National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT M. KEVIN MCGEE * Abstract - This paper simulates the impact of a capital gains tax cut on new and established firms, assuming that new firms differ from their older counterparts because of the dividend trap. For all parameter values, the tax cut increases the mature firms’ desired capital stock, holding interest rates constant. In nearly every case, however, the tax cut is more beneficial to mature firms than to new startups. Indeed, in many of the cases portrayed, the tax cut actually reduces new firm investment. Hence, this paper contradicts the widely held view that a capital gains tax cut would be a well-targeted approach for encouraging new firm capital formation. The problem with this logic is that it treats as given both the initial value of the firm and the accretions to value that follow. But certainly neither the firm’s current market value, nor its expected future increases in value, is independent of either the firm’s current level of investment or the tax treatment of its investment return. Any analysis that treats them as such should be suspect. This paper presents a “Trapped Equity” model of firm behavior, that endogenously determines both the firm’s initial value and its optimal initial level of investment. New firms differ from older, established firms in this model because of the dividend trap: since corporations can at the margin only return equity to their shareholders through taxable dividends, making new share issues a more expensive source of equity than retained earnings, new corporations are created with less equity than would otherwise be optimal. All their earnings are then retained, and firm equity grows internally, until the marginal value of additional equity is low enough to justify paying (taxable) dividends. New, equity-poor firms don’t pay dividends; old, equity-rich firms do. An oft-stated dictum of journalists and politicians is that a cut in capital gains taxation will increase economic growth, by encouraging investment in new firms.1 Much of the initial return on these newly formed firms, the reasoning goes, is in the form of increases in firm value, i.e., capital gains; a lower tax rate on this return would help direct more investment dollars into these nascent enterprises. * I find in this model that a reduction in the capital gains tax always increases University of Wisconsin–Oshkosh, Oshkosh, WI 54901. 653 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 investment demand by old firms, and usually increases investment demand by new firms as well. As such, the capital gains tax cut competes with a variety of other policy instruments, such as a reduction in the corporate tax rate, changes in depreciation allowances, and movement to a cash flow tax, all of which would similarly increase investment demand in models such as these. wisdom: that firm behavior is not modeled, but simply assumed. The subsequent sections address that shortcoming, by presenting a model of firm behavior. In the second section, I develop the dynamic optimization problem, based on the prior section’s asset market equilibrium, that the firm must solve, deriving the conditions for an optimal firm capital stock and financing mix. Functional forms, adopted to generate both analytic and numerical results, are presented in the third section. The fourth section develops analytically the impact of the capital gains tax cut on firm behavior in the trapped equity model, when firms are fully equity financed. The conditions under which the tax cut results in less relative investment in new firms than in old firms are derived. Readers who wish to skip the technical details may jump from the second section directly to the fifth section, where I present my simulation results. These simulations show that new firm investment falls relative to that of mature firms for all reasonable parameter values, and indeed falls absolutely for some parameter values, both in an all-equity model and when debt financing is also allowed. The final section summarizes these results. The alleged advantage of the capital gains tax cut, however, its advocates avow, is not just that it encourages investment, but that it targets that investment toward new enterprises where it is needed most. I find, however, that a reduction in the capital gains tax consistently increases investment proportionately more in old firms than it does in new firms. Although it has been for some time intuited that this result should arise in a trapped equity model—i.e., that a lower capital gains tax will merely deepen the equity trap—before now this result had never been formally established.2 And the possibility that the tax cut might actually reduce investment in new firms has to the best of my knowledge never before been suspected, let alone demonstrated. This paper therefore shows, at least from the trapped equity view of corporate taxation, that if the policy goal is not just to promote corporate investment, but to target that investment toward new enterprises, a capital gains tax cut is definitely not the policy option of choice. THE ASSET MARKET EQUILIBRIUM Capital gains are just one form of investment income. To attract investors, therefore, appreciating assets must yield an after-tax return at least as great as other assets, paying dividend or interest income. Hence, to assess how capital gains taxation impacts investment behavior, we must begin with the investor’s asset market equilibrium, first modeled by Pye (1972) and Stapleton (1972), and discussed by King (1974), Poterba and Summers (1983), and Sinn (1987).3 In the first section, I discuss the role of capital gains taxes in the equilibrium that must arise in the asset market. As will be seen, the result of that analysis, at least at first glance, closely parallels the popular wisdom, that a capital gains tax cut will encourage new firm formation. The limitation of that analysis is also the limitation of the popular 654 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT Investors will be indifferent between alternative investments when they yield identical after-tax rates of return.4 A corporation with a current market value of Vt must generate sufficient dividend . income .Dt and capital gain (Vt – VNt), where Vt is the change in firm value and VNt represents new share issues,5 to yield the same after-tax return as an interest-paying security: The firm’s market value is the present value of the stream of after-tax payments to its shareholders: its dividends after the income tax is levied and its share repurchases (negative new issues), which are untaxed. Since no tax liability is incurred until the dividends are actually paid, the share’s income stream is discounted by the investor at the after-tax interest rate. Since the ordinary personal income tax reduces both the after-tax value of dividend payments and the rate at which the firm’s payments are discounted, its impact on firm value is ambiguous. If the firm were to only issue a single dividend payment at some future time T, its current value would be 1 . (1 – θ)rVt = (1 – θ)Dt + (1 – c)(Vt – VNt). The parameters θ and c are the effective tax rates on ordinary and capital gains income, respectively, and r is the interest rate.6 Integrating subject to a transversality condition gives the current market value of the firm:7 5 V0 = DT (1 – θ )e–r(1 – θ )T. 2 ∞ ∫ [( V0 = e –ρt Its derivative, measuring the change in firm value as the ordinary tax rate increases, is 1–θ 1 – c Dt – VNt dt ) ] 0 where the firm’s discount rate ρ is 6 dV0 V0 = [rT(1 – θ ) –1] 1–θ dθ 3 ρ=r ( 11 –– θc ). which will be positive only for sufficiently large T, i.e., for dividends sufficiently distant into the future. Any increase in the ordinary personal income tax, therefore, presumably will be more likely to reduce or leave unchanged the current market value of established firms, whose stream of dividend payments may remain relatively constant over time, and increase the value of firms with strong growth prospects (and no current dividends).8 To interpret equation 2, observe that, in the absence of a capital gains tax, it simplifies to 4 ∞ V0 = ∫ e–r (1 – θ )t [(1 – θ)Dt – VNt ]dt. 0 655 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 8 The tax on capital gains income similarly affects the current market value of a given future stream of dividends and repurchases in two ways. First, the capital gains tax increases the after-tax value of any dividend payment at time t, since that dividend creates a capital loss (or avoids a capital gain) and hence reduces current or future capital gains tax liabilities. This effect partly offsets the dividend tax; if c = θ, the tax on the dividend payment and the tax reduction on the capital loss exactly offset, and the dividend’s value to the investor at time t is the same as when no taxes are imposed. dV0 V0 = 1–c dc which will be negative for large T. An increase in the capital gains tax therefore presumably will be more likely to increase or leave unchanged the current market value of established firms, whose stream of dividend payments may remain relatively constant over time, and reduce the value of firms with strong growth prospects. Since newly formed firms are presumably in the latter category, the asset market equilibrium suggests that a reduction in the capital gains tax rate will indeed encourage investment in new firms, by increasing the market value of their shares relative to other investment instruments. Second, an accrual capital gains tax will continuously result in immediate tax liabilities, rather than liabilities that are delayed until the actual dividend payments or share repurchases.9 Because of this partial (or if c = θ, complete) elimination of the share’s ability to delay tax liabilities, the investor’s discount rate approaches the before-tax interest rate, which is also taxed on an accrual basis. This analysis of the asset market equilibrium is in a sense a formalization of the popular wisdom, and it shares the same shortcomings of the popular wisdom. The impact on the market value of a given flow of dividends and repurchases was examined, without determining whether that flow of payments would remain unchanged. Mature firms were assumed to pay dividends (or repurchase shares) now, and new firms only later, without justifying those behavior patterns. And the discussion of tax impacts focused entirely on the firm’s total market value, without determining whether or how those taxes affect the marginal value of additional investment in the firm. Like the ordinary income tax, the capital gains tax’s impact on firm value therefore is, as a result of these two effects, ambiguous. For a firm paying only a single dividend at time T, the firm’s current value when capital gains are taxed is 7 V0 = DT 1 – θ e –r(1 – θ )T/(1 – c) 1–c ( [1 – rT(11 –– θc)] ) The next sections address those shortcomings. A dynamic optimization model, taking as its beginning point this asset market equilibrium, will be used to describe the firm’s optimizing behavior, and the change in V0 due to the tax rate is 656 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT to identify differences between new and established firms, and to examine how a reduced capital gains tax translates into investment demand. outlays, and agency costs (1 – u)Ψ(B,K).10 These agency costs are assumed to depend upon the ratio of debt to capital, to reduce the firm’s taxable income (and hence are effectively tax deductible), and to reflect both the agency and bankruptcy costs associated with excessive debt, as well as the agency costs associated with excessive equity.11 The agency cost function Ψ therefore will reach its minimum at some optimal debt/capital ratio γ, which will be the ratio the firm would choose in the absence of taxation.12 THE EQUITY TRAP FIRM OPTIMIZATION MODEL The dynamic optimization model used here expands upon the firm growth dynamics presented in Sinn (1991a), by incorporating a debt/equity financing choice. Its results are similar to those of Hayashi (1985). The firm maximizes its current share value, developed in the prior section, subject to two dynamic constraints: the investment constraint that capital growth equals investment minus capital depreciation, Two additional constraints are imposed on the optimization problem: 11 Dt ,VNt ≥ 0. 9 The former, that dividends are nonnegative, is natural; the latter, that new share issues are nonnegative, rules out share repurchases and allows the model to reflect the “New View” (or trapped equity view) of dividend taxation developed by Auerbach (1979), Bradford (1981), and King (1974).13 . Kt = It – δKt where δ is the real rate at which capital assets depreciate; and a budget constraint, equating the firm’s cash inflows and outflows, 10 Attaching the costate variables qte –ρt and zte –ρt to the two dynamic constraints and the multipliers µDe –ρt and µV e –ρt to the inequality constraints, and maximizing the resulting Hamiltonian function, yields the following firstorder conditions (suppressing time subscripts): . Bt + VNt + (1 – u)[R(Kt ,Lt) – wLt] + uδKt = Dt + (1 – u)rBt + It + (1 – u)Ψ(Bt,Kt). . Inflows are net new bond issues B, new share issues VN, after-tax operating income (1 – u)[R(K,L) – wL], and tax depreciation allowances uδK; K and L are firm capital and labor, w is the wage rate, and u is the corporate tax rate. Outflows are dividends, deductible interest payments (1 – u)rB, investment 12 HI = e–ρt[q + z] = 0 657 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 16 13 HD = e–ρt [(11 –– θc ) + µ D . z = z [ ρ – r (1 – u) – (1 – u)ΨB ] ] +z =0 17 14 . q = q (δ + ρ) + z[(1 – u)(RK – ΨK) + uδ ]. HVN = e [ µv – 1 – z] = 0 –ρt 15 . . Since equation 12 implies that z + q = 0, combining these equations gives the firm’s cost of capital: HL = – (1 – u) ze–ρt [ RL – w] = 0. 18 RK – δ = r + Ψ B + Ψ K The costate variables qt and zt measure the change in the firm’s value due to incremental increases in Kt and Bt , respectively; qt will be positive and zt negative. Equation 12 states that, at the optimal level of investment, they will sum to zero, which implies that the marginal cost of capital will equal the marginal cost of debt, or that, at the margin, the firm cannot increase its market value through additional purchases of debt-financed capital. which depends both on the marginal agency costs of debt (ΨB) and equity (ΨK).15 In general, these marginal costs will be of opposite sign; e.g., when the firm is excessively debt financed, ΨB will be positive, since more debt will exacerbate the problem of excessive debt, but ΨK will be negative, since additional equity will reduce the agency costs due to excessive debt. If the agency cost function is convex, implying for example that the increased bankruptcy risk of more debt is greater when the debt/equity ratio is already high, then these marginal costs will not be of equal magnitude (e.g., ΨB will exceed ΨK, when the firm is excessively debt financed), so agency costs due to an inefficient debt/equity ratio in general will raise the cost of capital and reduce investment.16 Equations 13 and 14 determine when dividends or new shares will be issued: by equation 13, dividends will be paid ( µD = 0) whenever –z, and hence q equals (1 – θ)/(1 – c); by equation 14, new shares will be issued ( µV = 0) when q = 1.14 Equation 15 states that labor will be employed until its marginal revenue product equals the wage rate. All of these results are standard. FUNCTIONAL FORMS The canonical equations, which describe the rate of change in these two costate variables over time, are To draw out the implications of the above model, it will be useful to adopt 658 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT functional forms for the revenue function R(K,L) and the agency function Ψ(B,K). In this section, I describe the adopted functions. which gives a marginal revenue product of capital of 20 I assume that the revenue function is Cobb–Douglas and homogenous of degree (1 – β). Two stories could justify this less than unit homogeneity. One would be a decreasing returns to scale production function. The other would be a degree of market power, giving the firm a downward sloping demand for its product. In particular, if the firm faces a constant elastic demand for its product, Q = P –1/β, where P is the firm’s price, then the firm’s revenue R = Q1–β will be homogeneous of degree (1 – β) when the production function is linearly homogeneous. Either story is sufficient to guarantee that the firm’s size (i.e., output level or capital stock) is determinate in the long run. RK = AK –β. The agency cost function is assumed to take the form19 21 Ψ= v (λ – γ )2K 2 where λ is the debt/capital ratio B/K. Agency costs are normalized to equal zero at their minimum point, where λ = γ. A marginal increase in debt increases agency costs by The market power story implies that corporate enterprises earn significant inframarginal rents, that increase at a diminishing rate as output increases. It is the existence of these potential rents that makes new firm creation worth taking on in the face of the dividend trap.17 This story is also consistent with the images of potential new enterprises that proponents of lower capital gains taxes put forward: innovative, high technology startups, with a great idea or a new discovery to exploit. These firms are not perfect competitors, not indistiguishable providers of some homogeneous product. 22 ΨB = v (λ – γ ) while an increment in equity increases them by 23 ΨK = – v (λ2 – γ 2). 2 For subsequent ease of notation, I assume the real revenue function net of labor costs takes the form18 These functional forms will be incorporated into the previous analysis, to help illustrate the impact of the capital gains tax on firm formation. 19 CAPITAL GAINS AND THE NEW VIEW R(K,L) – wL = A K 1–β (1 – β ) In the trapped equity model developed by Auerbach (1979), Bradford (1981), 659 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 and King (1974), established firms pay dividends, but newly created firms do not. As Sinn (1991a) demonstrates, new firms go through three stages: an instantaneous birth stage, in which new shares are issued; a growth phase, during which all earnings are retained; and maturity, when the firm pays dividends. In the New View model, share repurchases are not possible.20 where equation 3 has been used to substitute for ρ. Equations 24 and 25 both imply that a reduction in the capital gains tax rate, by decreasing the investor’s discount rate, will decrease the firm’s optimal debt/equity ratio. Earnings retained within the firm, that generate the capital gains, will be less heavily taxed; the firm responds by retaining more earnings, thereby replacing some of its debt with equity. To analyze the impact of the capital gains tax in this model, I must examine each of the three growth phases of the firm: infancy, expansion, and maturity. It will be most convenient to examine them in reverse order. Those increased retained earnings will not be used solely to decrease debt. Since the reduced debt/equity ratio reduces the firm’s total agency costs, by equation 18, the reduction in the capital gains tax rate in turn will reduce the cost of capital, increasing the firm’s desired capital stock. The assumed functional forms make this relationship more explicit: substituting equations 23 and 24 into equation 18, and then solving equation 20 for K, gives the firm’s optimal capital stock: Mature Firms Mature firms issue dividends, so µD = 0, and q = –z = (1 – θ)/(1 – c). Therefore, both costate variables q and z are constant over time, and the canonical equation 16 reduces to 24 ΨB = [ ρ – r (1 – u) (1 – u) 26 ] K= which says that the firm will choose a debt/capital ratio that equates the after-tax cost of additional debt (ΨB + r)(1 – u) to the discount rate ρ. When the quadratic agency cost function (equation 21) is assumed, this in turn implies that the debt/capital ratio λ will be [( ) r ν (1 – u) 1–θ 1–c A ρ – ν (λ2 – γ 2) (1 – u) 2 } . Since equation 24 was used to eliminate ΨB, the firm must be choosing its costminimizing debt/capital ratio. Therefore, equation 26 describes the optimal capital stock as a function of the optimal amount of equity, with the denominator of equation 26 measuring the required rate of return on equity net of the marginal agency cost of equity. The capital gains tax cut reduces the discount rate ρ but, by reducing the 25 λ=γ+ { δ+ 1 β ] – (1 – u) 660 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT optimal debt/capital ratio λ, raises the marginal agency cost of equity. As equations 3 and 25 make clear, the former effect is dominant, and a lower capital gains tax rate increases the mature firm’s optimal capital stock.21 A capital gains tax cut will reduce the desired debt/equity ratios of mature firms and increase their demand for capital. have sufficient earnings on hand to pay dividends, after meeting their investment needs, expanding firms are equity cash starved and must borrow too much to finance too little investment. To examine the impact of the capital gains tax on these growing firms, consider first the simpler case, where the firm is fully equity financed. Letting . B = B = 0 in equation 10, and z = 0, the remaining canonical equation becomes Expanding Firms Expanding firms neither issue shares nor pay dividends, so both µD and µV > 0. By equations 13 and 14, 29 . q = q [δ (1 – u) + ρ – (1 – u)RK] 27 (11 –– cθ) < (11 –– θc ) + µ D which, using equation 14, gives the mature firm’s capital stock: = – z = 1 – µv < 1 30 so – z and therefore q are between (1 – θ)/(1 – c) and 1. Since, as Sinn (1991a) shows, expanding firms must eventually become mature firms, and therefore q and – z must eventually equal (1 – θ)/(1 – c), q must be falling and z rising during this stage. Then, . . q < 0 and z > 0, so by equation 16, KT = ρ – r (1 – u) [ (1 – u) δ+ ρ (1 – u) . During the growth stage, dividends and new share issues are both zero, so substituting the budget constraint (equation 10) for I into equation 9 gives the firm’s capital growth equation: 28 ψB > 1 β { } A ] 31 . K = (1 – u) which says that the debt/capital ratio will be higher in the expansion stage than at maturity, which by equation 18 implies that total agency costs, and hence the cost of capital, will be higher, and the stock of capital lower, than at maturity. Unlike mature firms, which (1 1– β )AK 1–β –δ (1 – u) K. Defining as t = T the moment the firm reaches the mature stage, equations 30 and 31 together imply that the expanding firm’s capital growth path prior to time T will be 661 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 32 Kt = { A d(1 – β) e [ ( 1– ]} βδ (1–u)(T–t) 1 β βδ (1 – u) + ρ δ (1 – u) + ρ absolute rate (the extra output has increased after-tax income and hence investment) but at a slower relative rate (the additional inframarginal rents will be relatively smaller). Therefore, the capital stock during those periods will be a larger fraction of the ultimate level. ) . When debt financing is brought back into the model, an analytical solution is no longer possible. It is clear that, during the expansion phase, the firm’s capital stock will be rising; Hayashi (1985) demonstrated that its debt/ equity ratio during that phase will be falling. The impact of the capital gains tax cut on expanding firms in this model will be explored through numerical simulation in the next section. In this all-equity model, the capital gains tax rate affects Kt only through the discount rate ρ; since from equation 32 dK/dρ is clearly negative, a reduction in the tax increases K over the entire growth stage, holding constant the date of maturity at time T. Perhaps, more interestingly, reducing the discount rate flattens the relative optimal capital stock profile over the growth period. Reformulating equation 27 produces Infant Firms Infant firms, i.e., new startups, or existing firms whose investment prospects have suddenly expanded issue new shares: µV = 0 and q = – z = 1. Sinn (1991a) has shown that, since infant firms become expansion firms, their capital stock must be suboptimal, so the flow condition (equation 17) cannot hold. Similarly, the above analysis shows that the debt/capital ratio must be suboptimal, so equation 16 cannot hold either. Both statements imply that infancy is a momentary phenomenon: the infant firm issues some beginning stock of shares and bonds and proceeds immediately into the expansion phase. 33 Kt β ( )[ KT = δ (1 – u) + ρ (1 – β)δ (1 – u) ] (1 – eβδ (1–u)(T–t)) + eβδ (1–u)(T–t), which increases as ρ falls: with a lower discount rate, the firm’s optimal Capital stock n periods before maturity will be a larger fraction of its mature optimal capital stock than at the higher discount rate. During the growth stage, all the firm’s after-tax income is reinvested; as its capital stock and hence output rises, that income increases at a decreasing rate (for β < 1), so productive capacity similarly grows at a decreasing rate. Since with the lower discount rate the ultimate mature optimal capital stock will be larger, during the last n periods, it will have been growing at a greater To determine the size of these initial stocks, equation 16 or 17 must be integrated backward over time, from the moment maturity is reached (when q = – z = (1 – θ)/(1 – c)) through the expansion phase, until q = – z = 1. The sizes of the initial stocks will depend upon the exact paths of q and z, which in turn depend upon the exact form of the revenue function F(K,L) and the 662 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT agency cost function Ψ. Since any reasonable function forms will be nonlinear, no analytic solution for the size of the initial capital stock can be obtained. market power to exploit and earns very few inframarginal rents. Its rate of capital accumulation therefore is very slow, and its length to maturity can be quite long— perhaps a century or more. Discounting to the present, any decline in the eventual qT so many years away has but a negligible impact on the initial investment decision, and the effects of the lower discount rate alone dominate. However, it may be reasonably questioned whether firms with so little market power, that would as corporations fail to pay dividends for so long, would ever be formed as corporations in the first place in the face of the dividend trap. Notice however that a reduction in the capital gains tax rate reduces the value of q at maturity, without affecting its initial value at formation. A lower capital gains tax increases the impact of the dividend tax, “deepening” the equity trap. Therefore, unless the tax cut . increases q, the length of time the firm spends in the expansion phase will increase. This implies, ceteris paribus, a lower initial optimal capital stock, since it now takes longer to grow to its mature size; for example, in equation 33, Kt falls as T, the date at which maturity is reached, increases. The question then is, will this longer growth to maturity, decreasing the initial capital stock, be large enough to offset both the flatter relative growth profile and the higher ultimate capital stock at maturity, which both suggest a larger initial K0. Figure 1 illustrates the results when β is reasonably large.22 In the New View model, firms acquire an initial capital stock in infancy, expand by investing their cash flow during the growth phase, and maintain some steady-state capital stock in maturity. Holding constant the maturity date, the capital gains tax cut increases the firm’s desired capital at maturity and throughout the growth phase; since that growth phase is longer, however, the optimal initial level of investment is nearly unchanged. The relative capital stock (K0 /KT), holding interest rates constant, is as a result significantly smaller. The Appendix demonstrates that, in the all-equity model, with interest rates fixed, a capital gains tax cut may either increase or decrease the ratio of new firm capital to mature firm capital, (K0 / KT). When β is very small, i.e., when the firm produces with a nearly (or exactly) constant returns to scale technology and faces a nearly horizontal demand curve, a capital gains tax cut will increase the initial capital stock relative to its level at maturity. With a larger β, the tax cut works in the opposite direction, reducing (K0/KT). Interest rates however are unlikely to remain fixed. The tax cut increases both new and existing firms’ demand for capital; unless the supply of capital to them is perfectly inelastic, the interest rate must rise. But an increase in the interest rate raises the firm discount rate ρ, which as the Appendix shows will necessarily reduce (K0 /KT). On balance then, the all-equity New View model suggests that, unless the corporate sector is made up of nearly perfectly competitive firms, with a very elastic supply of savings to it, a capital gains tax cut will direct capital away These differing results reflect the fact that, for very small values of β, a lower qT has a comparatively small impact on the initial optimization decision. When β is very small, the firm has almost no 663 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 FIGURE 1. The Evolution of the Firm’s Capital Stock from rather than toward new enterprises. dividend stream are constant over time. The market value of a new firm, immediately after its initial share issues (which occur at time zero), will be Similarly, the capital gains tax cut will reduce the market value of new firms relative to old firms. In the trapped equity model, with no share repurchases, the market value of a mature firm will be 35 ∞ 1–θ 1–θ ∫ (1 – c ) D dt = (1 – c ) ρ Vn = e ∞ V = t e – ρt T 34 m Dt – ρt ∫e ( – ρt The tax cut increases the eventual dividend payments by both firms equally, while increasing T, the years to maturity; hence, V n must fall relative to V m. 1 – θ D dt = 1 – θ Dt t 1–c 1–c ρ ) ( ) T where the second equality assumes that the steady, state capital stock and hence It may seem paradoxical that a capital gains tax cut, which in the first section 664 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT appeared to increase the market value of new firms relative to old, is now shown to do just the opposite. Keep in mind however that, in the initial section, we examined how the market values a given stream of dividends and repurchases, concluding that, with a lower capital gains tax, it would reward capital growth over immediate dividends. While the market value of firm shares was allowed to change in that model, the actions of those firms whose share values were changing were held rigidly constant. internal finance to maturity, increasing over time their capital stock, while decreasing their debt/capital ratios. This section simulates such firms, both at the point when they are created and at the time they reach maturity, before and after the capital gains tax cut.23 In this section, we have examined how both old and new firms would optimally adjust their patterns of capital investment and dividend paying to that lower tax. Older firms, already mature in size and generating more revenue than their investment needs, would expand investment somewhat with the tax cut, until the marginal return on their investments matched the new, lower discount rate. New firms, on the other hand, would respond by choosing a smaller initial investment level, thereby delaying maturity and the eventual payment of dividends. By rewarding growth over repayments, the lower capital gains tax discourages initial investment in these new enterprises, reducing rather than enhancing their current market value relative to their mature counterparts. The values for the inflation rate π and the real interest rate r are widely used; the depreciation rate δ is a weighted average of the depreciation rates estimated by Hulten and Wycoff (1981). The tax rates reflect the current top corporate tax rate (u), the current 36 percent marginal tax rate at $200,000 adjusted gross income (θ ), and a top capital gains tax rate of 28 percent, divided by 4 to convert it into its accrual equivalent (c).24 As a sensitivity test, a 14 percent effective capital gains tax rate is also simulated. To simulate the impacts of the tax cut, I assume the following baseline parameter values: π = 0.04 r = 0.03 δ = 0.095 u = 0.34 θ = 0.36 c = 0.07 A range of values for β, from 0.1 to 0.5, were used to simulate the model. This parameter measures both the firm’s returns to scale in production and the firm’s market power in pricing its product, increasing as both returns to scale and market power increase. The range of values could depict a firm with a constant returns to scale production technology, facing a demand elasticity ranging from –10 to –2. This range should be broad enough to include nearly all the new and existing firms observable in less than perfectly competitive industries. The revenue function scale parameter A can be arbitrarily chosen; it was always set so mature firms would have 100 units of capital when c = 0.07. I turn now to numerical simulation, to determine whether the endogenous firm financing model leads to a similar conclusion. NUMERICAL SIMULATION The previous three sections have presented a Trapped Equity model, in which new firms are created with a limited amount of capital and a high debt/capital ratio, to then grow through 665 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 Table 1 reports the simulation results, when firms are assumed to be entirely equity financed. Before the capital gains tax cut, new firms begin with from 18.6 to 27.7 percent as much capital as mature firms, depending on the values of β and c.25 It then takes the firm from 9 to 62 years to reach maturity, with the greater time lengths associated with the lower values of both c and β. new firms. As the previous section noted, the tax cut has two opposite impacts on the value of K0: since the tax cut increases the desired level of capital at maturity, KT , the optimal initial level of capital will increase; but, since the tax cut also increases the length of time until maturity is reached, T, the optimal initial level of capital will fall. For small values of β, the former impact is dominant, but, as β rises, the latter impact comes to dominate. In general then, a capital gains tax cut, while necessarily increasing investment in mature firms, may in fact have the opposite impact on new firms. When the tax is cut to zero, the initial capital stock as a fraction of its level at maturity declines, becoming from 15.5 to 21.9 percent of the corresponding mature capital level. This is a relative decline of 4.5 percent (13.5 percent at c = 0.14) when β = 0.1, and of 16.6 percent (32.9 percent at c = 0.14) when β = 0.5. In every case, investment in mature firms increases by a greater absolute amount, and by a greater relative percent, than investment in new firms.26 The capital gains tax cut would shift investment toward mature firms, not new ventures. Table 2 simulates the case of a separating equilibrium, in which new firms are created by “small businessmen,” who face a higher effective capital gains tax rate than the “diversifiers” who own mature firms.27 At, for example, β = 0.167, the small businessman creates the firm with 20.6 units of capital, allowing it to grow through retained earning for the next 32 years, until K = 76.2. The diversifiers would then presumably purchase a controlling interest in the firm, taking it through internal growth to its mature size of K = 100. Perhaps, more significantly, at the larger values of β, the capital gains tax cut actually reduces the total investment in TABLE 1 ALL EQUITY MODEL Capital Gains Tax c = 0.14 Capital Gains Tax c = 0.07 β K0 KT K0 /KT T 0.10 0.17 0.25 0.33 0.50 15.5 20.6 23.1 23.5 21.6 63.5 76.2 83.4 87.3 91.3 0.244 0.271 0.277 0.270 0.231 50 32 21 15 9 Capital Gains Tax c = 0 K0 KT K0 /KT T K0 ' K T’ K0'/KT’ T’ 22.1 23.9 23.9 22.8 18.6 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 0.221 0.239 0.239 0.228 0.186 62 39 26 18 10 31.7 28.0 25.1 22.4 16.9 150.3 127.7 117.7 113.0 108.5 0.211 0.219 0.213 0.199 0.155 77 47 30 21 11 TABLE 2 SEPARATING EQUILIBRIUM Capital Gains Tax c = 0.14/0.07 Capital Gains Tax c = 0 β K0 KT K0 /KT T K0' KT’ K0' /KT ’ T’ 0.10 0.17 0.25 0.33 0.50 15.5 20.6 23.1 23.5 21.6 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 0.155 0.206 0.231 0.235 0.216 62 39 26 18 10 31.7 28.0 25.1 22.4 16.9 150.3 127.7 117.7 113.0 108.5 0.211 0.219 0.213 0.199 0.155 77 47 30 21 11 666 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT As Table 2 shows, in this separating equilibrium story, it is possible for the capital gains tax cut to increase the relative amount of capital in new firms —but only for small values of β. At β = 0.167, for example, the tax cut increases the small businessman’s initial investment to K = 28, a 36 percent increase, but expands the size of the diversifier-owned mature firm only 28 percent, to 127.7. However, at the three higher levels of β, the tax cut reduces the relative size of the initial capital stock in this separating equilibrium model, and at the two highest levels of β, the tax cut reduces the absolute size of the initial capital stock as well. The best that proponents of this separating equilibrium story can claim is that the capital gains tax cut might disproportionately benefit new firm investment, and, even then, they could not guaran- tee that new firm investment would increase at all. Table 3 reports the results of simulations in which firms are both equity and debt financed. Three sets of agency parameter values were used. Values for γ, which determined the optimal debt/ capital ratio in the absence of taxation, range from 0.003 to 0.25 and 0.30; the first value is used to verify that the model with very small amounts of debt gives approximately the same results as the all-equity model, while the latter two values more reasonably approximate actual debt/capital ratios. Values for ν, which determines the size of the firm’s agency costs, range from 0.1 to 1.0. The larger ν is, the greater the cost of deviating from the debt/capital ratio γ. In the first set of simulations, when ν equals 1, these debt/capital ratios stay TABLE 3 ENDOGENOUS DEBT γ = 0.003, ν = 1 Capital Gains Tax c = 0.07 Capital Gains Tax c = 0 β K0 KT K0 /KT λ0 λT T K0' KT’ K0'/KT’ λ 0' 0.10 70.1 0.25 0.33 0.50 22.1 24.6 25.2 24.7 21.9 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 0.221 0.246 0.252 0.248 0.219 0.027 0.040 0.060 0.086 0.165 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 62 39 25 17 9 31.7 28.8 26.5 24.4 20.2 150.1 127.6 117.6 113.0 108.5 0.211 0.226 0.225 0.216 0.186 0.022 0.036 0.058 0.086 0.179 λT’ 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 T’ 77 46 29 20 10 γ = 0.20, ν = 0.3 Capital Gains Tax c = 0.07 Capital Gains Tax c = 0 β K0 KT K0 /KT λ0 λT T K0' KT’ K0'/KT’ λ 0' 0.10 0.17 0.25 0.33 0.50 23.1 27.0 29.3 30.9 35.2 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 0.231 0.270 0.293 0.309 0.352 0.300 0.354 0.435 0.533 0.795 0.210 0.210 0.210 0.210 0.210 54 33 21 15 8 29.4 29.5 29.6 30.2 34.3 138.5 121.6 113.9 110.3 106.7 0.212 0.243 0.260 0.273 0.322 0.283 0.342 0.432 0.545 0.844 λT’ 0.193 0.193 0.193 0.193 0.193 T’ 67 39 25 17 10 γ = 0.30, ν = 0.1 Capital Gains Tax c = 0.07 Capital Gains Tax c = 0 β K0 KT K0 /KT λ0 λT T K0' KT’ K0'/KT’ λ 0' 0.10 0.17 0.25 0.33 0.50 32.3 42.0 52.6 61.5 76.8 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 0.323 0.420 0.526 0.615 0.768 0.620 0.767 0.921 1.052 1.302 0.330 0.330 0.330 0.330 0.330 49 31 22 17 12 37.8 43.6 52.7 61.6 77.8 132.8 118.6 112.0 108.9 105.8 0.284 0.367 0.471 0.566 0.735 0.565 0.733 0.911 1.060 1.330 667 λT’ 0.279 0.279 0.279 0.279 0.279 T’ 62 38 26 20 13 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 within a relatively narrow range, while the last set of simulations, when ν equals 0.1, allows firm financial policies to vary considerably more.28 have impacted both interest rates and exchange rates, in both cases, partially offsetting the impact of the tax cut. The numbers nevertheless support my central thesis here: that any increased corporate investment resulting from the capital gains tax cut will occur primarily in mature firms, with only a small or perhaps negative impact on new startups. The introduction of debt into the simulation increases the amount of investment in new firms relative to mature firms (K0/KT and K0'/KT’), reduces the capital growth the tax cut induces in mature firms (KT’ relative to KT), and reduces the length of time to maturity (T ).29 All three effects are small for γ = 0.003 and increase as γ increases. Summary This paper has examined the impact of a capital gains tax cut on new and established firms, assuming that new firms differed from their older counterparts because of the dividend trap. For all parameter values, the tax cut increased the mature firms’ desired capital stock, holding interest rates constant. More significantly, as in Table 1, in every simulation reported in Table 3, the capital gains tax cut reduces investment in new firms relative to mature firms (K0 / KT > K0'/KT’) and, in four cases, reduces the absolute level of investment in new firms (K0 > K0'). Hence, the endogenous financing model delivers the same message found in the all-equity model: in a trapped equity model, a capital gains tax cut would relatively favor established firms, not new startups. In nearly every case, however, the tax cut was more beneficial to mature firms than to new startups. And indeed, in many of the cases portrayed, the tax cut actually resulted in a reduction in new firm investment. Hence, this paper contradicts the widely held view that a capital gains tax cut would be a welltargeted approach for encouraging new firm capital formation. The previous simulations were run prior to the 1997 reduction in the top capital gains tax rate to 20 percent. Table 4 simulates the impact of that tax cut on new and established firms, for several of the previously examined sets of parameter values. Caution should be used in reading too much into these numbers: the simulations assume other things remained constant, whereas the predicted increase in domestic corporate demand for investment would likely Obviously, this paper does not preclude the possibility that the capital gains tax cut is nonetheless a desirable policy change. Clearly, its impacts on the cost of capital and on firm financial policy are desirable. But there are a variety of TABLE 4 REDUCTION IN THE CAPITAL GAINS TAX RATE TO 20 PERCENT Capital Gains Tax c = 0.07 Capital Gains Tax c = 0.05 β γ ν K0 KT λ0 λT T K0 ' K T’ λ0' λT ’ T’ %dK0 %dKT 0.17 0.17 0.25 0.25 0.33 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.3 27.0 42.0 29.3 52.6 30.9 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 0.35 0.77 0.44 0.92 0.53 0.21 0.33 0.21 0.33 0.21 39 26 39 26 18 27.7 42.4 29.4 52.6 30.7 105.9 105.0 103.9 103.3 102.9 0.35 0.76 0.43 0.92 0.54 0.20 0.31 0.20 0.31 0.20 47 30 47 30 21 2.5 0.9 0.2 0.0 –0.9 5.9 5.1 3.9 3.3 2.9 668 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT other tax instruments, such as a cut in the corporate tax rate, the various forms of tax integration, or a corporate cash flow tax, that can achieve similar impacts. Which tax policy provides these benefits with the fewest negative side effects is still an open question. This paper however does cast serious doubt on the capital gains tax cut’s alleged advantage over these other policy options, and will make it more difficult for its proponents to argue that it confers a policy advantage that these other policy options fail to provide. 9 ENDNOTES 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Typical of this view is Hauser (1995), who asserts that “because the [capital gains] tax restricts capital formation, its burden falls on new business startups.” Auerbach (1989) presents such an argument. This asset market equilibrium only examines the choice investors face between different saving instruments; the choice between saving and consumption is not considered. Therefore, the asset values that result from this analysis should be interpreted as values relative to other investment instruments, such as bonds. This presentation, for simplicity, treats the investment options as risk free. Poterba and Summers (1983) include a relatively simple analysis of risk in their asset market equilibrium, requiring that the risk-adjusted return to investors be the same across all assets. Their results are virtually identical to those presented here. A more complete asset market equilibrium would take into account the covariances between the return distributions of the various assets. Such a model is beyond the scope of this paper. The capital gain earned by existing shareholders will equal the increase in firm. value net of the value of new shares issued, (Vt – VNt). Capital gains are modeled here as being taxed on accrual. In reality, capital gains are taxed on a realization basis, and some are never taxed. However, since some fraction of all gains is continually being realized and taxed, it is conventional to consider our capital gains tax on realizations as approximately equivalent to an accrual capital gains tax with a substantially lower tax rate. See, for example, Sinn (1987) for the mathematical details. It can be easily shown that the value of a firm paying a constant dividend stream and making no 11 12 13 14 15 16 669 share repurchases will be invariant to the ordinary income tax rate. Intuitively, such a firm’s shares have a payoff structure identical to an infinitely lived bond; its value relative to such a bond therefore will be constant. If the dividend stream increases over time, the ordinary income tax will increase the current share value of a firm that will never repurchase shares; if a constant dividend firm also repurchases shares, the tax will reduce its current share value. Of course, since capital gains are taxed on realization rather than accrual, for many investors, there will be no loss in tax deferment. For at least some investors, however, those who need to liquidate some of their share holdings, the capital gains tax creates tax liabilities at the time of sale that reflect future dividend payments. This impact is similar to that which a lower rate accrual capital gains tax would generate and is modeled accordingly. An earlier version of this paper incorporated the rate of inflation into the model as well. To simplify the exposition, the inflation variable has been dropped; the simulations in the fifth section, however, are based upon the model with inflation. Copies of this section with the inflation variable are available from the author on request. See Harris and Raviv (1991) for a survey of the literature on agency costs. That literature suggests that increasing the debt/equity ratio will increase the conflicts of interest between equityholders and debtholders, including but not limited to bankruptcy costs, while reducing the conflicts between management and equityholders. The resulting optimal debt/equity ratio, even in the absence of taxation, will be an interior solution. Kanniainen and Södersten (1994) similarly adopted a monitoring cost function m(B,K) in their model. They assume that mK > 0, mB < 0, and mBB > 0, implying a convex cost function. See Zodrow (1991) for a discussion of the “Traditional” and “New” views of dividend taxation. Sinn (1991b,c) has argued that, even with share repurchases, many of the features of the New View continue to hold; Bernheim’s (1991) analysis of dividends as signals supports this argument. However, the important New View feature for this paper, that the initial level of investment in new firms should differ substantially from that of mature firms, would disappear if there were no binding constraint on repurchases at the margin. Neither dividends nor share repurchases will occur when (1 – θ)/(1 – c) > q > 1. ΨK measures the change in agency cost due to a change in capital, holding debt constant. Therefore, since additional capital must be equity financed, ΨK reflects the marginal agency cost of equity. See note 12. National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 17 18 As Gravelle and Kotlikoff (1989) point out, unless there are significant economies of large scale production to exploit, firms are unlikely to form as corporations in the first place. Similarly, Dixit and Pindyck (1994) show that, in the presence of risk, no firms will invest at all for sufficiently small β. This can be derived from the Cobb–Douglas function form as follows: Let R[Q(K,L)] = [ A (1 – β)(1 – α) α .[αW ] K ] 24 1–α 25 (1–α)(1–β ) α L . 26 Since the real wage rate will be assumed constant, including it in the revenue function is innocuous. Setting the marginal revenue product of labor equal to the wage rate, and solving for L, gives L= [ A (1 – α)(1 – β ) ][α ] W α K (1–β ) 27 19 20 21 which, when substituted into the revenue function and simplifying, gives equation 19. Mello and Parsons (1992) measured the agency cost of debt alone, using a contingent claims model of a firm that faces a randomly fluctuating market price. Their agency cost function is either approximately linear (at a low commodity price, where very little debt is optimal) or almost exactly quadratic (at a higher commodity price, where a substantial amount of debt is optimal). My assumed functional form is consistent with the latter case. See also note 12. More generally, the model can allow some share repurchases, but the total earnings so dispersed are constrained to some suboptimal level. The difference between the Traditional and New Views is not whether dividends are issues and shares repurchased, since in the United States both clearly occur. The difference is which form of distribution is available to the firm at the margin. From equations 3 and 20, the derivative ρ d ν 2 – λ dc (1 – u) 2 ( 22 23 ) = 28 29 ρ (1 – λ) anonymous referee for bringing his work to my attention. Because capital gains are not taxed until realized, and because gains held until death are untaxed altogether, the effective (accrual equivalent) capital gains tax rate is well below the statutory tax rate on realizations. Bailey (1969) estimated that when the statutory rate is 25 percent, the effective tax rate will be between 5 and 9 percent, depending on the rate of real gain accruals. Ballard et al. (1985) use the one-fourth statutory rate as a reasonable approximation. Figure 1 depicts the evolution of firm capital from birth to maturity, for β = 0.25. At c = 0.07 and β = 0.0617, investment in new and mature firms retains the same ratio, of 19 percent, before and after the tax cut; for smaller values of β, the ratio will rise when capital gains taxes are cut. Such low values of β imply demand elasticities greater than –16 and lengths to maturity of 92 years or longer, neither of which seems to reasonably reflect reality. Presumably, the small businessmen gain part of the deferral advantage of capital gains taxation, since they only pay the tax on realization, but not all of the advantage, since they are unable to hold a significant fraction of their gains until death. I am indebted to an anonymous referee, who suggested this scenario to me. Indeed, when ν equals 0.1, the simulated debt/ capital ratio for new firms exceeds one for the larger values of β. Although these results suggest that such a low value for ν is unreasonable, they are reported nonetheless, because they help verify the robustness of the model’s firm investment results, even into this untenable range of parameter values. As in the all-equity simulations, the values for the revenue function parameter A were chosen so mature firms, before the tax cut, would have 100 units of capital. REFERENCES (1 – u)(1 – c) Auerbach, Alan J. “Wealth Maximization and the Cost of Capital.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 93 No. 3 (August, 1979): 433–46. is positive, so dK/dc must be negative. The figure uses the baseline all-equity parameter values discussed in the next section, with β equal to 0.25, and an initial effective capital gains tax rate of 0.07. It corresponds with the simulation results reported in the third row of Table 1. Weichenrieder (1995), focusing on issues of dividend taxation rather than capital gains, simulated a trapped equity model similar to the one presented here. His numerical results are broadly consistent with mine. I am indebted to an Auerbach, Alan J. “Capital Gains Taxation and Tax Reform.” National Tax Journal 42 No. 3 (September, 1989): 391–401. Bailey, Martin J. “Capital Gains and Income Taxation.” In The Taxation of Income from Capital, edited by A. C. Harberger and M. J. Bailey. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institute, 1969. 670 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT Ballard, Charles L., Don Fullerton, John B. Shoven, and John Whalley. A General Equilibrium Model for Tax Policy Evaluation. Chicago: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1985. Sinn, Hans-Werner. Capital Income Taxation and Resource Allocation. Amsterdam: NorthHolland, 1987. Sinn, Hans-Werner. “The Vanishing Harberger Triangle.” Journal of Public Economics 45 No. 3 (August, 1991a): 271–300. Bernheim, B. Douglas. “Tax Policy and the Dividend Puzzle.” Rand Journal of Economics 22 No. 4 (Winter, 1991): 455–76. Sinn, Hans-Werner. “Taxation and the Cost of Capital: the ‘Old’ View, the ‘New’ View, and Another View.” In Tax Policy and the Economy 5, edited by David Bradford. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1991b. Bradford, David F. “The Incidence and Allocation Effects of a Tax on Corporate Distributions.” Journal of Public Economics 15 No. 1 (February, 1981): 1–22. Sinn, Hans-Werner. “Share Repurchases, the ‘New’ View, and the Cost of Capital.” Economics Letters 36 No. 2 (June, 1991c): 187–90. Dixit, Avinash K., and Robert S. Pindyck. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994. Stapleton, R. C. “Taxes, the Cost of Capital, and the Theory of Investment.” Economic Journal 82 (December, 1972): 1273–92. Gravelle, Jane G., and Laurence J. Kotlikoff. “The Incidence and Efficiency Costs of Corporate Taxation when Corporate and Noncorporate Firms Produce the Same Good.” Journal of Political Economy 97 No. 4 (August, 1989): 749– 80. Weichenrieder, Alfons J. Besteuerung und Direktinvestition (Taxation and Foreign Direct Investment). Tübingen: Mohr, 1995. Harris, Milton, and Arthur Raviv. “The Theory of Capital Structure.” Journal of Finance 46 No. 1 (March, 1991): 297–355. Zodrow, George R. “On the ‘Traditional’ and ‘New’ Views of Dividend Taxation.” National Tax Journal 44 No. 4 Part 2 (December, 1991): 497– 510. Hauser, W. Kurt. “Capital Gains: Lift the Burden.” The Wall Street Journal (October 24, 1995): A22. APPENDIX Hayashi, Fumio. “Corporate Finance Side of the Q Theory of Investment.” Journal of Public Economics 27 No. 3 (August, 1985): 261–80. For notational convenience, define Hulten, Charles R., and Frank C. Wycoff. “The Measurement of Economic Depreciation.” In Depreciation, Inflation, and the Taxation of Income from Capital, edited by Charles R. Hulten. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institute, 1981. A1 ∆ = δ(1 – u). In the all-equity model, equation 32 can be used to solve the canonical equation 29 for qt: Kanniainen, Vesa, and Jan Södersten. “Costs of Monitoring and Corporate Taxation.” Journal of Public Economics 55 No. 2 (October, 1994): 307–21. A2 King, Mervyn A. “Taxation and the Cost of Capital.” Review of Economic Studies 41 No. 1 (January, 1974): 21–35. qt = Mello, Antonio S., and John E. Parsons. “Measuring the Agency Cost of Debt.” Journal of Finance 47 No. 5 (December, 1992): 1887– 1904. 1–β ( ) [ (1 – β) ∆ 1 – θ (∆+ρ)(t–T) e 1–c (∆ + ρ)eβ∆(t–T) – (β∆ + ρ) ] β . At t = 0, qt equals one, so equation A2 implies Poterba, James M., and Lawrence H. Summers. “Dividend Taxes, Corporate Investment, and ‘Q’.” Journal of Public Economics 22 No. 2 (November, 1983): 135–67. A3 Pye, Gordon. “Preferential Tax Treatment of Capital Gains, Optimal Dividend Policy, and Capital Budgeting.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 86 No. 2 (May, 1972): 226–42. β (1–β)(∆+ρ)T = e 671 ( ) [ β 1 – θ (1–β) 1–c (1 – β) ∆ (∆ + ρ)e –β∆T – (β∆ + ρ) ] . National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. LI NO. 4 Also, at t = 0, equation 32 gives the initial capital stock equation A7 becomes A4 A9 K0β = { [ ( ) ]} β ∆ + ρ β∆T A(1 – u) 1– e (1 – β)∆ ∆+ρ R β ( ) – ( ) { 1–θ 1–c 1–β (∆ + ρ) – (1 – β)∆ R (β∆ + ρ) } (β∆+ρ) (1–β)∆ =1 which can be rearranged as an implicit function F(R,c). Its partial derivatives are A5 A10 –A(1 – u)[β∆ + ρ] (∆ + ρ)e –β∆T = β [(1 – β)∆K 0 – A(1 – u)] (∆ + ρ)(1 – R) ∂ In F = ∂R R[(∆ + ρ) – (1 – β)∆R] or which must be positive, since R < 1; A6 β ( )(∆+ρ)T = e 1–β { (∆ + ρ)[( 1– β)∆K0β – A(1 – u)] –A(1 – u)[β∆ + ρ] } A11 ∆+ρ (1–β)∆ . ∂ In F ∂ρ Substituting equation A5 into the denominator of A3, and equation A6 for the left-hand side of A3, gives = 1 (1 – β)∆ – A7 β 0 K = A(1 – u) 1–θ 1–c β 1–β ( ) [ ] ( ) { ∆+ρ A(1 – u)[β ∆ + ρ] (∆ + ρ)[A(1 – u) – (1 – β)∆K0β ] {[ In 1 + (1 – β)∆(1 – R) (1 – β)∆(1 – R) β∆ + ρ ] } ∆ + ρ – (1 – β)∆R and A12 (β∆+ρ) } (1–β)∆ . ∂ In F ρ∂ In F β = – . ∂c (1 – c)∂ρ (1 – β)(1 – c) Using equation 30, both the A(1 – u) terms can be replaced by (∆ + ρ) K Tβ. Defining R as Now, equation A11 will have the same sign as the term in brackets, which can be rewritten as {ln (1 + m1) – m0}; both m0 and m1 are positive. However, since (1 + m1) = 1/(1 – m0), that bracketed term is equal to –{m0 + ln (1 – m0)}. Replacing the logarithm with its Maclaurin expansion, and simplifying, gives A8 R = [K0/KT]β, A13 672 National Tax Journal Vol 51 no. 4 (December 1998) pp. 653-73 CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION AND NEW FIRM INVESTMENT This is consistent with equation 33, which showed a similar result for expanding firms. A13 ∂ In F ∂ρ = 1 (1 – β)∆ { m02 2 + m03 3 + m04 4 In contrast, the sign of equation A12 is not unambiguous: for sufficiently small (β/(1 – β)), it is positive; otherwise, it is negative. Hence, only for relatively small β (e.g., constant returns to scale production function, with extremely elastic firm demand curves) will dR/dc be negative, with a reduction in the capital gains tax, holding the interest rate constant, increasing the initial optimal capital stock relative to its level at maturity. } + ... which is clearly positive. Hence, by the implicit function theorem, dR/dρ must be negative, and a reduction in the discount rate will increase the initial optimal capital stock relative to its level at maturity. 673
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz