Wt B Wt F Wt cf Wt cp Rt M t Pt K t Et At* (42), Where Wt is the net wealth of private sector. Monetary base (Ht) is equal, by definition, to the sum of bank reserves and cash owned by the public. In this way, we have: H t Rt M t (43). As we have seen, only banks and financial capitalists take portfolio decisions. Productive capitalists and firms allocate their wealth entirely in only one asset. With regard to financial capitalists, we suppose that the amount of cash that they wish to hold (at the t period) is equal to the stock of money they retained (at the previous period) plus the saved share of net profit (at the previous period). Hence, M t M t 1 1 s f it 1 Lt 1 (44) Finally, with some calculus, from (26), (44) and (43), we have: Rt H t 1 M t 1 DG t 1 s f it 1 Lt 1 (45) 12 3. Simulation`s Results Computational simulation model results6 can be synthesized in two parts. The first refers to internal macroeconomic dynamics of the model. The second, described from exogenous variables computed by Monte Carlo simulation processes, is related to external macroeconomics dynamics of the model. 3.1. Internal Macroeconomic Dynamics From Graph 1, that describes the evolution of real GDP along 73 periods, we extract conclusions that are similar to the original Oreiro-Ono`s model for a closed economy. We note an irregular growth and a non-explosive path of real GDP. Nevertheless, in this open model there is narrower fluctuations, what does not occur in closed model. Graph 1 – Real GDP Gráfico 1 - Dinamica do PIB 6.000.000 5.000.000 4.000.000 3.000.000 2.000.000 1.000.000 0 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 Source: model results estimated by authors. Concerning to GDP growth, graph 2 demonstrates, initially, an explosive growth (a take-off, just as described by ROSTOW, 1960). After that, a stagnation period, followed by an abrupt fall (economic depression, at the 11th period) and an expansionist period with a sharply cyclic GDP growth path. Soon after, we have a second depression, with smaller duration than the first. Then, the economy begin to grow with larger volatility than the simulation of closed (and without endogenous technical progress) Oreiro-Ono`s model. 6 To run this model, the software we employed was Excel 2002. 13 Graph2 – Growth rates of GDP Gráfico 2 - Taxa de Crescimento do Produto Real 0,15 0,1 0,05 0 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 -0,05 -0,1 -0,15 -0,2 -0,25 -0,3 Source: model results estimated by authors. The unemployment path describes peaks and “valleys” related to the performance of real activity (graph 2). The growth rates “valleys” are near to the rate of 2,5%, that is equivalent to unemployment level obtained by economies that exhibits cycles of high expansion (Japan, in the postwar; China, since the final of 80`s; South Korea, from the final of 70`s; Ireland, in the middle of 90`s; Spain and Chile, from the beginning of 90`s). The four peaks registered in simulation become smaller, what allows us to suppose that - with the development of the economy - the unemployment rate volatility tends to decrease (graph 3). Graph 3 – Unemployment rates Gráfico 3 - Taxa de Desemprego 0,450 0,400 0,350 0,300 0,250 0,200 0,150 0,100 0,050 0,000 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 Source: model results computing by authors. Graph 4 presents a slow, progressive and cyclical fall of financial fragility. We can see a tendency of reduction of subjective rate of discount trajectory. 14 Graph 4 – Financial fragility (ft) and subjective rate of discount (dt) Gráfico 4 - Fragilidade (ft) e Desconto (dt) 6,00 5,00 4,00 3,00 2,00 1,00 0,00 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 ft dt Source: model results estimated by authors. With three axes, graph 5 demonstrates the inverse relationship between interest rates and investment. Furthermore, as the theory of investment predicts, we can see a lag-response (of about one period) of investment to impulses of real interest rates. Graph 5 – Investment (solid line) and real interest rates (dotted line) Gráfico 5 - Juros reais e Taxa de Investimento 1.800.000 0,3 1.600.000 0,25 1.400.000 1.200.000 0,2 1.000.000 0,15 800.000 600.000 0,1 400.000 0,05 200.000 0 0 1 4 7 10 13 16 19 22 25 28 31 34 37 40 43 46 49 52 55 58 61 64 67 70 73 Taxa de investimento Juros reais Source: model results estimated by authors. In the long term, we also see the underutilization of productive capacity. Again, the difference regarding to the closed model is the cyclical outline of the graph. With the rise of real interests and the disinflation at the 3rd period, there is a period of GDP growth stagnation, when the capacity utilization degree arises (graph 2). Given the rising of inflation among periods 25 and 32, and the increasing of 15 real interest, this degree abruptly decreases and the real wage grow. Real interest and inflation, from the period 54, show an unstable trajectory. Thus, the capacity utilization falls and the real wage arises again (graph 6). Graph 6 – Real interest (solid line) and profit rates (dotted line) Gráfico 6 - Juros reais e Participação dos Lucros da Renda 0,5 0,4 0,3 0,2 0,1 0 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 -0,1 -0,2 Taxa de Lucro Taxa de Juros Source: model results estimated by authors. 3.2. External Macroeconomic Dynamics In long-term, the dynamic interaction between real exchange rate and net exports is described by the graph 10. In the periods where a real exchange rate appreciation occurs, we notice that net exports decreases. Furthermore, its volatility tends to increase a lot. Graph 7 – Exchange rates (solid line ) and net exports (dotted line) Gráfico 7 - Câmbio real x Saldo Comercial 90,000 3.000.000 80,000 2.000.000 1.000.000 70,000 0 60,000 -1.000.000 50,000 -2.000.000 40,000 -3.000.000 30,000 -4.000.000 20,000 -5.000.000 10,000 -6.000.000 0,000 -7.000.000 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 câmbio real 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 saldo comercial Source: model results estimated by authors. 16 The relationship between the exchange-rate and GDP growth rates approaches the conclusions of McCombie-Thirwall`s model. When the real exchange rate appreciates, the real GDP tends to decrease. It happens in several periods (graph 8). The reciprocal reasoning is also true. Simulation results demonstrated that, after successive periods of rapid growth, there are periods of appreciation of exchange rates because of the fall of net exports. In such periods, the price elasticities of demand for exports were larger than the price elasticities of demand for imports. At the same time, the income elasticity for imports is larger than income elasticity for exports. In the simulation process, those elasticities was generated by the Monte Carlo method, with results that suggest a causal relation between the increase of real exchange rate and the decrease of volatility of the level of openness of current account. It is possible to verify that the strong recession of period 13 was preceded by two cycles of exchange rate depreciation (in the periods 8 and 11, respectively). These two cycles provoked a reduction of the net exports (as we described in graph 7). Graph 8 - Exchange (solid line) and growth rates (dotted line) Gráfico 8 - Câmbio Real (Et) x Crescimento real do PIB (gt) 90,000 0,12 80,000 0,1 70,000 0,08 60,000 0,06 50,000 0,04 40,000 0,02 30,000 0 20,000 -0,02 10,000 0,000 -0,04 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 crescimento 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 câmbio real Source: model results estimated by authors. Two hyperdevaluations of exchange rates occurred in the periods 8 and 11. They cause a arise in the exports and, for consequence, provoked an increase of the degree of openness of the current account and of its volatility (graph 9). 17 Graph 9 – Degree of openness in the current account (solid line) and exchange rates (dotted line) Gráfico 11 - Corrente de Comércio (% do PIB) x Câmbio real 140,0 6,000 120,0 5,000 100,0 4,000 80,0 3,000 60,0 2,000 40,0 1,000 20,0 0,0 0,000 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 Câmbio real 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 Corrente de comércio Source: model results estimated by authors. Note: foreign transactions as a percentage of GDP. To conclude, we can observe a long-run tendency for the increase in the share of financial wealth in total wealth. This increase is the result of the fact that productive and financial capitalists use their personal savings only to buy financial assets. Productive assets are bought only by means of investment decision of productive firms. This result is consistent with the ‘stylized facts´ of capitalist long-run dynamics; according to which financial wealth tends to increase in importance in the long-term. Graph 10 – Financial wealth share in total wealth Gráfico 13 - Índice de Financeirização da Riqueza 1,2 1,0 0,8 0,6 0,4 0,2 0,0 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 Source: model results estimated by authors. 18 4. Final considerations The central goal of this article was to build a simulation macrodynamic model for an open economy with governmental activities, a flexible exchange rate-regime, inflation targeting, endogenous technical progress and imperfect capital mobility. This model is an extended version of Oreiro & Ono`s seminal model. Oreiro & Ono`s model do not have exogenous variables. To build the open model, we apply a Monte Carlo simulation to generate these variables. With the model results, we verify that, under a internal macrodynamic view, there emerges a cyclical, irregular and non-explosive growth path, which are more volatile than the Oreiro-Ono`s model one. In the open model, financial fragility exhibits a slow, progressive and cyclical tendency to fall, while the discount rate series demonstrates a progressive reduction of its volatility. Just as in Oreiro-Ono's original model, this open model also shows that there is no full capacity utilization in the long term. The results of both models shows the stability of profit rate and profit share in the long-term. However, with regard to model`s external macrodynamics, we analyze the interaction among real exchange rate and net exports in the long term. It allows us to conclude that, when a appreciation of real exchange rate occurs, net exports falls and its volatility decreases. In long-term, the dynamic interaction between real exchange rate and net exports shows that the appreciation of exchange rate foregoes the decreasing of net exports. Therefore, the volatility of net exports tends to increase a lot. The conclusions of McCombie-Thirwall`s model are close to the results of the dynamic interaction between exchange rates and GDP growth rates. In fact, when the real exchange rate appreciates, the real GDP tends to decrease. The inverse dynamic is valid. Two hyperdevaluations occurred. They enlarged exports and provoked an increase of the commerce and its volatility. Finally, there is a long-run tendency for increase of the share of financial wealth in total wealth. This result is consistent with the ‘stylized facts´ of capitalist long-run dynamics; according to which financial wealth tends to increase in importance in the long-term. References 1. ARONOVITCH, S. “A Note About the Effects of Inflation and Activity Level on Bank Spread”. (“Uma Nota sobre os Efeitos da Inflação e do Nível de Atividade sobre o Spread Bancário”). Brazilian Review of Economics (From the original: Revista Brasileira de Economia), v.48, n.1, p. 125-40, 1994. 2. BARBOSA, F. H. “A Inércia da Taxa de Juros na Política Monetária”. Revista de Economia, v.30, n. 2, p. 105-119, 2004. 3. BRESSER-PEREIRA, L.C e NAKANO, Y. Inflation and Recession: The Theory of Inertial Inflation (From the original: “Inflação e Recessão: A Teoria da Inércia Inflacionária”). São Paulo: Brasiliense, 1984. 4. CHIANG, A. C. & WAINWRIGHT, K. Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics.4th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill, 2005. 5. CHOWDURY, A. & PATRICK, C. Development Policy and Planning: An Introduction to Models and Techniques. New York: Routledge, 1994. 6. DOMAR, E. “Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth and Employment”. Econometrica, vol. 14, 1946. 7. EICHNER, A. “A Post-Keynesian Short-Period Model”. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 1, p. 38-63, 1979. 19 8. ENDERS, W. Applied Econometric Time Series. New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1995. 9. GREENE, W.H. Econometric Analysis. 5th ed. New York: Prentice-Hall, 2003. 10. HANSEN, L.P.& HECKMAN, J J. “The Empirical Foundations of Calibration”. Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, v. 10(1), pp. 87-104, Winter, 1996. 11. HARROD, R. F. "The Theory of International Economic Policy, Volume II. Trade and Welfare". Economic Journal, v. 76(266), June, 290-95, 1957. 12. HICKS, J. Contribution to the Theory of Trade Cycle. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1950. 13. KALDOR, N. “Alternative Theories of Distribution”. Review of Economic Studies, v. 23, p.83-100, 1956. 14. ____________ “A Model of Economic Growth”. The Economic Journal, vol. 67, n. 268, p.591-624, 1957. 15. ____________ “Marginal Productivity and the Macro-Economic Theories of Distribution: Comment on Samuelson and Modigliani”. Review of Economic Studies, v. 33, p. 309-319, 1966. 16. ___________ The Scourge of Monetarism. Oxford University Press: Oxford. 2nd ed., 1986. 17. KEYNES, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan Press. 18. LIMA, G.T. (1992). In Search of Lost Time: The Post-Keynesian Recovery of Keynes` Economy of Employment (From the original: “Em Busca do Tempo Perdido: A Recuperação Pós-Keynesiana da Economia do Emprego de Keynes”). BNDES: Rio de Janeiro. 19. LAW, A M. & KELTON, W. D. Simulation modeling and analysis. 2nd . ed. Singapore: McGraw-Hill, 1991 20. MATTOS, R.S. e VEIGA, A. “Entropy`s Otimization: Computational Implementation of Maxent and Minxent Principles” (From the original: “Otimização de Entropia: Implementação Computacional dos Princípios de Maxent e Minxent”). Operational Research (From the original: Pesquisa Operacional), v.22, n.1, Jan/Jun de 2002. 21. MADDALA, G.S. Introduction to Econometrics. 3rd ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons, 2001. 22. MEADE, J.E. & HAHN, F.H. “The Rate of Profit in a Growing Economy”. The Economic Journal, v. 75, n.298, June, pp. 445-448, 1965. 23. McCOMBIE, J.S.L e THIRWALL, A.P. Economic Growth and the Balance-of-Payments Constraint. London: McMillan, 1994. 24. MOORE, B. Horizontalists and Verticalists. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988. 25. OREIRO, J. L. e LEMOS, B. P. “A Post-Keynesian Growth and Income Distribution Model Applied to the Dynamic of Capitalists Developed and Underdeveloped Economies” (From the original: “Um Modelo Pós-Keynesiano de Crescimento e Distribuição de Renda Aplicado à Dinâmica das Economias Capitalistas Desenvolvidas e em Desenvolvimento”). Papers and Proceedings of XXXIII National Meeting of Economics (From the original: Anais do XXXIII Encontro Nacional de Economia). Rio Grande do Norte: Natal, 2006. Available at: http://www.eco.unicamp.br:8888/seer/ojs/viewarticle.php?id=219&layout=abstract 26. OREIRO, J. L. e ONO, F. H. “Um Modelo Macrodinâmico Pós-Keynesiano de Simulação”. Review of Political Economy (From the original: Revista de Economia Política), vol 27, nº 1, Jan-Mar – 2007. Abstract available at: http://www.rep.org.br/pesquisar3.asp?id=1084 27. PASINETTI, L. “Rate of Profit and Income Distribution in Relation to the Rate of Economic Growth”. Review of Economic Studies, 29, p. 267-79, 1962. 28. _________ “The Principle of Effective Demand” In: HARCOURT, G.; RIACH, P.A. A Second Edition of The General Theory. Routledge: London, 1997. 29. POSSAS, M. Rationality and Regularities: Towards a Micro/Macro- Dynamic Integration. (From the original: “Racionalidade e Regularidades: Rumo à Integração MicroMacrodinâmica”). Economics and Society (From the original:Economia e Sociedade, v.2, p.59-80, 1993). 30. DOMAR, E. Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth and Employment. Econometrica, vol. 14., 1946. 31. EICHNER, A. The Megacorp and the Oligopoly. M.E. Sharpe: Armmonk, 1980. 20 32. KEYNES, J. M. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money.. London: Macmillan Press, 1936. 33. LAW, A M. & KELTON, W. D. Simulation modeling and analysis. 2. ed. Singapore: McGraw-Hill, 1991. 34. McCOMBIE, J.S.L e THIRWALL, A.P. Economic Growth and the Balance-of-Payments Constraint. Londres: McMillan, 1994. 35. MEADE, J.E. & HAHN, F.H. “The Rate of Profit in a Growing Economy”. The Economic Journal, v. 75, n.298, June, pp. 445-448, 1965. 36. ROSTOW, W.W. The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1960. 37. ROUSSEAS, S. Post Keynesian Monetary Economics. London: M.E. Sharp. 2nd ed., 1986. 38. SAMUELSON, P.A., Foundations of Economic Analysis. p. xxi-xxiv, cap.VIII, "Welfare Economics," 1947.(edição ampliada em 1983). 39. STEINDL, J. Maturity and Stagnation in American Capitalism. Basil Blackwell:Oxford. 1952. 40. TAKAYAMA, A. Analytical Methods in Economics. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1995. 41. TAYLOR, J. “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice”. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 195-214, 1993. 42. ZUROSE, K. “Rate of Profit and Interest in a Growth Theory with Endogenous Money”. Cambridge Journal of Economics, v. 28, n.6, November, pp.889-901, 2004. 21
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz