Chapter-I INTRODUCTION India's disadvantage during two centuries of British rule was not only limited to the depletion of the masses and increasing unemployment but also caused stress in the process of uneven spatial development. The differential economic spectrum in the states was the result of public investment geared to serve colonial interest. Therefore, after independence, India emerged as a federation of a few relatively 'rich and industrialized' states and of many poor states which depended mainly on agriculture with old techniques and semi-feudal agrarian relations. The theoretical formulation and the policy concern post independence should have been to correct the spatial imbalance. The planning process should have been designed to bring higher growth in the poor states in comparison to the rich states. It meant that poor states must achieve a higher rate of investment than the rich ones. Since the rate of saving in poor regions is less than the rich regions, private investment rate in poor areas is less than rich areas. Savings of the poor regions mostly get invested in industrialized regions therefore the rate of private investment in the poor economies is lower than in the rich ones. If the investment rates in the poor states are boosted either by private or public investment then uneven regional growth could be checked. Since, the taxable capacity and the amount of productive assets in the poor states remain lower than in the rich states, the rate of resource mobilization in the poor states will also be lower than in the rich states. Therefore, the rate of public investment and rate of growth of production in the rich states will remain higher than the poor ones causing the regional inequality to increase, unless the process is checked by transfer of adequate resources from the rich to the poor states. The implications were echoed in Finance Commission and planning commission reports, but its full implication has never been realized by the constitutional bodies and the institutions of the union government which are involved in 1|Page this process of transfer. The result is that the process of uneven regional growth continues even after six decades of independence. Government's economic policies during the colonial period were to protect British interests rather than the welfare of the Indians. The primary concerns of the government were law and order, tax collection and defence. As for development, Government adopted a basically laissez faire attitude. Railways and road network were developed to facilitate movements of goods and defence personnel than to facilitate better administrative control. Irrigation canal system was developed mainly to fight droughts and famines and to boost land revenue. Education, to begin with, was developed mainly to train lower ranking functionaries for the colonial administration. There was lack of a sustained policy to promote indigenous industry. It is believed that government policies were responsible for the decline of Indian traditional industry. Pre-independence period was that of stagnation of economy. The growth of aggregate output during the first half of the twentieth century is estimated at less than 2 percent per year, and per capita output by half of a percent a year or less. There was hardly any change in the structure of production. Productivity levels and the growth of modern manufacturing were counter-balanced by the displacement of traditional crafts. Along with a poverty-stricken economy, independent India also inherited some assets in the form of a transportation system, an administrative apparatus in working order, a shelf of concrete development projects and a comfortable level of foreign exchange. It can be argued whether the administrative apparatus of the British helped or hindered development since 1947, there is little doubt that its existence was a great help in restoring civil order, organizing relief and rehabilitation for millions of refugees and integrating the former princely states to the Union. The development projects initiated in 1944 for Post-war Reconstruction Program was of particular value to Independent India's first government. Under the guidance of the Planning and Development Department created by the Central Government, a great deal of useful work was done before independence to outline the broad strategy and policies for development of major sectors and translate them into programs and projects. 2|Page At the time of Independence several of projects and programs were ready to be taken up. They included programs and projects in agriculture, irrigation, fertilizer, railways, newsprint and so on. First Five Year Plan began in 1950-51 but planning commission came in place during second Five Year Plan. Main basis of the first Five Year Plan was the groundwork done before independence. Almost all the principal projects were continuations and great deal of efforts were made to complete them early. During last two decades Indian economy has experienced an average annual growth rate of around 6 percent. It was quite impressive compared to the performance of economy during the preceding three decades when the average growth lagged 3.5 percent per annum. The growth rate of 3.5 percent during the first three decades of the republic had been better than the virtual stagnation of the Indian economy during the first half of the twentieth century. In per capita income, the improvement has been even better around 4 percent per annum in the recent period as compared to less than 1.5 percent in the earlier period. During the recent period, acceleration can be seen in the growth performance over the years. The average compound growth per annum was 5.7 percent during the sixth Five Year Plan (1980-85), 6.0 percent during the Seventh Plan (1985-90) and 6.6 percent during the Eighth Plan (1992-97). Growth rate dropped to 3.1 percent during 1990-92 as a result of international payment crisis and introduction of major economic reforms. Indeed, the growth averaged about 7.5 percent during the three-year period ending 1996-97, which is good by any standards. The growth rate has been lower between1998-2000. In contrast to stagnation/negative growth of East Asian economies India's performance, however, is remarkable. The World Bank and other international agencies had characterized India as one of the fastest growing economies of the world. Along with faster economic growth and reduction in poverty, there has been considerable improvement in various human development indicators, social development indicators and demographic characteristics since 1980s. During the last twenty years, the country has made major strides in health and education sectors. The share of the service sector in employment and incomes improved considerably in the economy. There is a broad consensus in the overall improvement of the economy and quality of life but different opinions about the distributional impacts of these gains. 3|Page Disparities in economic and social development across and intra-regional disparities among different segments of the society have been the major planks for adopting planning process in India since independence. In addition to massive investments in backward regions, many public policies directed at encouraging private investments in such regions have been pursued during the first three decades of planned development. While efforts to reduce regional disparities were not lacking, achievements were not often commensurate with these efforts. There was Considerable level of regional disparities at the end of the seventies. It is believed that accelerated economic growth since the early eighties have increased regional disparities. The ongoing economic reforms of liberalisation, privatisation and globalisation since 1991 have further widened the regional disparities. The problem of acute regional imbalances has not yet received the public attention it deserves. Rising inequality can create economic and political problems for any country. It has serious ramifications for the continuation of the reforms process in the Indian economy. It is very important to understand the impact of reforms on the regional inequality in the economy. It is interesting to measure the contribution of tertiary sectors to regional inequality in India and study the impact of the reforms on the services sector contribution. Average services sector growth rate during the 1980s was 6.6 percent, but rose sharply to a high 7.6 percent in the 1990s. Agricultural and the industrial growth rates played significant roles in the 1980s but the services sector was the engine of growth during the 1990s and 2000s. Regional imbalance has been one of the major concerns before policy makers and planners. There had been a huge gap between active and vibrant regions and hinterland in terms of availability of facilities and this has resulted in unequal levels of economic and human development. World Bank (2006) in its reported entitled, "India-Inclusive Growth and Service Delivery: Building of India's Success" has observed sharp differentiation across states since the early 1990s reflects acceleration of growth in some states and lagging behind of others. The report further adds that growth failed to pick up in states such as Bihar, Odisha and U.P. that were initially poor and it means gap between rich and poor states widened dramatically during the 1990s. The World Bank again in its recent 4|Page release (2008) has mentioned that disparity in income distribution in India has risen during 1993-2005 which is revealed by the fact that Gini coefficient in this connection has risen from 0.3152 in 1993-94 to 0.3676 in 2004-05. The Draft of Eleventh Five Year Plan (2007-2012, Vol. 1) has also admitted that regional disparities have continued to grow and the benefits of economic growth have been largely confined to the developed areas. The nexus between growth and inequality has been debated extensively by the scholars and empirical investigations. For example, starting with the classical economists, Ricardo’s two sector model concentrated on growth and distribution within agriculture and industry addressed the shares of rent and profits and growth process eventually approaching the steady state zero growth due to diminishing returns in agriculture (Boyer, 1996). Karl Marx believed that capitalism would result in uneven distribution of wealth and capitalist have an incentive for pushing wages to the subsistence level (Martin and Sunley-1998, Dunford and Smith-2000) The neo-classical growth models for closed economies (Solow 1956,1957,1970) Cass (1965), and Koopmans (1965) state that per capita growth rate tends to be inversely related to the starting level of output/income per head and if economies are similar in respect of preferences and technologies, then poor economies grow faster than rich ones. The neoclassical were more optimistic about market forces and believed that regional inequality is a passing phase and that market forces would ensure that the returns to all factors of production would approach their marginal products (Smith, 1975). Neo-Keynesian growth models says that reduction in concentration raises the real wage and provides a redistribution of income which leads to higher utilization and higher rate of economic growth. The link between inequality and average well being for two sector economy is known as Kuznets hypothesis (1953,1963) which maintains that given a two sector economy with not too distinct degrees of sectoral Mean incomes, a perennial shift of population from one sector to another will initially raise aggregate inequality and it will decrease at later stage. This formulation has been labelled as the "Inverted U" (1-U) hypothesis or Kuznets cycle (Branlke, 1983). The Convergence hypothesis asserts that differences in per capita income between any pair of regions will be transitory so long as the two regions contain identical technologies, preferences and population growth (Bernard and Durlauf, 1966). 5|Page The bulk of the new theoretical literature on growth and inequality has focused on models which generate divergence across nations. The long-term progress in raising rural living standards has been diverse across Indian states (Datt and Ravallion, 1998). Such disparities are responsible for various states having different capacities for poverty reduction (Datt and Ravallion 2002). Similarly, Rajarshi Majumdar (2004) in his paper titled, "Human Development in India : Regional Pattern and Policy Issues" says that states like Kerala, Maharashtra and Himachal Pradesh put up good performance regarding social and human development indicators but Kerala has not been able to convert its social development into economic progress. On the other hand, Gujarat having low Human Development (HD) ranks, has good ranking in per capita Net State Domestic Product (PCNSDP). Services sector is a complex area and very often one finds different definitions of services. The traditional belief that services cannot be stored and they are consumed as soon as they are produced is not necessarily true. Due to technology, there is increasing time gap between consumption and production of services. Some services can be provided from the same storage repeatedly over a period of time and some services can be reproduced with fewer input and in a much shorter time span. Common definition of services sector includes labour services, travel, transport, port & shipping and other related services, insurance banking and other financial services, construction and engineering design services, education, tourism, health care and miscellaneous and other private services. Development theory says an economy evolves from a predominant agriculture oriented set-up to a nature of industrial economy satisfying Rostow’s four stages and Kuznets’s characteristic features of growth. It is believed that as income grow, the production structure changes due to changes in income elasticity of demand in favour of manufactured goods. In the case of employment, a shift away from primary sector was also observed, a part of the transfer of labour from the primary sector went into industry but on an average the main beneficiary was the service sector." In India, there is rapid transition from agriculture to services, with industry lagging behind. Inter-sectoral growth 6|Page movements show the declining share of agriculture in total output and rapidly rising share of service sector. Some economists hold the view that the net domestic product becomes a misleading indicator of economic progress if the service sector grows rapidly as a part of the output of this sector and does not contribute to the growth potential of the economy. Some economists believe growth of service sector accentuate the existing skewed income distribution. Some opined that growth of service sector should not cause any alarm and government should take measures to enhance its role, in view of the need of the economy to create strong infrastructure and for providing shelter and employment to the people. The service sector contributes about half of the world GDP. The share of this sector in the GDP increases, generally, as economy develops. Developed economics are predominantly service economies and generate over 60 percent of the total employment. Services assume special importance for developing countries. Services like banking, communication, transportation etc. provide infrastructure services to the entire economy. In the low income economies, services contribute more than one third of the GDP. The share of the services in India's GDP increased from 38.04 percent in 1980-81 to 41 percent in 1990-91 then the share increased to 57.30 percent in 2009-10. Service sector generally grows faster than the economy as a whole. The growing importance of services is reflected in the international trade too. Between 1970-1990 international trade in services increased by an average of 12 percent annually reaching $ 800 billion by 1990. The value of international trade in services is one fourth of the value of the trade in goods. Services make up a major chunk of the invisibles account in the balance of payments. The service sector in economic theory has evolved from being an unimportant and a residual sector during Adam Smith's time to being the leading sector for growth in present day economies. According to the theory of structural transformation an economy evolves from a primary agrarian one, where the agricultural sector dominates, to an industrial one, where the manufacturing sector is the largest one, to the services sector where the services dominates. At the micro level, as income increases, the expenditure on 7|Page food increases less than proportionately and on consumer durable goods more than proportionately. With further increase in income, the expenditure on goods does not increase proportionately, but increases more than proportionately on travel, health, education, communications and financial services. The structural transformation of an economy takes place mainly along two dimensions: one is sectoral share in GDP and the second is share of the labour force engaged in each sector. In developed countries the agricultural sector loses its importance with a simultaneous growth of the manufacturing sector. Most developed countries and some industrialized countries have crossed this stage and are now shifting from manufacturing sector to the services sector. Developed economies experience an increase in the share of the service sector in both, the total GDP and the labour force. These countries have witnessed a typical pattern of structural transformation in which the share of agriculture has declined and the share of manufacturing has increased, peaked at a certain level and then declined, accompanied by an increase in the share of the services sector. Employment in manufacturing sector as a share of total employment has fallen in world's most advanced economies. In India, the shares of the services sectors in GDP have increased dramatically. The share of the primary sector in GDP is declining and that of secondary and tertiary are growing. The tertiary sector has become the highest contributor to GDP displacing the primary sector. The share of the labour in the primary sector has remained high. The tertiary sector's share in the workforce has increased over the years but still it has not been able to displace the primary sector's position. Thus, in terms of employment the primary sector provides the maximum employment. The growth of the tertiary sector in India seems to be somewhat out of line with international experience in recent decades. The newly industrializing countries of AsiaKorea and Taiwan – had their share of employment in manufacturing increasing much faster than that in the tertiary sector during their initial period of growth in the 1970s. Only in the 1990s after Taiwan and Korea had development into mature industrialized economies did their tertiary sector become the dominant provider of employment outside agriculture. In India share of employment growth in the tertiary sector in the 1970s was 8|Page already 60 percent higher than that in manufacturing. In 1980s and 1990s there was a virtual stagnation in the share of employment in manufacturing. The debate about "excess" growth of the service sector (Bhattacharya and Mitra, 1990, 1991) emerged out of this difference in the pattern of development of the Developed countries and less developed countries. Bhattacharya and Mitra contend that the service sector is growing at a much faster rate than the commodity output. They call this 'excess growth'. They opine that this imbalance in growth between the two will lead to inflation and imports for consumption. According to them, "it appears that income from service sector is growing many folds more than the demand generated for the services by the commodity sector". Elsewhere they write, "The growth of service income would therefore increase only demand for commodities without any effect on supply. Their argument implies that a balance between the growth of the commodity sector and the service sectors is necessary. This need not be so. The domestic commodity sector need not be the only source of demand for the service sector; demand for services can come from other sources like final consumption, exports increased urbanization and women entering the workforce. The authors themselves admit that the exogenous source of demand has far outweighed the commodity sector demand. Two features of the Indian case stand out in contrast to the developed countries pattern of structural transformation. In the developed countries the decline in the share of agricultural GDP resulted in an increase in the share of manufacturing GDP and only after that did the share of manufacturing decline and the share of services increased. In India, the share of manufacturing did not increase much. The process of structural change was characterized by a decline in the share of agriculture GDP and an increase in the share of GDP from services. The second difference was that in the developed countries the changing shares of the three sectors in GDP were mirrored in the changing share of employment/labour force in these three sectors. In India, the changing shares of sectoral GDP were not mirrored by the changes in the labour force shares. During the process of growth over the years 1980-81 to 2009-10, the Indian economy has experienced a change in the production structure with a shift away from agriculture towards industry and the tertiary sector. The share of agricultural sector in real 9|Page GDP, at 2004-05 prices, declined from 35.69 percent in the 1980-81s to 29.53 percent in 1990-91 and 14.64 percent in 2009-10. The share of industrial sector increased from 25.66 percent to 27.63 percent and 28.27 percent and the share of service sector increased from 37.65 percent to 42.55 percent and 57.09 percent respectively during the same period. During the 1950s it was the primary sector that was the dominant sector of the economy and that accounted for the largest share in GDP. But the whole scenario changed subsequently, and especially in the 1980s. Services sector output increased at a rate of 6.63 percent per annum in the period 1980-81 to 1989-90 (i.e. pre-reform period) compared with 7.71 percent per annum in the period 1990-91 to 2000-2001 (i.e. postreform period) further to 9.15 percent per annum in the period 2001-02 to 2010-11. the tertiary sector emerged as the major sector of the economy both in terms of growth rates and share in GDP in the 1990s. Agriculture and manufacturing sectors have experienced phases of stagnation and growth, the tertiary sector has shown a uniform growth trend during the period 1980-81 to 2009-10. Growth of services sector has imparted resilience to the economy. Keynesian literature believes that income distribution is central to the pace and pattern of economic growth in terms of its implications for aggregate demand. In the mainstream economic discourse micro-economic arguments are increasingly brought in to understand how greater equality is conducive to faster economic growth. Another stand in the recent years, on the basis of public choice theoretic literature, has shown how income distribution influences economic growth as it affects voting behaviour in a democracy (Tanzi and Chu 1998). In this genre of literature, there are several chains of causation, in which initial level of inequality affects economic outcomes. A fiscal channel suggests that income inequality creates a demand for redistributive fiscal policy. In a median voter model, the key measure of inequality is the level of income or wealth of the median voter relative to the average. The poorer the median voter in relation to the average, the larger the amount of redistribution that, a majority of voters will favour. Impoverished fraction of the population creates political pressure for redistributive policies. It may take different forms in different institutional contexts but it is generally felt in both democracies and dictatorships. In fact, in order to survive, even dictators cannot totally ignore popular demands. Redistributive fiscal policies lead to high levels of 10 | P a g e taxation, which negatively affects growth in the long run. Thus, the chain of causation goes from high initial income inequality to high taxes and from large redistributions to low growth. An alternative argument is that the rich in every society have the political and economic resources to escape taxation through capital flight or by tax evasion. Demand for redistribution policies with a vanishing tax base may lead to large budget deficits. A second channel linking inequality and macroeconomic performance goes through political instability. Income inequality fosters social discontent and unrest. The associated threats to property rights, policy volatility and government fragility depress productive investment, promote capital flight and ultimately reduce growth (Alisena 1998: 301) Empirically, it has been found that in the OECD countries, in the post-war period, economies with less unequal income distribution have performed better. Similarly, comparing the performance of the East Asian economies with those of Latin America, Jeffery Sachs contended, "....high income inequality....(In Latin America) contributes to intense political pressure for macro-economic policies to raise income of lower income groups, which in turn contributes to bad policy choices and weak economic performance" (Sachs 1989 :9). In most states, the share of the service sector now exceeds 50 percent of SDP. During the last three decades, the service sector has grown on an average by 8 to 9 percent per annum in many states, notably Gujarat, Haryana, Kerala, Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu and West Bengal with the exception of Gujarat, the service sector now accounts for almost half of SDP in all rich states. Transition of the India from an agrarian economy to an economy dominated by service sector, thereby bypassing the stage of a developed industrial economy, is increasing economic inequalities. The economic performance of different regions in India has been extremely different over the past three decades which has resulted in higher level of regional disparities. The growth of the services sector in the Indian economy has its own limitation. The economic and social position of the worker in the services sector will steadily go 11 | P a g e down in the long run since real income cannot be higher than productivity for any extended length of time. The workers in the service sector will use all their strength and put all efforts to get higher wages, than their economic contribution justifies. To some extent, increases in regional inequality are driven by factors that are necessary for accelerated growth-in particular, the more efficient allocation of private capital, foreign as well as domestic. State government policies can make a lot of difference: government in poorer states such as Madhya Pradesh and Rajasthan have made strides in improving, on average, the relative standard of living of their constitution. Hence we cannot say that liberalization necessarily leave certain states behind. At the sub state level, some states are facing greater disparities emerging within their boundaries. One might guess that intra-state labour mobility is greater than across states, so that this problem may be more self-correcting than inter-state disparities. On the other hand, the problem may be mobility across rural and urban areas, and across social boundaries. The evidence is consistent with the point of view that the reforms have had a greater positive impact in urban areas, leaving rural areas to await meaningful agricultural reform (removing distortions on pricing and distribution, and improving infrastructure). Intrastate disparities also put the focus on effective state government policies, including building the fiscal and institutional capacity of nascent local governments to deliver local public goods and services. The central government may also draw some policy lessons from the empirical evidence on regional inequality as it shows very clearly that intergovernmental transfers cannot remove such inequalities. Streamlining and improving the centre-state transfer system can only help isolate any inter-state disparities that are likely to cause political tensions, and make clear the redistributive effort that is politically necessary. In this respect, it is important to recognize that implicit financial transfers by the central government, through its control of the financial system, have been important and have often favoured higher income states (Rao Shand and Kalirajan 1999). Reducing the role of pervasive government in the financial sector can be an important component to making the inter-governmental transfer system at all levels (centre-state, state-local and centre-local) more efficient, if inter-regional inequalities are to be clearly addressed by government policy. If we look at India's record with respect to inequality in the postreform period then we find it is not bad, with respect to potential problems of growing 12 | P a g e regional disparities. Economic reform has actually done better in many ways than any commentators have expected. Clearly we do have policy improvements that can help us further in managing inequalities, but they are much more in the spirit of further reform than of any backpedalling. As economy progresses the share of the primary sector decreases and that of the secondary sector increases. After industrialization gathers momentum, the secondary sector becomes the dominant sector in the economy. It is only at a later stage when the economy attains a fairly high level of development typically when it becomes a middle income country that the tertiary sector overtakes the secondary sector. This is the general pattern of development seem, especially in East Asia. If we take the example of China, the secondary sector now contributes almost 50% of GDP. In India, at aggregate level, and also at the regional level, the tertiary sector became the largest sector even before the secondary sector can dominate the economy. The pattern of structural changes which we noticed in India deviated from the development pattern of other western economies. According to Kuznets western economies experienced a stage by stage shift from primary to secondary and from secondary to tertiary in their advanced stage of development but in India this trend is not visible. The expansion of the secondary sector is not enough in India so as to absorb the increase in labour force. The unskilled and uneducated rural masses have continued to struggle in the primary sector and those who have been forced out of the primary sector by economic, social and political factors have joined urban slum sectors. The pattern of growth underlines the link between growing poverty and unemployment and the inadequate growth of manufacturing and building activities in the economy. The development of infrastructure industries to meet the growing demand in the economy increases the role of public services in the economy. The effect is a result of growing mobility due to expanding trade, tourism urbanization etc. They are mainly responsible for the growth of the services sector. The above factors are internal factors which resulted in expansion of the tertiary sector. External development such as expansion of knowledge based services, progress of information technology etc. are responsible for the growth of the tertiary sector in the economy. Sectors like trade, hotels, 13 | P a g e restaurants, storage, communication, finance, insurance real estate and business services have experienced high trend in growth rate within the services sector. A probable interpretation of the phenomenon could be upsurge in industries related to services sector in recent years. The share of primary sector in national income has decreased from 35.69% in 1980-81 to 14.64% in 2009-10, while the share of services sector has increased from 37.65% in 1980-81 & 57.09% in 2009-10. This has led to inequality in distribution of income in various sectors. On the one hand in primary sectors 55.9% of labour force is earning only 14.64% of national income, on the other hands in services sector 25.4% of labour force earning 57.09% of national income. The annual growth rate of per capita gross state domestic product (GSDP) in Punjab, Himachal Pradesh and Haryana increased. In Bihar and U.P. the growth rate declined. Disparity in services sector is one of the main reasons of inequality in per capita income. Rural urban inequalities in consumer expenditure have increased. The salaries of public sector employees have grown at 5% per annum while agricultural wages grew at the rate of 2.5% per annum in 1990s. Intra rural inequalities have not risen while intra urban inequalities have increased. In fact it is work even when one takes note public consumption (education, health services etc.) for the poor. There is an inverse relationship between population growth and income growth across the states in 1990s. This has a very serious implication not only for growth but also for employment. The poorer states notably Bihar and U.P. with higher population growth have performed badly in terms of SDP growth in 1990s. In the post reform era the inverse relationship between income and population growth has become a serious problem not only economically out also politically. The rapid growth has been an inequitable growth as the poor are being by passed and marginalized by structural changes of modern growth. Widespread poverty creates condition in which the poor have no access to credit facilities and they are unable to finance their children's education, health and nutrition which will lead to lower economic productivity and thereby lead directly and indirectly to a slower growing economy. 14 | P a g e Major problem in India is not only huge difference in per capita income but also the fact that rate of growth of state income is higher in rich states than poor states. BIMARU (Bihar, M.P., Rajasthan and U.P.) have per capita income as well as low rate of growth of state income. Deposit mobilization by commercial bank also reflects the relative prosperity of some states. In 1998 per capita bank deposits of Maharashtra and Punjab were Rs. 13,200 and 11962 respectively as against per capita deposits in Assam and Odisha of only Rs. 2359 and Rs 2506 respectively. Disparity in education sector is also a major cause of inequality in service sector in major states of India. Educational disparity is startling between various states and regions of India. While the state of Kerala is exceptional with 91% literary, the second most literate state is Himachal Pradesh with 77% and least literate state is Bihar with only 48% of citizens educated. The second distressing aspect is rural –urban disparity in literacy which is 27% favouring urban areas. The National Human Development Report-2001 for India reveals considerable differences in human development among Indian states during 1981-2001. The report notes that in the early eighties, states like Bihar, U.P., M.P. Rajasthan and Odisha had HDI close to just half that of Kerala's. The inter-state differences in human poverty are quite striking and report notes that while there have been improvements in the human development index and human poverty index during the 1980's, the inter-state disparities and the relative position of the states has practically remained the same. Facts show that inter-state disparity as measured and stood at 0.100 in 1991 [Tenth Five Year Plan (200207) Vol. III]. An approach to the 11th Five Year Plan (Planning Commission, Government of India, 2006) has also acknowledged regional backwardness as an issue of concern. The differences across states have long been a cause of concern for the planners of country because we cannot let large parts of the country be trapped in a prison of discontent, injustice and frustration that will only breed extremism. India is a vast multilingual, multi-cultural country with a federal, democratic polity, a pluralistic society and large inter-state disparities in levels of development arising out of differences in factor endowment, infrastructural facilities and literacy education and employment levels. Regional disparity is now a matter of serious concern for the country. It is well known that in large economy different regions with different resource bases and endowments 15 | P a g e would have a dissimilar growth path over time. The transition of the country from an agrarian economy to an economy dominated by services, by passing the stage of a developed industrial economy is further aggravating economic inequalities in India. 1.1 Objectives of the Study In this work it has been broadly hypothesized that the liberalization, characterized by excessive and skewed tertiarization of the economy, has its own consequences in terms of structure, linkage pattern and macro dynamics of the system. From this point of view the main objectives of the study are –: To analyse the nature, structure and growth of services sector in Indian Economy. To delineate the structural change in tertiary sector into its time and space dimension in India. To study the inequality in benefits from reform in major states of India. To explore the sustainability of services sector growth in India. To explore whether disparities in services sector growth is the cause of regional disparities. 1.2 Hypothesis Keeping in view the broad objectives of the study the main hypothesis to be treated in the field are: Regional disparity has widened significantly during the 1990s whether this is due to ongoing economic reform is a matter of investigation. A proper test of convergence would be required to estimate the impact of initial levels of income on subsequent periods of growth. Economic growth divergence can be obtained through the coefficient of variation in per capita income across the states over time. 16 | P a g e 1.3 Area of Study The present study has been undertaken for regional disparities in services sector. In order to accomplish the task, inter-state disparity in total as well as per capita GSDP for 16 major Indian states has been taken for the period 1980-1981 to 2009-10. The states selected for this study are Andhra Pradesh, Assam, Bihar, Gujarat, Haryana, Himachal Pradesh, Karnataka, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Odisha, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. Three newly formed states namely Chattisgarh, Jharkhand and Uttaranchal are taken from the time period 2000-01 to 200910, before that in order to avoid complexities arising out of the re organisation of states data till 1999-2000 is used which is the last year from which data from the undivided states is available. Bihar, M.P. and U.P. therefore refers to undivided states uptil 19992000. These states together account for 91 percent of the population of India and the remaining 9 percent is spread in 12 smaller states and seven union territories including Delhi (GOI, 2001). Jammu and Kashmir will be excluded because of political disturbances during 1990's. Pondicherry and six smaller states of north-east will be excluded because they are too small to reflect general economic behaviour of states in India. The small state of Goa has been excluded from the analysis because of the significant differences in the structure of its economies from the rest of the states and therefore its steady state values of income are likely to be different. In order to generate data on the aggregate and Sectoral output of the states for this study are obtained from the central statistical organization (CSO). The GSDP and the population data series for the states will be revised according to analytical convenience. 1.4 Methodology Keeping in view the broad objectives of the study the main hypothesis to be treated in the field are: Regional disparity has widened significantly during the 1990s whether this is due to ongoing economic reform is a matter of investigation. 17 | P a g e A proper test of convergence would be required to estimate the impact of initial levels of income on subsequent periods of growth. Economic growth divergence can be obtained through the coefficient of variation in per capita income across the states over time. The coefficient of variation is one of the most widely used measures of regional inequality. This measure is standardised and can be used to make comparison between regions. The weighted coefficient of variation is calculated as follows: 𝐶𝑉𝑤 = √∑ni(𝑦𝑖 − y ∗ )2 𝑃𝑖 𝑃 𝑦∗ Where Pi refers to population of the ith state P refers to population of the country Yi refers to per capita GSDP,of the ith state Y* refers to per capita national income and n refers to number of states. This measure in better for cross country comparison as the measure of inequality depends not only on the number of regions but also on the population proportion of the regions. 1.5 Tentative Chapters The chapterization of the proposed study is designed as follows:1. Introduction. 2. Review of Literature. 3. Role of Services Sector in Economic Development. 4. Inter-Linkages between Sectors. 5. Growth Performance of the States. 18 | P a g e 6. Regional Disparities in Services Sector in India. 7. Sustainability of Services Sector in Indian Economy. 8. Conclusion. Bibliography. 1.6 Limitations of the Study Empirical research in services in India is limited. There is a lack of reliable, timely and easily interpretable data. Trade data on services at a more disaggregated level, consistent with value added and employment data and comparable across time would go a long way in promoting research in this field. Constructing and index for services would also help in assessing services. Such an index can be constructed by first identifying suitable measures for the output of different services and then attaching appropriate waits to different services. This will not only help in assessing the growth in different services but also help in formulating policies viz-a-viz disaggregated services. At this stage, it is important to note some limitations of SDP data. First, there are some conceptual problems of measuring GDP at the state level. Secondary, although we have used CSO compiled SDP data, they are based on the primary data of production and prices collected by the concerned state statistical department. The CSO only processes and makes corrections in the methodology of SDP measurement, particularly the value added component, but it does not change the original data on production and prices. It is well known that there are a lot of measurement problems at the state level and at the national level. In some states the quality of primary data is very weak, partly because of poor statistical systems and partly because of biases in data collection and dissemination. In many cases, checking for consistency raises doubts about the quality of original data. For instance, we find a very poor relationship between electricity consumption and industrial growth in some states. In some other states, SDP growth is at variance with employment growth in both industry and tertiary sectors. The relationship between input and output in agriculture is also weak in some states. Thirdly, in some cases unusually high agricultural growth for a long period of time, more than two decades for instance, raises doubts about the authenticity of data. It appears that either the law of diminishing 19 | P a g e marginal returns does not apply or that hidden structural changes have not been recognized independently. Finally, a large share of employment in India is in "selfemployment" category, there is an inherent difficulty in allocating income accruing from self-employment when more than one earner from the same household is in an incomeearning activity. Households from different self-employed activities by different members of the household would be typically pooled together. There is no way of distinguishing the individual contributions of individual earners. These limitations have to be borne in mind while measuring growth and disparity at the state level with SDP data. Hence the substance of the analysis will be based on the study of trends in the tertiary sector as a whole. 20 | P a g e Chapter-II REVIEW OF LITERATURE Several theories and models have been developed, since the beginning of the mid50s, to provide theoretical frameworks for understanding regional economic problems. Different factors have been identified as determinants of growth in different growth models. Among the various growth models, the most popular ones are Export base models, Neo-classical models, Cumulative causation (Myrdal-Kaldor) models, Econometric models, Input-output-models and Multi sector development planning models (Richardson 1973) The usefulness of these models cannot be denied by us but their applicability cannot be universal. Their applicability will be determined in view of the differences in resource endowments, economic strategies, capital formation and institutions among countries, and within a country among different regions and states. If we take the Indian context, the well known hypothesis of an inverted U-shaped curve was developed by Hirschman (1958). This hypothesis gets reinstated by the empirical statements from Kuznets (1957) and Williamson (1965) which state that as an economy grows, regional disparities diverge at first only to converge later. Kuznets studies have very well shown us that in several European countries the position of lowincome groups was relatively worse in the early years of industrialization or economic growth. Udall lends support to Kuznets and Galenson in suggesting a shift in the demand for labour in the long run toward tertiary sector. Kuznets says that with economic development the share of tertiary employment in the labour force increases mainly because of slow growth of technical progress in services, a high income elasticity of demand for some of the tertiary activities and increasing urbanization resulting in rise in the demand for services like transport and distribution. It is viewed that increase in 21 | P a g e manufacturing activity leads to a rise in tertiary employment as income growth originating from the expansion of manufacturing activity raises the consumption of services and also the demand for service inputs-into manufacturing. The growth of employment in tertiary activities is viewed mainly from two different angles: (a) treating it primarily as a 'supply push' phenomenon and (b) rationalizing its growth in terms of 'demand induced' hypothesis. Extreme economic under development and high levels of economic development are associated with greater income inequality. It results in the possibilities of regional disparities changing with the stage of development. If we see from a theoretical point of view not much work has been done but the empirical work conducted in India in the field of regional economics has been considerable. The major finding is the simple idea that a region with lower per capita income should grow faster tends to hold for almost all countries experimented so for. The US, Canada, Japan and Europe clearly show the required 'negative' relationship between initial 'per capital income' and annual average growth rate over a long period of time. If one believes in the data set, no one can deny both the visible scatter as well as the statistical relationship hidden therein the point that within a national boundary, the poorer region has grown faster than the richer ones, is well taken. A theoretical problem with the so-called convergence hypothesis is that, on the one hand, such models depend on a neoclassical specification of the growth process but fail to justify the restricted mobility of resources which leads to protracted convergence with perfect or extensive resource mobility. Convergence should have been instantaneous. This problem has been mentioned in Marjit and Mitra (1996) and Sala-i-Martin. Barro et al analyze a model of partial mobility of capital and convergence across countries. The main observation of the empirical research is that there have been evidences of 'convergence' in Europe, USA, Canada and in Japan this also reinforces the strength of Solow model vis-a-vis endogenous growth models. A large percentage of workforce particularly in the developing countries is located in tertiary activities is attributed to a lack of employment opportunities in manufacturing and agriculture resulting from technological change, factor market imperfections and rapid increase in the labour force (Meier 1970). It is often argued that 22 | P a g e only a small proportion of tertiary employment in the less developed countries is a function of the income elasticity of demand for services, and majority of it is believed to be a manifestation of excess supplies of labour relative to demand. Every supply of labour is taken to create its own employment in this sector by sharing out a given amount of work (Bhalla 1970). There is no doubt that it appears to be one of the extreme views. Udall (1976) points out that the demand for service employment is usually taken in the literature to be relatively elastic (with respect to price). It is quite evident from the literature that the tertiary sector comprises of highly heterogeneous jobs which responds differentially to demand and supply factors. The degree of responsiveness to a particular set of factors also varies depending upon the nature of jobs within the tertiary sector. Greenfield (1966), for example by dividing the services into consumer and producer categories, noted that 'production' services grow as industrial corporations in order to reduce their costs and use the knowledge of the experts shift some of the tasks previously performed by them, to the producer service firms. The demand for producer services is expected to rise in a growing economy, with increasing specialization and capital accumulation. The service organizations in various countries have become large users of information technology with a shift to a predominantly service economy, and it has given rise to a large demand for service functions allied to the operation of the computer hardware. Rising female labour force participation is expected to have a positive effect on tertiary sector employment. Women workers prefer tertiary sector employment as this sector is more conducive to the absorption of female labour entering the job market. The relationship between workforce participation rate and tertiary sector employment share has been subjected to much debate and discussion. Fuchs (1980) and Grubel (1987) argue that with rising female labour force participation the demand for personal services grows as employed women spend a higher proportion of their income on services which they themselves would have rendered within the household had they not been employed. We also see that with certain demographic changes, like population aging, the purchase of personal services shows an increasing tendency (Silner 1987). 23 | P a g e All this tends to suggest that different components of the tertiary sector draw their growth stimuli from different sets of factors, and it would be quite inappropriate to merge all these components in one single category. Elfring (1989) studied in detail the service sector employment in seven OECD countries under four board categories – The producer services (Activities whose output is purchased mainly by enterprises and which are intermediate or auxiliary to the production process in other activities). The distributive services (those services which involve the distribution of commodities, information and transportation of persons) The personal services (which cover hotels, bars and restaurants, recreation and amusements, and domestic services, repair services, barber and beauty services, laundry and cleaning services and miscellaneous personal services) The social services (provided mainly by government, non-profit organizations, private businesses and professions) The role of diminishing returns has assumed a central position in this debate. It is quite natural that some effort would be spent on studying the convergence problem of states within India. In this array of research studies, a subject, which has dominated the concerned literature and which cannot be addressed without employing the data set out in the present data base, relates to inter-state disparities in income growth and to the logical question as to whether there has occurred inter-regional convergence in income growth and whether income differentials have narrowed. The studies which have addressed this question broadly fall under two categories, that is First, those that have found that there was a marked reduction in income differentials or that they have seen a noticeable tendency for convergence of long term SDP growth rates. Examples are Gupta (1973) Dholakia (1994) Cashin and Sahay (1996) and Sarkar (1996). Second, those that have noticed a widening of regional disparities amongst the states or that have depicted a picture of inter-state divergence. Examples are Nair (1971), Chaudhury (1974), Majumdar and Kapoor (1980), Bajpai and Sachs (1996) Rao, Shand and Kalirajan (1999) Dasgupta, Maiti, Mukherjee, Sarkar and 24 | P a g e Chakrabarti (2000) Sachs, Bajpai and Ramiah (2002) and Nayyar (2008). It must be clarified here that the results of these studies may have been period specific. They provide an empirical analysis of conditional convergence across Indian states and assess the extent to which differences in core social and economic infrastructure developments gives rise to differences in steady state levels of output. Nair’s (1983) pioneering analysis covered 14 major states. He had put together data on SDP for the years 1950-51, 1955-56, 1960-61 to 1975-76 from different official and unofficial sources. The study showed that inter-state disparities in per capita NSDP, as measured by the coefficient of variation (CV) had declined over the period 1950-51 to 1964-65, but increased between 1964-65 and 1976-77. The CV was about 24 per cent in 1950-51, 18 per cent in 1964-65 and 28 percent in 1976-77. Punjab (including Haryana), Gujarat and West Bengal were the high income states in 1950-51, 1960-65 and 1971-76. Bihar, Odisha and Uttar Pradesh were at the bottom of the income scale. Roychoudhury (1993) reported that the CV of per capita in NSDP in current prices had increased between 1967-68 and 1977-78 but declined between 1977-78 and 1985-86. However, the CV in terms of constant price data showed a persistent increase during the entire period 1967-68 to 1985-86. Sarkar (1994) studies the link between regional imbalances and plan outlays. He discovers a strong link between development (measured in terms of 14 variables including per capita consumption of electricity, percentage of villages electrified, per capita expenditure on health effective literacy rates, etc) and the per capita plan outlays for the different states. He employs principal component analysis to construct a composite index of development according to which Punjab scores the highest and Bihar the lowest. The analysis is based on a study of 15 Indian states. Dholakia (1994) concludes in terms of a study of 20 Indian states over the period 1960-61 to 1989-90 that there are marked tendencies of convergence of long-term economic growth rates for the states. He identifies 1980-81 to be the year of break in the 25 | P a g e trend of real incomes of Indian states. Several of the lagging states started growing after this date while the leaders began to stagnate. Cashin and Sahay (1996) have taken into account the sectoral composition of the 20 states, and found about 1.5 percent of the gap between real per capita incomes in rich and poor states was closed each year during 1961-91. That is it would take about 45 years to close half the gap between any state’s initial per capita income and the states common long run level of per capita income. However, in an industrial country it would take only about 35 years. The author also found that over 1961-91 there was a widening of the dispersion of real per capita Net State Domestic Product (NSDP) for the Indian states. Marjit and Mitra (1996) raise an interesting theoretical question also in the presence of factor mobility (as should be the case between Indian states). They wonder how far the predictions of the convergence hypothesis are valid. With perfect factor mobility, technologically similar regions must instantaneously achieve equality of per capita incomes, thus removing any possibility of differential growth rates. Thus, the absence of imperfect factor mobility is a necessary condition for the convergence theory to hold. Alternatively, in the presence of factor mobility, differential growth rates across regions do not imply convergence on account of diminishing returns. Even if a negative relationship between initial per capita income and the overall growth rate is observed it may not indicate convergence. The theoretical literature on regional inequality is based on the assumptions that may not be equally relevant for all sectors of the economy. Different sectors may contribute very differently to changes in regional inequality. There are a few studies that have looked at the contribution of different sectors in the context of changing regional inequality in India. Das and Barua (1996) find that for the period from the 1970s to early 1990s agriculture and services are the crucial sectors that contributed significantly to higher regional inequality. It may be noted that the literature on regional inequality in India is completely by the neoclassical growth frame work and accordingly, test for absolute or conditional convergence of regions over time. They examined several dimensions of 26 | P a g e regional economic disparities among 23 states/Union territories during the period 197092. Theile’s entropy measure of inequality was computed for economy wide NSDP and NSDP in different sectors for each of the years 1970 to 1992. It was found that inter-state inequality increased in almost all sectors. Krugman and Livas Elizondo (1996) find an increasing regional disparity throughout the 1980s and a decreasing disparity during the 1990s. Nagaraj et al (1997) consider the growth performance of Indian states during the 1960-94 period and find evidence of conditional convergence i.e. convergence relative to state specific steady states, They also assess the contribution of various indicators of physical, economic and social infrastructures to growth trends. They show that the coefficient of variation of per capita SDP had tended to fall in the 1960s, attributed largely to the impact of green revolution, especially in rural India. However, in the following decades the regional disparity shot up more sharply in the 1970s less markedly during the 1980s and continuing to grow during the first half of the 1990s. Ghosh, Marjit and Neogi (1998) used the data for 26 states for 35 years, 1960-61 to 1994-95 to test the hypothesis of absolute convergence and found strong evidence for divergence. The coefficient of variation of per capita SDP declined mildly during 196162 to 1981-82 from 33.9% to 31.8%. The CV increased steadily after 1981-82 reaching the value of 43.4% 1993-94. The study used the Consumer Price Index Number for Agricultural labourers available for 15 states for deflating the nominal net SDP figures to obtain the real SDP figures. This was an improvement over studies which used some allIndia level deflator. Rao, Shand and Kalirajan (1999) examining the period 1965-95 found that SDPs for the 14 major states (excluding Goa and all the special category states) were diverging (using standard growth regressions for conditional convergence) even when one controlled for differences in initial conditions. This study focused its attention not only on the question of convergence but also tried to examine the reasons for the observed pattern. They found the states to follow divergent growth paths, which they try to explain in terms of other variables besides the initial level of income. They emphasized the role 27 | P a g e of private investment flows in explaining this patters of regional inequality. However a closer look indicates that aggregate inequality did not increase much during the 1980s, whereas there is a definite rise during the initial years of the 1990s. They suggest that primary sector was largely responsible for the rise in regional disparity from mid 1960s until 1990. However, the standard deviation in secondary sector was stable during the same period, suggesting the stabilizing role of secondary sector in aggregate inequality. Further, they point out that from the early 1990s to mid 1990s, the primary sector had a limited role in the growing inequality in the economy, but the secondary sector played a significant role. As far as the tertiary sector is concerned, there is no consistent trend in accentuating or offsetting regional divergence. Dasgupta et al (2000) have studied the period from 1970 to 1995 and concluded that it is primarily the agricultural sector, and to a certain extent the manufacturing sector, that had important roles to play in the regional divergence over this period while the tertiary sector had a stabilizing influence, with regional inequality decreasing in this sector. He used the per capita SDP data up to 1995-96, and found a clear tendency for the Indian states to have diverged during the period in question as far as per capita SDP goes. In terms of sector-wise composition of SDP they diverged a tendency for overall convergence towards the national average. Dasgupta compared for each state four estimates of the growth rate over the period 1970-71 to 1995-96. The arithmetic mean, the geometric mean, the median of year-to-year growth rates and the trend exponential growth rate. There were considerable differences among the four estimates, though the ranking of the states in terms of the alternative estimates was not much different. The arithmetic mean of year-to-year growth rate and the trend exponential growth rate were found to be close to each other. Convergence was analysed with respect to aggregate SDP, SDP in agriculture, manufacturing, service sector and infrastructure sector. Convergence was found only in the service and in the infrastructure sectors. There was evidence of absolute divergence. No test of Conditional Convergence was reported. 28 | P a g e Subramanayan and Rao (2000) examined data on per capita net state domestic product of major 17 states for the period of 1965-66 to 1996-97 to test the premises that neo-classical theory of growth predicts convergence of per capita incomes across the region in the face of equal accessibility to technology and identical saving rate in the Indian context. They also tried to find out whether agriculture led growth is more equitable or industry led growth. However, there was no evidence of convergence of per capita income across Indian states in either period. Karnik et al (2000) examined the role of institutional and political factors in the economic performance of Indian states. A Gallup organisation’s opinion poll of CEOs of about 100 companies, covering the years 1995, 1997 and 1999 constituted the data base for the analysis. This data set is similar to that employed by Knack and Keefer (1995) in their cross-country study on institutions and economic performance. The poll asked respondents to rank 27 Indian states on the basis of their perceptions regarding infrastructural, institutional and political conditions in the states in order to explain the attractiveness of these states as investment destinations N.J. Kurian (2000) attempted a comparative analysis of 15 major states in respect of a variety of indicators bearing on social and economic development. He classified the states into two groups, “Forward” group consisting of Andhra Pradesh, Gujarat, Haryana, Karnataka, Kerala, Maharashtra, Punjab and Tamil Nadu, while the “Backward” group consists of Assam, Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, Odisha, Rajasthan, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. In some parts of his analysis he compared the indictors for the two groups of states. Kurian taking a holistic view of development drew attention to inter-state disparities by presenting recent data for states on demographic characteristics social characteristics, magnitude and structure of SDP, poverty ratio, developmental and nondevelopmental revenue expenditures, Eight Plan outlay and its sectoral distribution, disbursal of financial assistance for investment, indicators of physical infrastructure development and indicators of financial infrastructure. The paper pointed out that a sharp dictionary between the forward and backward groups of states had emerged. 29 | P a g e Mathur (2001) in continuation of his earlier works analysed several facets of national and regional economic growth since 1950s but with a specific focus on the 1980s and 1990s. The study reported a steep acceleration in the coefficient of variation of per capita incomes in the post-reform period of 1991-96. A tendency towards convergence was noticed within the group of middle income states, while divergence was evident within the groups of high and low income states. Shand and Bhide (2000) analyse the sources of economic growth in 15 major states over the period 1970-71 to 1995-96. The paper presents useful data in a comparative frame work for each state on sectoral distribution of NSDP. By way of analyzing the determinants of growth, the authors present rank correlation coefficient between NSDP growth rate and alternative measures of size of state life expectancy and literacy, relative sizes of sectors and banking infrastructure and social expenditures. The study suggests that agricultural growth has positive impacts on industrial growth and service sector growth. Agricultural growth is affected positively by land productivity in agriculture and negatively by the share of agriculture. Reform in the agriculture sector will yield very beneficial results as growth in this sector is found to have a positive and significant impact on overall growth. In a related study, Bhide and Shand (2000) bring out the stark differentiation between “progressive” and “backward” states. Good performers achieved high growth in all three sectors of agriculture, industry and services. Poor performers such as Odisha and Assam fared badly in all the three sectors. Infrastructure appears to be negatively related to the size of public administration. Aiyar (2001) in a recent study followed the panel data regression approach with data for a sample of 19 states over the period 1971-96 and used the Least Squares with Dummy Variable (LSDV) method of estimation. He maintained a clear distraction between absolute and conditional convergence and estimated the corresponding models. The dependent variable in each model was the growth rate over a five year period. Literacy rate (LIT) and private capital investment (PVK) the latter proxied by the amount of bank credit per capita were the explanatory variables. The assumption was that 30 | P a g e these variables had a bearing on the state’s growth rate. The results of the study provide strong evidence for absolute divergence and conditional convergence. Two regressions were computed. For regression 1 which assumed a common steady state, the estimated convergence rate was -0.013, implying absolute divergence at the rate of 1.3 per cent over a five year period. For regression 2 which included LIT and PVK and fixed effects for the 19 states, the estimated convergence coefficient was very high at 0.199. The estimated partial elasticity’s with respect to LIT and PVK were statistically significant with values equal to 0.76 and 0.15 implying strong effects of the conditioning variables on growth of per capita SDP. The results are interesting. But they are subject to the serious limitations of the use of high frequency panel data in the context of analysis of growth determinants highlighted by Pritchett (2000). Paluzie (2001) predicted a decreasing regional disparity in the first decade and increasing regional disparities in the next one. Most of these studies cover the period until mid 1990s although a few recent studies cover the entire 1990s a decade that is useful in understanding the effect that the reforms has had on regional disparity. Ahluwalia (2001) did a very influential study in which he used population weighted Gini coefficients for the 14 major states. It showed a substantial increase from 0.175 in 1991-92 to .233 in 1998-99 in real per capita GSDP. It has a distinctly different interpretation of the statistical result of its own as well as those of others. In reviewing the existing studies, Ahluwalia finds that those studies have dealt with long-term trends and the general conclusion "seems to be that there is no evidence of conditional convergence". This is, after allowance is made for differences across states in some of the initial conditions that affect growth rates, such as share of agriculture and some measure of infrastructure development, the long term time paths of per capita GSDP across states show convergence. He argues that conditional convergence is of course quite consistent with divergence in per capita GSDP over certain periods. Explaining that his paper was not concerned with convergence in the sense of underlying long-term trends but rather with the actual behaviour of per capita GSDP in the post-reform period compared with prereform behaviour, Ahluwalia argues that though inter-state inequality as measured by 31 | P a g e Gini coefficient clearly increased, the common perception that "the rich states got richer and the poor states go poorer" was misleading. Punjab and Haryana, which were the richest states, have not only faced slower per capita GSDP growth in the 1990s than in the 1980s, but have also lagged behind the national average. Except for Bihar, Uttar Pradesh and Odisha, which have grown even more slowly, all other states, have narrowed the distance between themselves and Punjab and Haryana. Apart from Maharashtra and Gujarat, the other two high-income states, which have experienced the fastest rates of growth in per capita GSDP, Rajasthan and Madhya Pradesh, have broken ranks from BIMARU states and performed reasonably well. Ahluwalia finds that the states, which have achieved strong growth in GSDP in the 1990s, are fairly well-distributed regionally : Gujarat and Maharashtra in the west, Madhya Pradesh and Rajasthan in the North, West Bengal in the East and Tamil Nadu, Karnataka and Kerala in the South. Ahluwalia also questioned the role of geography like coastal locations as determining growth performance. Jeffrey Sachs, et al (2002) have been canvassing the role of geography like coastal locations as determining growth performance. According to them the most suitable sites for sustained manufacturing growth in India as in China are along the coast, while hightech services or financial services are much less dependent on coastal locations. Madhya Pradesh and Rajasthan are both heartland states but have performed reasonably well, better than Odisha, which is a coastal state. The southern states as a group have done well, though they are by no means the only ones to achieve acceleration in growth during the 1990s. Others argue that the manufacturing sector rather than the agriculture sector is a more consistent engine of growth and it is likely to play a growing role in a liberalized economy. Urbanisation is likely to be a key determinant of growth. A 10 percentage point higher rate of urbanization is associated with 1.3 percentage points a year higher annual growth. Sachs et al note that these are major differences across Indian states in the area of policy reform Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu, Gujarat, Karnataka and Andhra Pradesh have 32 | P a g e been more reform-oriented, Haryana, Kerala, Odisha, Madhya Pradesh, Punjab, Rajasthan and West Bengal are somewhat behind in undertaking policy reform. Bihar and Uttar Pradesh are far behind. With the exception of Andhra Pradesh the reform oriented states are also the fastest growing states in the post-reform period. Dholakia,(2002) a veteran in productivity analysis, showed that TFP accounted for about 22% of GDP growth during the pre-liberalisation period 1960-85 and for about 48% during the liberalization period 1985-2000. The two sets of estimates, which of course need to be reconciled, highlight the importance of TFP in Indian economic growth. Singh and Srinivasan (2002), looking at the period 1990-91 to 1998-99 however found that the evidence does not permit one to reach very definite conclusions on convergence or divergence across the (14 major) states. As in other studies, they found that private investment (measured by per capita bank credit) matters for growth. They also found that credit-deposit ratios and FDI approvals per capita have positive impacts on growth. In contrast consistent with the finding of Ahluwalia, the broad infrastructure index constructed by the Centre for Monitoring the Indian Economy (CMIE) which includes 13 variables measuring aspect of physical, social and financial infrastructure, has no significant impact on growth. Singh and Srinivasan also suggest that the Human Development Index (HDI) constructed in the NHDR does not show any increase in across state variation (again, this is for the 14 major states), as measured by the un-weighted standard deviation. Since the average HDI has risen in the 1990s, the coefficient of variation has fallen. These numbers are consistent with the conclusion that interstate disparities in well-being have not worsened in the 1990s. Nagaraj (2002) examines the effect of economic reform on output, investment and employment, singled out the distribution of NSDP originating in the manufacturing sector across states, because economic reforms in India essentially focused on the manufacturing sector. His analysis shows no statistically significant improvement in the growth performance of states that have initiated market oriented policies. On the other 33 | P a g e hand, four states namely, Bihar, Haryana, Punjab and Uttar Pradesh have experienced statistically significant slowdown in their manufacturing growth rates after the reforms, thus implying growing inequality in the pattern of manufacturing growth, though this in turn may "imply a greater efficiency as the production decisions are increasing driven by private profitability considerations" Shetty (2003) too observes that regional disparity did increase, whether measured at 1980-81 prices or 1993-94 prices for the period from 1980-81 to 2000-01 conventionally, scholars working on state domestic product (SDP) data have restricted their analysis on only major Indian states in view of data limitation associated with smaller states and union territories in India. Breaking from this trend Shetty calculates the regional inequality based on all states and union territories of India and finds that the disparity is much higher compared to that which is based on major states only. The estimated Gini coefficients from both Ahluwalia and Shetty show that during the 1980's regional inequality remained stable till about 1986-87 and started increasing slowly thereafter, but not as fast as in the 1990's. Sivasubramonian (2004) undertook a very careful analysis of the sources of growth in the Indian economy during the period 1950-2000 and showed that TFP accounted for 32 per cent of GDP growth. The relative importance of TFP varied over time; TFP’s contribution was highest (43%) during 1950-64 and lest (13%) during 196580 and relatively moderate (35%) during 1980-2000. Bhattacharya and Sakthivel (2004) reveal that disparities in per capita GSDP has accentuated in the 1990's compared to the 1980's. The coefficient of variation of per capita GSDP which was 0.22 per cent per annum in the 1980's doubled to 0.43 percent per annum during the 1990's. Burgess and Venables (2004) and Foster and Rosenzweig (2004) showed that agricultural productivity plays a comparatively small role in explaining the inter-state variations in total, urban and even rural poverty. Further, at the levels of states, agricultural growth and overall growth are negatively correlated. 34 | P a g e Rodrik and Subramaniam (2004) observed, based on state level data for the period 1960 to 2000, that there was an upward trend in the average income as well as a wider spread in the distribution of incomes. They confirmed the wider spread and observed that the convergence coefficient was positive and insignificant during the 1960s and 1970s for the subsequent decades, i.e., 1980s and 1990s the coefficient increased and was statistically significant, suggesting that in the later two decades, states are diverging, at an annual rate of 1.2%. They further observed 'divergence big time', with peninsular India growing more rapidly than the hinterland BIMARU states. In the future, they pointed out that this trend could widen as existing advantages are reinforced by new technologies. Virmani, Arvind (2008) examined the role of agriculture growth and the growth in fast moving modern sectors like, registered manufacturing, communication, trade, hotels and restaurants, on the growth of domestic product of states in India and their inter-state differences, based on data for the period 1993-94 to 2004-05. He also investigated, as to what extent do interstate differences in average per capita income of states explain interstate differences in poverty rates as measured by official poverty data. He has observed that the cross-state Gini coefficient of per capita GDP (based on 16 states) distribution weighted by population has increased from 0.60 to 0.63 between 1993-94 and 2004-05. However, the degree of variation in SDP growth rates has declined marginally when the total period is divided into two sub-periods, 1993-94 to 1999-2000 and 2000-01to 2004-05. Importantly, Virmani has observed that the most critical areas distinguishing state growth performance have been modern manufacturing, communication, trade, hotels and restaurants sectors. Analyzing the determinants of poverty across states, he has observed that the consumption share of bottom 40% of the population is an important determinant, besides other factors like per capita state GDP, growth in state per capita GDP from agriculture and per capita state GDP from nonagriculture sectors. He also observed that the Gini's coefficient of per capita GDP distribution weighted by population has marginally increased during the 1993-94 to 2004-05 period although the degree of variation in SDP growth rates has declined when the total period has been divided into two sub-periods, with a break at 1999-2000. 35 | P a g e Nayyar (2008) has sought to examine whether or not the disparate levels of income and development inhabit any tendency in the data to converge to common steadystate paths. While analyzing the data for 16 states for the period 1978-79 to 2002-03, he has observed that there was no tendency for states to converge to identical states based on both cross sectional and panel data; but in contrast, there was robust evidence of conditional convergence. Under the conditional convergence, initially poorer states do converge faster to their divergent steady states. He has observed increasing dispersion in per capita real incomes across states over time. States in India are converging to very different steady states, which may be attributable to increasing inter-state disparities in levels of private and public investment and an insignificant equalizing impact of centrestate government transfers. Kalra and Sodsriwiboon (2010) examined the convergence and skill over across the Indian states using non-stationary panel data techniques. The finding suggested the existence of divergence over the entire sample period, convergence during sub-periods corresponding to structural breaks, and club convergence. There was strong evidence of club convergence among the high and low-income states; the evidence for middle-income states was mixed Dynamic spill over effects among states were small. Agarwalla and Pangotra (2011) have tried to examine the trends in disparities across the regions in India over a period of 26 years (1980 to 2006) by employing panel data estimation method based on the neo-classical framework. Examining 25 state economies in India they found convergent trend in regional incomes, conditional upon growth rates of inputs, and technological growth rate. They have also found that during the period of 1972 to 2006 the speed of convergence has been faster, because during that period Indian economy had gone through structural reforms. Further, evidence showed that incomes of the special category states have experienced convergence at a higher rate. Bandyopadhyay (2011) used the distribution dynamics method to identify polarization of incomes across the Indian states and further examined whether there is any evidence of “neighbouring regions effect”. The author found no evidence of conditional convergence in investigating for a “neighbours effect” that explains the 36 | P a g e polarization which suggests that India being a developing country need to develop the networks across the states to generate spatial interactions. Mamoni Kalita and Aviral Kumar Tiwari (2012) attempted to test income convergence of the Indian states. For the analysis, the study utilized 27 Indian states data for the period 1980-81 to 2007-08 to test for convergence of Indian states GDP in the panel framework by using a more recently test developed by Ucar and Omay (2009) for heterogeneous panel unit root test particularly for two reasons. First, it is based on heterogeneous panel as India states are heterogeneous in nature and culture. Second, it has advancement in showing the nonlinear nature of convergence if it exists as it is ignored by existing studies. The Study found strong evidence against the convergence of the Gross State Domestic Product (GSDP) among the Indian states. There is no convergence of GSDP of the Indian states. This implies that Indian states do not follow balanced growth path that is Indian states are not growing together and there is strong mismatch in the growth path of GSDP. 37 | P a g e Chapter-III ROLE OF SERVICES SECTOR IN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT India stands out for the size and dynamism of its services sector. The contribution of services sector to the Indian economy has been manifold. Services sector share in gross domestic product (GDP) is 55.2 per cent and it is growing by 10 per cent annually, contributing to about a quarter of total employment. It also accounts for a high share in foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows and over one-third of total exports. It has recorded very fast (27.4 per cent) export growth through the first half of 2010-11. The share of services in India’s GDP at factor cost (at constant prices) increased rapidly. It increased from 38.04 per cent in 1980-81 to 57.30 per cent in 2009-10. If we also include construction, then the share increased to 64.83 per cent in 2009-10. The ratcheting up of the overall growth rate (compound annual growth rate [CAGR]) of the Indian economy from 5.7 per cent in the 1990s to 8.6 per cent during the period 2004-05 to 2009-10 was to a large measure due to the acceleration of the growth rate (CAGR) in the services sector from 7.5 per cent in the 1990s to 10.3 per cent in 2004-05 to 2009-10. The services sector growth was significantly faster than the 6.6 per cent for the combined agriculture and industry sectors annual output growth during the same period In 2009-10, services growth was 10.06 per cent and in 2010-11 it was 9.38 per cent. India’s services GDP growth has been continuously above overall GDP growth. As Figure 3.1 depicts Agricultures share in GDP has declined, while the share of industry has shown negligible change and consequently the entire subsequent decline in agriculture has been picked up by the services sector. 38 | P a g e Figure 3.1: Average Sectoral Contribution to GDP. 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% Agriculture 50% Industry services 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1980s 1990s 2000s Source: National Accounts Statistics The primary sector is the dominant employer followed by the services sector but the share of services has been increasing over the years while that of primary sector has been decreasing. There was a sharp fall in the share of the primary sector in employment from 1993-94 to 2004-05. The rise in share of employment of the other two sectors was almost equally divided between the secondary and tertiary sectors. In 2007-08 compared to 2004-05, the trend was similar, the fall in employment in primary sector was less at 1.1 per cent with a small commensurate rise in employment in the other two sectors, which was again almost equally divided between the other two sectors (Table 3.1) Shows that in 2007-08 the services sector provided employment of one fourth of the total employment where as secondary sector provided only 18.7 percent of the total employment. Primary sector still remains the largest employment provider with 55.9 percent of labour force employed by the sector. 39 | P a g e Table 3.1: Share of Broad Sectors in Employment (UPSS) Shares in % Change in Shares in % Sectors 1993-94 2004-05 2007-08 2004-05 2007-08 2007-08 over over over 1993-94 2004-05 1993-94 Primary 64.5 57.0 55.9 -7.5 -1.1 -8.6 Secondary 14.3 18.2 18.7 3.9 0.5 4.4 Tertiary 21.2 24.8 25.4 3.6 0.6 4.2 Source: Economic Survey 2010-11. Since 1990s there has been an increase in share of services in inward FDI and outward FDI. Study by Sen (2011) shows that there is a significant positive impact of FDI on services sector and the service sector growth has in turn a significant growth on GDP. Financial and non financial services (21%) computer hardware and software (8%) telecommunications (8%) housing and real state (7%) have attracted largest share of FDI equity inflows. The share of these four sectors combined namely financial and non financial services computer hardware and software, telecommunications, housing and real estate, predominantly consisting of services, in FDI equity inflows in April 2000December 2010 is around 44 percent. If we include construction then the share rises to 51 per cent. The financial and non-financial services sector which falls purely in the services category is the largest recipient of FDI equity inflows with a 21 per cent share. (RBI bulletin 2010) 40 | P a g e Figure 3.2: Annual Growth Rate of GDP and Services Sector GDP 12 10 8 6 Overall GDP Services GDP 4 2 0 Source: National Income Statistics. Centre for Monitoring Indian Economy The services sector growth rate has always been aove overall GDP growth rate since 1981-82 except for the years 1983-84, 1988-89,1990-91,1994-95,1996-97 and 2003-04 when the two converged. Thus for the last 30 years, this sector with with much growth above overall GDP growth of the economy has been pushing up the growth of the economy with a great amount of stability (Figure 3.2) A comparison of the share of services in the gross state domestic product (GSDP) of different states and union territories (UTs) in 2009-10 shows that the services sector is the dominant sector in most states of India. States and UTs such as Kerala, Maharashtra, Bihar, Tamil Nadu, West Bengal, Tripura, Nagaland, Mizoram and Delhi have shares equal to or above the all-India share. State-wise growth of GSDP is also closely associated with faster growth of the tertiary sector. Interestingly, Bihar with 16.6 percent Growth which has the highest overall growth rate in 2008-09 also has the fastest growth among States in services, in part due to its rapid progress from a low base (only Goa with 20.1 percent growth rate in services is higher than that of Bihar, but this is for 2007-08). Even relatively low-income States such 41 | P a g e as Odisha and Rajasthan which have relatively low overall growth rates have started piggy-backing on the good performance of their services sectors to climb up the ladder of progress. Delhi with 81.8 percent tops the list. Other than Chattisgarh (34.8 percent) and Himachal Pradesh (39.6 percent) services in all other states individually hold a share of more than 40 percent in the GSDP. The highest growth rates of the services sector are in the North Eastern states of Arunachal Pradesh (34.9 percent) and Sikkim (30.1 percent). Other states with higher than national average growth in the sector are Kerala, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra and Mizoram. Thus, the services revolution in India seems to be becoming broader based rather than being concentrated in only a few States. Some services have been particularly important for this improving performance in India. Software is one sector in which India has achieved a remarkable global brand identity. Tourism and travel related services and transport services are also major items in India’s services. Besides these, the potential and growing services include many professional services, infrastructure-related services, and financial services. The contribution to GDP and growth pattern of disaggregated services has shown a fluctuating pattern. Table no. 3.2 depicts that business services, communication, banking and hotels and restaurants have shown a consistent rise in growth rate and contribution to the GDP. There was a decline in the growth rate of insurance, public administration & defence, legal services, real estate, personal services and storage from 1980s to 1990s. Their contribution to GDP in this time period has not shown a significant change except for real estate and railways. Growth of services in India has been broad based, although it has been usually rapid in modern services like communications, business services and services that are tradable internationally. Trade in software services and banking services should be given an impetus as they have a higher contribution to GDP, rising domestic demand, higher growth rates and boost productivity of the manufacturing sector, thereby leading to a sectorally linked productivity spiral. Education and health care should be regulated to meet domestic demand. 42 | P a g e Table 3.2: Average Annual Growth Rate and GDP Shares of Services Sub-Sectors. (%) 1980s 1990s 2000s Service Sub –Sector Growth GDP Growth GDP Rate Share Rate Share Rate Share Trade, Hotels & Restaurants 5.93 11.81 7.48 3.03 8.49 15.9 Transport, Storage & Communication 6.03 6.23 7.49 6.86 12.86 8.94 8.67 8.92 8.05 1.99 9.38 4.92 5.9 13.37 6.46 3.86 6.62 3.79 6.53 40.33 7.28 45.7 8.95 53.6 Financing Insurance, Real Estate & Business Services Community, Social and Personal Services Total Services Growth GDP Source: Computed from National Income Statistics, Centre for Monitoring Indian Economy July 2011. The contribution to GDP and growth pattern of service sub – sectors has shown a fluctuating pattern. Trade, Hotels and Restaurants and Transport, Storage & Communication have shown a consistent rise in growth rate. There was a decline in the growth rate of Financing, Insurance & Real Estate from 1980s to 1990s. The contribution of Community, Social and Personal Services to GDP in this time period has not shown a significant change Table 3.2 and Figure 3.3 and Figure 3.4 depicts that the share of Trade, Hotels & Restaurant in GDP increased from 11.81 percent in 1980s to 13.03 percent in 1990s and further to 15.9 percent in 2000s where as the growth rate increased from 5.93 percent in 1980s to 7.48 percent in 1990s and further to 8.49 percent in 2000s. 43 | P a g e The contribution of Transport Storage & Communication to GDP increased from 6.23 percent in 1980s to 6.86 percent in 1990s and rose at 8.94 percent in 2000s and the growth rate also increased from 6.03 percent in 1980s and 7.49 percent in 1990s and jumped to 12.86 percent in 2000s. Financing, Insurance, Real Estate and Business Services contribution to GDP increased consistently from 8.92 percent in 1980s to 11.99 percent in 1990s to 14.92 percent in 2000s whereas the growth rate has decreased from 8.67 percent in 1980s to 8.05 percent in1990s and then rose to 9.38 percent in 2000s. Community, Social and Personal Services growth rate has increased from 5.9 percent in 1980s to 6.46 percent in 1990s and then rose marginally to 6.62 percent in 2000s. Whereas, the contribution to GDP remained almost constant. CSO’s classification of the services sector falls under four broad categories:1. Trade, Hotels, and Restaurants. 2. Transport, Storage, and Communication. 3. Financing, Insurance, Real Estate, and Business Services. 4. Community, Social, and Personal Services. Among these, Financing, Insurance, Real Estate, and Business Services; and Trade, Hotels and Restaurants are the largest groups accounting for 17.17 per cent and 16.39 percent respectively of the national GDP in 2009-10. The Community Social and Personal Services category accounts for a 13.57 per cent share while Transport, Storage, and Communication accounts for 10.16 percent share of the National GDP in 2009-10. It becomes important to ensure that the services that contribute relatively more to growth are placed on a higher productivity trajectory in order to maintain the growthenhancing role of the services sector. On the basis of our analysis the services identified as a priority are software services, domestic trade (retail/wholesale distributive services), and financial services. A roadmap of specific policies needs to be drawn for services, not only to support their growth during periods of crisis, but also for accelerating their growth rate in the future. These sectors have shown a remarkable resilience despite relatively less support compared to other sectors. 44 | P a g e Figure: 3.3: Average Annual Growth Rate of Services Sub-Sectors. (%) 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1980s 1990s 2000s Figure 3.4: GDP Shares of Services Sub-Sectors. (%) 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1980s 1990s 2000s 45 | P a g e The term distributive trade refers to wholesale trade and retail trade that can be defined as an act of purchase of goods and their disposal by way of sale without any intermediate physical transformation of goods. This includes commission agents, commodity brokers and auctioneers, and all other wholesalers who trade on their own behalf and on the account of others. Retail trade covers units that mainly resell without transformation new and used goods for personal or household consumption. This sector covers a wide range of economic activities. Besides the sectors of trade, hotel and restaurant, transport, storage, communication, real estate and ownership of dwellings, banking, and public administration, it also covers the sectors of business services and ‘other services’. Business services include business accounting, software development and data processing, business and management consultancy, advertisement, and other business services. The sector ‘other services’ comprises education, research & scientific services, medical and health services including veterinary services, sanitary services, religious, community services, recreation and entertainment services, personal services like domestic, laundry, dyeing and dry cleaning, barbers and beauty shops. Distributive trade is a very important sector for India with a potential to provide employment to a large proportion of the population and significantly contribute to the GDP. In India 98% of trading activities are carried out in the unorganized segment of the economy. A significant impediment in policy formulation in this sector is that the statistics of this segment have not been adequately developed and are lacking in quality, comparability, and timeliness. There is no regular flow of data either from official sources or through annual surveys. As a result, estimates vary widely about the true size of retail business in India. According to Central Statistics Office estimates, total domestic trade, both wholesale and retail, constituted about 15.1% of India’s GDP in 2006-07, an increase from 13% of the GDP in 1999-00. In 2004-05 CSO report employment in the retail trade was around 35.06 million, which constituted about 7.3% of the workforce (459 million). The corresponding retail employment was about 30.62 million in 1999-00, which means 46 | P a g e that an additional 4.44 million jobs were added to this sector in the five-year period, 2000-05, showing an annual employment growth of 2.7% per annum. Wholesale trade, on the other hand, contributed 5.48 million jobs. Indian retail is dominated by a large number of small retailers consisting of the local kirana shops, which together make up the so-called “unorganized retail” or traditional retail, with a gradually rising organized retail sector. The total number of organized retail outlets rose from 3,125 in 2001 (covering an area of 3.3 million sq. ft.) to 27,076 in 2006 (covering an area of 31 million sq. ft.). The impact of the global crisis on the retail/wholesale trade sector has been low. In 2007-08, the sector’s contribution to GDP growth increased 1.42 percentage points, compared to an increase of 1.40 percentage points in 2006-07. This was in spite of a slight decline in the overall contribution of the services sector to GDP growth from 6.9 percentage points in 2006-07 to 6.7 percentage points in 2007-08. The retail sector in India has steadily growing domestic demand, which is explained by a rapidly expanding middle class, sustained high economic growth during the last few years causing a rapid rise in disposable incomes, favourable demographics placing incomes on younger population with less dependency, and growing urbanization. Indian retail sales were about US$322 billion in 2006-07 (National Council of Applied Economic Research, Market Information Survey of Households), which amounted to about 35% of India’s GDP. India is now the seventh largest retail market in the world. The Indian retail industry is projected to grow to about US$590 billion by 2011-12 and is then to grow to over US$1 trillion by 2016-17. This implies there is huge growth potential in the country’s retail sector. Trade is an important segment in India’s GDP. The GDP from trade (inclusive of wholesale and retail in the organized and unorganized sectors) at constant prices increased from Rs. 4,33,967 crore in 2004-05 to Rs.6,71,396 crore in 2009-10, at a CAGR of 9.1 per cent. The share of trade in the GDP remained fairly stable at around 15 per cent in the last four years. The last decade has witnessed acceleration in the growth rate of real GDP. It has been in the range of 8-9 per cent during the last five years. This fast growth means rising 47 | P a g e disposable income of the population, in particular that of the middle class. With the growth in consuming population, the retail business also got a boost. There are no official estimates of the size of retail trade in the country, though some estimates have been made by some institutions. On the basis of an NSSO Survey, the International Council for Research on International Economic Relations (ICRIER) study of 2008 places employment in the retail trade at 35.06 million, which constitutes 7.3 per cent of the workforce in the country. On the basis of employment intensity in retail trading, the contribution of the retail sector in the GDP is estimated in the range of 10 to12 per cent. A large number of small and decentralized traders dominate the Indian retail scene. One estimate puts their number at 1.3 crores. The organized corporate sector has started showing interest in the retail business. Due to fast growth in the GDP and rising disposable income of the consuming classes, the modern format of retailing (i.e. organized retailing) is attracting domestic and foreign investment. Tourism is another major engine of economic growth in most parts of the world including India. Tourism does not fall under a single heading in the National Accounts Statistics, so its contribution has to be estimated. In 2007-08, the contribution of tourism to the country’s GDP, and to total jobs (direct and indirect) in the country was estimated at 5.92 per cent, and 9.24 per cent respectively. In absolute numbers, the total number of tourism jobs in the country increased from 38.6 million in 2002-03 to 49.8 million in 2007-08. According to the UN World Tourism Organization, tourism provides 6 per cent to 7 per cent of the world’s total jobs directly and millions more indirectly through the multiplier effect in this sector. (Economic Survey 2010-11) Tourism also plays an important role in the country’s foreign exchange earnings, as its share in India’s export of services accounted for 13 per cent of the total export of services in 2009-10. In India, the tourism sector witnessed significant growth in recent years. During the period 2004 to 2009, the CAGRs of foreign tourist arrivals and foreign exchange earnings from tourism in rupee terms were 8.1 per cent, and 14.5 per cent respectively. Foreign tourist arrivals in India, which were at 5.28 million in 2008, fell to 48 | P a g e 5.11 million 2009 due to the global crisis. These arrivals, which registered negative or low growth rates in the first eleven months of 2009, started recovering from December 2009 with a good growth of 21 per cent. In the year 2010, the recovery continued with foreign tourist arrivals at 5.58 million registering a growth of 9.3 per cent. The foreign exchange earnings from tourism in the year 2010 witnessed a growth of 18.1 per cent over the previous year in rupee terms compared to the decline of 3.3 per cent in 2009. Domestic tourism also plays an important role in overall tourism development in the country. The number of domestic tourist visits increased to 650 million in 2009 as compared to 562.98 million in 2008, witnessing a growth of 15.5 per cent in spite of various adverse factors during this period. The hotels and restaurants sector is an important sub-component of the tourism sector. Availability of good quality and affordable hotel rooms plays an important role in boosting the growth of tourism in the country. Presently there are 1593 classified hotels with a capacity of 95,087 rooms in the country. The hotels sector comprises various forms of accommodation, namely star category hotels, heritage category hotels, timeshare resorts, apartment hotels, guest houses, and bed and breakfast establishments. The share of the hotels and restaurant sector in the overall economy increased from 1.46 per cent in 2004-05 to 1.69 per cent in 2007-08, and then decreased to 1.53 per cent and 1.45 percent in 2008-09 and 2009-10 respectively. The CAGR in the GDP contributed by the hotels and restaurants sector was 8.5 per cent in 2004-05 to 2009-10. There was, however, negative growth (-3.41 percent) in 2008-09 over the year 2007-08, which was due to the adverse global economic conditions in this year, while in 2009-10, the sector registered a growth of 2.2 per cent. Several studies have identified the demand-supply gap in hotel rooms in India; some of them have estimated a gap of 150,000 hotel rooms, of which 100,000 rooms are in the budget segment. Since the construction of hotels is primarily a private-sector activity and is capital intensive with a long gestation period, the Government is making efforts to stimulate investments in this sector and speed up the approval process. Various financial and fiscal incentives have been announced by the Government for the hospitality sector including a five-year tax holiday under the Income Tax Act for two, three, and four star 49 | P a g e category hotels located in all United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) World Heritage sites (except Mumbai and Delhi) for hotels starting operations from 1 April 2008 to 31 March 2013. Government also announced a five-year tax holiday in 2007-08 for two, three, and four star category new hotels and convention centres coming up between 1 April 2007 and 31 July 2010 in the National Capital Territory of Delhi and some neighbouring districts of the National Capital Region. Other incentives for hotels include: Relaxation of external commercial borrowings (ECB) to reduce the liquidity crunch being faced by the hotel industry for setting up new hotel projects. Allowing FDI up to 100 per cent under the automatic route for the hotel and tourism-related industry. Delinking of credit to hotel projects from commercial real estate by the RBI, thereby enabling hotel projects to avail of credit at relaxed norms and reduced interest rates. Investment-linked deduction under Section 35 AD of the Income Tax Act announced in the Union Budget 2010-2011 for establishing new hotels of 2- star category and above all over India. Government has allowed 100 per cent deduction in respect of the whole or any expenditure of capital nature. Government also has a voluntary scheme of granting approval to bonafide tour operators, travel agents, tourist transport operators, and adventure tour operators who satisfy certain criteria specified in terms of turnover, infrastructure and manpower. Since infrastructure development holds the key to India’s sustained growth in the tourism sector, the Government has been making efforts to develop quality tourism infrastructure at tourist destinations and circuits. Despite these efforts there is a lot more to be done given the potential of this sector.In fact at 11.5 percent, the share of Travel in India’s exports of commercial services in 2008 is relatively lower than that of many other exporters of services and half the shares of the U.S.A, E.U. and China. (Table 3.3) 50 | P a g e Table: 3.3 Composition of Commercial Services Exports of India and Other Major Services Exporters (Shares in 2008) Hong India USA EU Japan China Singapore 1.Transportation 11.0 17.5 23.0 31.9 26.2 34.8 31.4 2.Travel 11.6 26.0 22.2 07.5 27.9 12.7 16.6 3.Other 77.4 56.5 54.8 60.6 45.9 52.5 52.4 Kong commercial services Source: calculated from World Trade organization (WTO) data. The Indian shipping industry plays an important role in the economic development of the country, especially in India’s international trade. It also plays an important role in the energy security of the country, as energy resources, such as coal, crude oil and natural gas are mainly transported by ship. Approximately 95 percent of of the country’s trade by volume and 68 percent in terms of value, is being transported by sea. During crises situations Indian shipping contributes to the uninterrupted supply of essentials and can serve as second line of defence. Though India has one of the largest merchant shipping fleets among the developing countries, it was ranked eighteenth in the world in terms of dead weight tonnage (DWT) as on 1 January 2010. Leaving the ‘flags of convenience’ countries, India’s share is low at 1.17 percent, while China’s is around three times higher than India’s. (Table:3.4) The gross foreign exchange earnings/ savings of Indian ships during 2007-08 were at a record level of Rs. 14,589 crore. Net foreign exchange earnings/ savings of Indian shipping companies, after accounting for financial costs at 8952 crore were around 61 per cent of gross earnings/ savings. 51 | P a g e Table: 3.4 Share of Merchant Fleets by Flags of Registrations as on 1 January 2010 DWT(in ‘000) Share (%) Panama 2,88,758 22.63 2 Liberia 1,42,121 11.14 3 Marshall islands 77,827 6.09 4 Hong Kong 74,513 5.83 5 Greece 67,629 5.30 6 Bahamas 64,109 5.02 7 Singapore 61,660 4.83 8 Malta 56,156 4.40 9 China 45,157 3.54 10 Cyprus 31,305 2.45 11 South Korea 20,819 1.63 12 Norway 20,811 1.63 13 UK and Northern Ireland 20,176 1.58 14 Japan 17,707 1.39 15 Germany 17,50 1.38 16 Italy 17,276 1.35 17 Isle of Man 16,711 1.30 18 India 14,970 1.17 12,76,137 100 Rank Flag of Registration 1 World Total Source :UNCTAD, Review of Maritime Transport 2010. In order to facilitate growth of the Indian shipping industry and make it competitive at international level, the government has initiated several measures like: Bringing acquisition of all types of ships under open general licence; Allowing 100 per cent FDI in the shipping and port sectors cargo support to Indian shipping lines by providing for centralized shipping arrangements through the Chartering Wing (Transchart) of the Ministry of Shipping. 52 | P a g e Introducing tonnage tax system during 2004-05; formulating a Cruise Shipping Policy of India in June 2008. Establishing the Indian Maritime University in November 2008. According to the National Council of Applied Economic Research (NCAER), a 5 per cent increase in the national shipping tonnage saves or earns an additional 17 per cent of the freight bill and according to a report by The Energy and Resources Institute (TERI), a 1 per cent change in Gross Registered Tonnage (GRT) is likely to bring about a 0.0068 per cent change in the GDP. While India’s overseas seaborne trade has been growing substantially over the years from 224.62 million tonnes in 1999-2000 to 598.70 million tonnes in 2008-09 with a CAGR of 10.57 per cent during 2004-05 to 2008-09, there is a sharp decline in the share of Indian ships in the carriage of India’s overseas trade from about 40 per cent in the late 1980s to 9.5 per cent in 2008-09 with a 5.7 per cent share in India’s export trade and 12 per cent share in India’s import trade. Given the relatively low participation of Indian ships in India’s export trade and given the fact that Indian ships are ageing, with the average age of the Indian fleet increasing from 15 years in 1999 to 18.3 years in 2009, there is urgent need to increase the shipping fleet for a country of India’s size. This will lead not only to higher growth of the economy but also higher foreign exchange earnings/ savings and higher employment. Ports play a vital role in the overall economic development of the country. India has a long coastline with 13 major ports and around 200 non-major ports. Around 72 per cent of the total cargo handled by volume was through India’s major ports and the rest through non-major ports till 2008-09 but after the development of private ports the share of major ports fell to 67 per cent during 2009-10. Despite the recessionary trend and decline in exports, during the years 2008-09 and 2009-10, traffic at major ports attained a growth of 2.2 per cent and 5.74 per cent respectively over the previous year. Recent developments in the port services sector include the finalization of a model concession agreement for awarding projects on Public Private Partnership (PPP) basis in 2008 and introduction of web-based port community systems. 53 | P a g e The ranking of ports in the world in 2008 places Singapore, followed by Shanghai and Rotterdam at the top, with Madras and the Jawaharlal Nehru Port Trust (JNPT) in the 70th and 71st positions in terms of total cargo volume. In terms of container traffic also, the JNPT ranks 25th. The average turnaround time in major Indian ports was 4.38 days in the year 2009-10 and was relatively higher in some ports like Paradip, Kolkata, Vizag, and Kandla, while average output per ship berth- day was 10,168 tonnes with more than double the average in the JNPT and around one- fifth the average in Kolkata port. With the average turnaround time in India already relatively high by international standards, the turnaround time of Singapore being less than a day. A cause for worry is rise in average turnaround time and average pre-berthing time, and also fall in average output per ship-berth-day in 2009-10. (Source: Ministry of Shipping website) A lot of attention needs to be paid to our port sector. A holistic approach is needed for improving the existing infrastructure and services at ports through modernization of the systems using latest technology. The infrastructure facilities at major ports for handling of crude oil needs to be strengthened through a facilitative policy on single-point moorings. Upgrading of the facilities at existing ports with regard to cargo handling, stevedoring, pilot age services, bunker services, and warehousing facilities need to be done. Trans-shipment of Indian cargo needs to be handled at Indian ports through concerted measures. This would include increasing the draft available at Indian ports, rationalization of port dues and providing differential levels of tariff for different sizes of vessels or for different cargoes so as to attract mother ships to berth at Indian ports. The many port charges in India need to be reduced as they are higher than in many other countries due to inefficiency of ports and inclusion of unrelated costs like pension and other contributions to labour in port services. The warehousing services sector plays an important role in the economy of the country. Warehousing services are an important cog both in inbound logistics, as raw materials, parts, stores have to be stocked, inventory control maintained, materials which do not meet specifications returned to suppliers, as well as outbound logistics as the goods produced have to be stored in different geographical locations before shipping/ dispatch as per demand/ order inflows. 54 | P a g e In India, the most important component of warehousing is storage for agroproduce, food grains, fertilizers, manure, etc. Other components include industrial warehousing for industrial goods, import cargo, and excisable cargo; Inland Container Depots (ICDs)/ Container Freight Stations (CFSs) for facilitating import/export trade; and special warehouses for cold and temperature controlled storage. The warehousing sector also provides ancillary services like handling, transportation, pest control, farmer extension schemes, dedicated warehousing at doorsteps, consultancy, and project execution. Indian Government has established Central Warehousing Corporation (CWC) with the objective of providing scientific storage facilities for agricultural implements and produce and other notified commodities. 17 State Warehousing Corporations (SWCs) were also set up under the Warehousing Corporations Act 1962 for the same objective. The CWC and the respective State Governments are equal shareholders of these SWCs. The commercial outreach with social objectives has resulted in the CWC operating a large warehousing network across the country. As on 31 December 2010, the CWC was operating 476 warehouses, with a total storage capacity of 102.24 lakh MTs and an average utilization of 85 per cent. It made an entry into operation of public bonded warehouses in the late 1970s, when the Central Board of Excise and Customs, acknowledging the expertise of the CWC in the field of storage and warehousing, identified it as a custodian for dutiable goods. The CWC has also diversified its business into CFSs/ICDs and also started Container Rail Transportation from Loni (UP) to Jawaharlal Nehru Port. The expansion of the overall capacity of the CWC has been slow as it is cost intensive. The profits generated are being ploughed back to construct additional warehouses thereby strengthening the warehousing infrastructure throughout the country. At the level of the state, the 17 SWCs meet the storage requirements and complement the work of the CWC. As on 31 October 2010, these SWCs were operating a network of 1585 warehouses with an aggregate storage capacity of 214.41 lakh MT. Major policy initiatives taken recently by the Government include construction of godowns under the seven-years guarantee scheme of the Government of India, most of them being managed by the CWC or SWCs; permission of up to 100 per cent FDI in the construction of warehousing infrastructure; and construction of warehouses under the 55 | P a g e Grameen Bhandaran Yojana of NABARD and the Rastriya Krishi Vikas Yojana. In the year 2007-08, the Government enacted the Warehousing (Development & Regulation) Act 2007 to make the warehouse receipt fully negotiable. Recently the Government took another major initiative for construction of godowns under its Private Enterpreneurs Godown (PEG) scheme. The CWC has constructed 0.9 lakh MT capacity godowns during the year 2009-10 and has planned to construct additional capacity to the tune of 1.77 lakh MT during the year 2010-11. The opening of the telecom sector in India has not only led to rapid growth but also helped a great deal towards maximization of consumer benefits as tariffs have been falling across the board as a result of increasing competition, with the telecom service price index falling from 100 in 2004-05 to 85.08 in 2007-08. The telecom sector has grown from a level of 22.8 million telephone subscribers in 1999 to 54.6 million in 2003, and further to 764.77 million at the end of November 2010. Wireless telephone connections have contributed to this growth as the number of wireless connections rose from 3.57 million in March 2001 to 729.58 million by the end of November 2010. Teledensity, which was 2.32 per cent, increased to 64.34 per cent in November 2010. However, there is a wide gap between rural tele-density (30.18 per cent in November 2010) and urban tele-density (143.95 per cent in November 2010). It shows that the market still has large untapped potential. The Internet, which is another growing mode of communication, is a worldwide system of computer networks. Broadband is often called ‘high- speed’ Internet, because it usually has a high rate of data transmission. Broadband subscribers grew from 0.18 million in 2005 to 10.71 million as at the end of November 2010. The number of Internet and broadband subscribers is expected to increase to 40 million and 20 million, respectively by 2010 (Source Economic Survey 2010-11). Introduction of BWA (Broadband Wireless Access) services will enhance the penetration as well as growth of broadband subscribers. Wi-Max has also been making headway in penetration of wireless broadband connectivity across all sectors. The real estate sector includes development of commercial and residential real estates, with participation and involvement of both Government agencies and private developers. The GDP from the real estate sector (including ownership of dwellings) 56 | P a g e along with business services witnessed a growth of 7.5 per cent (at constant prices) in the year 2009-10. In terms of share, it accounted for 9.3 per cent of the GDP in the year 2009-10. Fiscal incentives for the housing sector provided in successive budgets together with liberal investment and credit policies and reforms brought the housing and real estate sector to the centre stage of the Indian economy. Policy measures include permission for FDI in townships, housing, built-up infrastructure, and construction development projects, including SEZs, under the automatic route, which has attracted foreign investors into this sector. A joint study by Price Waterhouse Coopers (PWC) and Urban Land Institute of India (ULI) has cited India as one of the emerging markets for real estate sector in the Asia Pacific Region. The study classifies India as semi-transparent market in the Asia Pacific Region, and ranks it 41st on a global transparency scoring scale. It places Mumbai (ranked 3rd), New Delhi (5th), and Bangalore (10th) among the top 10 prospective cities for real estate investment for the year 2011. Mumbai and New Delhi in that order capture the top two places in terms of city development prospects for the year 2011. In this emerging services sector, while short term worries like hardening interest rates need to be addressed, there is also need for some fundamental reforms like tackling the high stamp duty issue which makes even honest citizens deal in black money and problems related to foreclosure of loans and the Urban Land Ceiling Regulations Act (ULCRA). Indian software services comprising ITES and IT-BPO services have shown remarkable resilience to the global economic crisis. Software services grossed US$47 billion in 2008–09, growing by 17% from the previous year. This sector is a major contributor to the growth of the economy and has a multiplier effect in terms of export earnings, investments, employment, and overall economic growth. The total employment in the IT services is estimated to have reached 2.0 million in 2007-08 against 1.63 million in 2006-07, a growth of 22.7%. This represents a net addition of 375,000 professionals to the industry employee base in 2007-08. The indirect employment attributed to the sector is estimated to be about 8.0 million in 2007-08. This translates to the creation of about 10.0 million job opportunities, which can be attributed to the growth of this sector. 57 | P a g e The global economic crisis led to a fall in the growth of software services, but the growth in domestic demand cushioned the adverse effects. Domestic demand for both IT and IT-BPO services grew much faster than their exports. A double-digit growth in exports of IT-BPO (29.8%) in a time of crisis reflects the competitive edge of Indian ITBPO services over other suppliers. At present, India has over 400 delivery centres across 52 countries. This strategy of geographical diversification along with productivity growth and operational efficiency has provided a strong footing to the sector. India has gained a brand identity as a knowledge economy due to its IT and ITES sector. The IT and ITES industry has four major components: IT services. Business Process Outsourcing (BPO). Engineering Services and R&D. Software Products. The growth in the services sector in India has been led by the IT-ITES sector which has become a growth engine for the economy, contributing substantially to increases in the GDP, employment, and exports. Its contribution to India’s GDP increased from 4.1 per cent in 2004-05 to 6.1 per cent in 2009-10 and an estimated 6.4 per cent in 2010-11. The industry has also helped expand tertiary education significantly. The top seven States that account for about 90 per cent of this sector’s exports have started six to seven times more colleges than other States. The Indian IT-ITES industry has registered robust growth since 2004-05. According to NASSCOM, the year 2010-11 is characterized by broad-based growth across mature and emerging verticals. The overall Indian IT-ITES revenue has grown to US $ 63.7 billion in 2009-10 and an estimated US $ 76.1 billion in 2010-11, translating into a CAGR of 22.5 per cent from 2004-05 to 2010-11. The industry grew by an estimated 19.5 percent in 2010-11 compared to the moderate growth of 6.2 per cent in 2009-10. Exports dominate the IT-ITES industry, and constitute about 77 per cent of total industry revenue. Total IT-ITES exports have grown from US$ 17.7 billion in 2004-05 to 58 | P a g e US $ 49.7 billion in 2009-10 and an estimated US $ 58.9 billion in 2010-11 registering a CAGR of 22.2 per cent from 2004-05 to 2010-11. Though the IT-ITES sector is export driven, the domestic market is also significant with a revenue growth of US $ 14 billion in 2009-10 and estimated revenue of US $ 17.2 billion in 2010- 11. This sector has also led to employment generation. Direct employment in the IT services and BPO/ITES segment was 2.3 million in 2009-10 and is estimated to reach nearly 2.5 million by the end of financial year 2010-11. Indirect employment of over 8.3 million job opportunities is also expected to be generated due to the growth of this sector in 2010-11. These jobs have been generated in diverse fields such as commercial and residential real estate, retail, hospitality, transportation, and security. India continues to be the dominant player in the global outsourcing sector. However, its future will depend on how the challenges related to competitiveness are tackled. These include increasing competition, rising costs, talent shortfall, infrastructure constraints, increasing risk perception, protectionism in key markets, and deteriorating business environment. The share of banking and insurance services of the total services output has remained consistently around 10%, while its share in GDP growth has increased steadily over time. In 2008, India had 88 scheduled commercial banks, 27 public sector banks, 31 private banks and 38 foreign banks. The banks have a combined network of over 53,000 branches and 17,000 automated teller machines (ATMs). According to a report by ICRA Limited, a rating agency, the public sector banks hold over 75% of the total assets of the banking industry, with the private and foreign banks holding 18.2% and 6.5%, respectively. Accounting, auditing, and book-keeping services are part of ‘business services’. The accounting profession in India is highly developed with the potential to become internationally more competitive. As per the WTO data, in the $33.76 billion other business services exports by India in 2008, the share of legal, accounting, management, and public relations services was 17.4 per cent and in the $21.06 billion imports of other business services by India, their share was 17.9 per cent. 59 | P a g e Indian accounting firms are increasingly getting integrated, and are providing associated services such as management consultancy, corporate finance, and advisory services, in addition to their core business of accounting, auditing, and tax services. The Indian accounting sector mainly comprises small and medium enterprises (SMEs), matching the existing economic structure of India. The number of chartered accountancy firms with five or more partners is about 2000 out of more than 13000 firms. The cost and management of accounting profession in India has attained great maturity with the quality of professional cost and management accounting services being on par with the best in the world. Scientific use of management accounting tools on a wider scale can bring about higher cost efficiency in operations and take the Indian accounting industry to greater heights. As per the Department of Science and Technology estimates, the national investment on R&D activities was Rs. 37,777.9 crore in 2007-08. India, with a R&D share of 0.8 per cent in the GDP in 2007-08, is ahead of other developing countries like Mexico, Malaysia and Chile. India lags behind countries like South Korea 3.5 per cent, Russia 1.1 per cent, China 1.5 per cent, and Brazil 1per cent. A cross-country comparison of expenditure on R&D by sectors shows the dominance of the business enterprises sector in other countries. In India Government sector continues to account for a leading share, an important development has been the rising share of the business enterprises sector from 19 per cent in 2002 to almost 30 per cent in 2007. As per estimates in 2009-10, the sectors which attracted largest R&D expenditures include pharmaceuticals, electrical, non electrical machinery, transport equipment, electronics and plastics. R&D intensity (R&D as per cent of sales) for the pharmaceuticals sector was much higher than other sectors. There is huge potential for R & D services, particularly in healthcare, biotech and electronics. However, there are issues related to intellectual property rights (IPRs) in the sector. India has amended the IPR laws in the past two decades and its laws are fully compliant with WTO regulations. The Government has taken many measures to encourage R&D like enhancing the weighted deduction on expenditure incurred on inhouse R&D from 150 per cent to 200 per cent for the manufacturing business and from 60 | P a g e 125 per cent to 175 per cent for payments made to national laboratories, research associations, colleges, universities and other institutions for scientific research. Also allowing a 125 per cent weighted deduction for approved associations engaged in research in social sciences or statistical research, besides exemptions in the income from approved research associations in the Budget 2010-11. The legal systems in India is rooted in British common law, thus making Indian lawyers competent, without much additional training, to undertake standard legal work such as vetting of contracts, patent registrations, or reviewing of documents. India has an estimated 600,000 legal practitioners and is next only to USA in terms of numbers. According to industry sources, Indian commercial law practice generates Rs. 600 crore to Rs. 650 crore per annum in revenues. The service providers are individual lawyers and small or family-based firms. In India, the practice of law is governed by the Advocates Act of 1961. India has over 750 law colleges and about 30,000 lawyers graduating every year. The Bar Council of India, which lays down the standards of professional conduct and etiquette, standards for legal education has been constituted under the Advocates Act 1961. There are also State Bar Councils that enrol advocates and enforce discipline. Government has constituted the National Legal Services Authority (NLSA), under the Legal Services Authorities Act 1987 to monitor and evaluate implementation of legal aid programmes and lay down policies and principles for making legal services available under the Act. India is ranked 41st, with a score of 4.8, in terms of judicial independence, according to the Global Competitiveness Report (2010-11) of the World Economic Forum. Over the years, the legal system in India has undergone changes. This has enabled transformation of Indian lawyers into global service providers. Since liberalization Indian lawyers have been gaining dynamic experience in handling cases in fields such as banking, telecom, insurance, power, civil aviation, and transportation, which were earlier largely under the purview of the public sector. In addition, they have acquired experience in areas related to taxation, mergers and acquisitions, joint ventures, IPRs, FDI, and special economic zones. India’s prominence in the Legal Process Off- shoring (LPO) segment is being widely acknowledged in the global market. Potential exists for India to tap a significant 61 | P a g e share of world LPO business. India holds significant advantage in various parameters that work in favour of driving the LPO industry towards India. Off-shoring legal work to India saves about 80 per cent of the cost that may be incurred in a developed country like USA. It is estimated that the cost of employing a fresh law graduate in the USA would be US $150,000 per annum as compared to US $ 15,000 per annum in India. Consultancy is essentially a knowledge based profession with an underlying developmental role spanning a wide range of sectors. Consultancy services play an important role in the development of the economy and consultancy exports enhance the visibility of Indian technical expertise abroad and boost the external sector in multiple ways including foreign exchange revenues, promotion of export of technology and merchandise (especially capital goods and raw materials) and training of personnel while contributing significantly to national development in the host country. Revenues of Indian consulting industry are estimated at US$ 4.41 billion in 2007. Though the consulting profession contributed only 0.44 per cent to the GDP in 2007, growth rates of the industry have been extremely promising over the last few years with a CAGR of about 73.68 per cent between 2002 and 2007. The consultancy services market can be broadly categorized into management consultancy and engineering consultancy. Some of the commonly provided services across both fields of consultancy include detailed project reports, impact studies, evaluation/ assessment studies, advisory services, design and detailed engineering. Consulting services in India are being provided by a host of entities, the major categories being individual consultants, consulting firms, R&D organizations, academic institutes, and professional bodies. Consulting firms are the dominant players (64 per cent) followed by individual consultants (22 per cent), R & D organizations (10 per cent), academic institutes (3 percent), and professional bodies (1 per cent). The client sectors to which consulting services are provided include agriculture, banking and financial services, chemicals, education, energy, entertainment, environment, governance, public administration and policy, hospitality, infrastructure, manufacturing, real estate, retail, information technology, telecommunications, transport and utilities. 62 | P a g e The Indian management consultancy industry has shown high growth partly due to the low base from which it picked up. Growth in management consultancy exports was also high with exports amounting to US$7.3 billion in the year 2006-07. The Indian engineering consultancy market is experiencing a boom, with many large-scale development projects driving its growth. It is a more developed market as compared to the management consultancy market. Although it is still relatively small in revenue size as compared to the global engineering consultancy market standing at US$ 2.91 billion in the year 2006-07. The Indian engineering consultancy industry has shown a steady growth over the last few years. India has emerged as one of the fastest growing consultancy markets worldwide. This is largely attributable to increased investment activities due to liberalization of FDI restrictions, entry of many new players into the Indian market, high growth in most key sectors and India being an emerging economy and a low- cost sourcing destination. The construction industry in India is an important indicator of development as it creates investment opportunities across various related sectors. The construction industry has contributed an estimated Rs 3,84,282 crore (at constant prices) to national GDP in 2010-11 (a share of around 8 per cent). The industry is fragmented, with a handful of major companies involved in construction activities across all segments; medium sized companies specializing in niche activities; and small and medium contractors who actually work on subcontract basis and carry out the work in the field. The sector is labour intensive and provides employment to more than 35 million people. Creation of physical assets is an important outcome of construction activity. Before liberalization the sector was dependent on Government spending on infrastructure. The sector was given industry status in the year 2000. Since then, there are more initiatives by the Government to undertake projects on PPP basis. These initiatives have resulted in more private ownership of build-operate transfer (BOT), build-operate-own-transfer (BOOT), and build-operate-lease-transfer (BOLT) projects. FDI is allowed up to 100 per cent under the automatic route in townships, housing, built-up infrastructure, and construction of development projects (which include housing, commercial premises, educational institutions, and recreational facilities). The 63 | P a g e construction sector has major linkages with the building materials industry since they account for sizeable share of the construction costs (approximately 40 per cent to 50 per cent). The construction component accounts for more than half of the investment required for setting up critical infrastructure like power projects, ports, railways, roads, and bridges. The sector therefore is critical for enhancing the productive capacity of the overall economy. Construction sector is all set to become one of the growth engines of the Indian economy in the foreseeable future. Construction services have been brought under the ambit of services tax since the year 2004. However, certain infrastructure projects like dams, roads, bridges, railways, and airports and projects awarded by Government/ local bodies are exempt from services tax. The existing VAT Act provides for deduction of subcontractor turnover based on documentary evidence. The outlook for the services sector which had slightly dimmed due to the fallout of the sub- prime crisis in the US and the global financial crisis has once again brightened. Recent business performance indicators of different service firms in different sub-sectors also support this healthy prognosis. Even during the crisis year, annual services growth was around the 10 per cent mark, which it has maintained since 2005-06. This is in contrast to the overall GDP growth which fell to 6.8 per cent in 2008-09 from 9.3 per cent in 2007-08. Thus the resilience of the services sector has greatly contributed to the resilience of the economy. 64 | P a g e Chapter-IV INTER LINKAGES BETWEEN SECTORS Structural changes have been historically associated with the economic development in the national economies. It has been defined as a process combining economic growth with changing share of different sectors in the national product and labour force. Structural changes observed historically have followed a sequence of shift from agriculture to industry and then to services. An underdeveloped economy is characterised by a predominant share of agriculture; with development the share of industry increases and that of agriculture declines, and subsequently after reaching a reasonably high level of development, the services sector increases in importance, becoming a major component of the economy. This pattern holds across historically and with countries with different levels of development. Structural shifts and changing sectoral shares are found to hold both for the national product and the work-force. Structural changes do not only characterise economic development, they are also necessary for sustaining economic growth. The neoclassical view that sectoral composition is a relatively unimportant by-product of growth has been convincingly questioned by structural economists like Kuznets, who have empirically demonstrated that growth is brought about by changes in sectoral composition. This is so both for the reasons of demand and supply. Emphasis laid on different factors by different economists has varied a lot, the broad line of reasoning advanced by pioneers like Fisher and Clark and followed with some elaborations and modifications by later analysts has been as follows: Income elasticity of demand for agricultural products is low. Income elasticity for industrial, particularly manufacturing goods is high. Income elasticity for services is still higher. 65 | P a g e As a result, the demand for agricultural products relatively declines and that for industrial goods increases with rising levels of income, and after reaching a reasonably high level of income, demand for services increases sharply. Accordingly the shares of different sectors in the national product get determined by the changes in the pattern of demand. On the supply side, agriculture being mainly dependent on a fixed factor of production, namely land, faces a limit on its growth and is subject to early operation of the law of diminishing returns. Industry, especially manufacturing offers large scope for use of capital and technology, which could be multiplied almost without limit with human effort. Labour supply could constrain expansion of industry, but it is possible to overcome it by introducing labour-saving technological changes. It also applies to services, where application of technologies seems to offer much larger scope, as shown by the experience of past few decades. In the case of services, there are also additional reasons why their share in national product increases with industrial development. These arise both out of the technological developments and economic and institutional arrangements compelled by them (Kuznets, 1966). Technological developments facilitate and economically necessitate geographical concentration and large scale based production. It leads to larger requirements of transport, storage and communication. In a rural economy, most of the food is produced close to the consumers but with increasingly larger population getting located in urban areas result in requirements of transport and trade increase even for making available food to the consumers. Increasing demand for housing in urban areas leads not only to the expansion of construction activity but also leads to demand for housing related services. These are generally not common in villages. Higher income levels not only give rise to higher demand for personal services such as education, health and recreation but also technology based modes of meeting them which leads to demand for other services. For example, when the conventional means of recreation such as folk songs and dances or fairs and festivals give way to radio and television, then a whole host of new services of repair, maintenance, production, broadcast, telecast and distributive arrangements for programmes develop. Larger scale and increasing complexity of economic organisations in different sectors of activity give rise to the need of regulation, requiring expansion in government machinery. There is a disagreement among economists regarding the primary 66 | P a g e force behind structural changes that accompany economic development. Classical economists like Fisher and Clark, basing their arguments on Engel’s Law thought that shift from agriculture to industry takes place as a result of low income elasticity of demand for agricultural products and high income elasticity of demand for manufactured goods. They seem to lay different emphasis on the demand and supply side factors in respect of shift from manufacturing to services. Fisher (1939, 1946) emphasised saturation of demand for manufactured goods and high income elasticity of demand for services. Basing his argument on the so-called “hierarchy of needs”, Clark agreed that final demand will increasingly shift to services, but shift of labour force takes place, according to him, due to high productivity of manufactured goods and low productivity of services. Kuznets (1971) saw income elasticity of demand as the primary reason for changes in economic structure, but recognised that other factors, technological and institutional, also play an important role in accelerating these changes. Primarily emphasising on the supply side, Kaldor (1966, 1967) considered manufacturing as the engine of growth. Agriculture being subject to diminishing returns is not able to sustain an increasing level of production and income therefore manufacturing without such limitations on expansion of production is the key to sustained economic growth. The key role of manufacturing in growth is explained by Kaldor through his three famous laws, emphasising strong causal relation between growth of manufacturing and growth of GDP, between growth of manufacturing output and growth of productivity in manufacturing and between rate of growth of manufacturing and growth of productivity in other sectors. Growth of services, according to him, was induced both by requirements of expanding industrial sector and rising levels of income. The ‘demand side’ explanation based on differences in income elasticity of demand is questioned by economists like Bamoul (1967, 2001) particularly in regard with the shift of labour force to services. According to this line of argument, employment shift does not result from changing final demand, but from differential productivity growth. Victor Fuchs (1968) in his classical study of the emergence of domination of services sector in the United States corroborates the view propounded by Bamoul and concludes 67 | P a g e that shift to services is largely a result of productivity differentials; demand shifts play only a minor role in this process. He finds that income elasticity of demand for services is only slightly higher (1.07) than for goods (0.93) and that for non-food goods is similar to that of services. Differences in emphasis placed on the ‘demand side’ and ‘supply side’ explanations of structural shifts, by different economists notwithstanding, the truth may lie somewhere in between. This view is best presented by Kuznets (1971), who sees the driving force for changes in sectoral composition of output in differences in income elasticity of demand for products of different sectors, but caused by differential growth of productivity in different sectors. Changing structure of demand with increasing per capita income levels induces changes in production structure, but at the same time, changes in technological conditions of production, increasing scale and concentration of production and institutional arrangements necessitated by changes in location of production and population, also have significant influence on the pattern of these changes. Further, the response of changing consumption demand pattern on production structure in the national economies will vary depending on the close or open character and trading possibilities of a country. In a closed economy the domestic production structure will need to respond to the changing demand pattern as much as its production capacity permits. In an open economy demand for certain commodities can be met by imports while the national production structure will primarily be determined by comparative advantage. Structural changes in the national output inevitably accompany and bring about economic growth irrespective of the primary and secondary factors causing them. Structural changes in output are also expected to be accompanied by similar changes in employment. Thus, with the decline in the share of agriculture in national product, a decline in the share of agriculture in employment can be expected resulting in a transfer of labour from agriculture to industry. In fact, such a transfer is seen by economists like Arthur Lewis (Lewis, 1955) as a source of capital accumulation and a relatively costless process of economic growth. Agriculture carried out mainly as a subsistence activity in an underdeveloped economy has a large surplus of labour with insignificant contribution to production but claiming its full share in consumption. Use of this labour in growing 68 | P a g e industrial sector leads to net addition to the national output without significantly increasing the cost of labour consisting of subsistence wage to the economy. Several assumptions involved in this approach have doubtful validity, a subject, which has been widely debated in development literature and need not be repeated here. It emphatically makes the point that economic development of an underdeveloped country not only involves but requires shift of labour from agriculture to industry. Magnitude of such shift will depend on the rate at which industrial development takes place and the technology and the labour absorbing capacity of the developing industry. There is a general agreement among economists that the employment share of services will rise in the next phase, after the first phase of shift to industry. It is not clear as to when and at what level of economic development and per capita income it will take place. The reasons why this shift will take place are also seen differently by different economists. Earlier economists like Fisher and Clark seem to take it for granted that it happens due to changing demand pattern. Fisher argued that services are “luxuries” with an income elasticity of demand greater than unity and therefore at higher income levels an increasing share of expenditure is absorbed by them and it leads to high share of services in output and labour force. Clarke argued that demand for manufactured goods saturates, settling at around 20 to 25 per cent and with continuing decline in the demand for agricultural products the demand for services rises. While Fisher assumed that increase in the share of services in final demand directly and proportionately translates into its share in employment. Later economists like Bamoul and Fuchs see a rise in the share of services in employment primarily in productivity differentials between industry and services sectors demand shifts playing a minor role. Bamoul, assuming that share of goods and services in real output is constant over time and across countries and basing his conclusion on a study of six developed countries (Canada, Germany, France, Japan, UK and US), over the period 1948-1995 finds that a higher and rising share of service sector in employment in high income countries is explained by low productivity of this sector. Victor Fuchs in his study of 48 US States over the period (1929-1965) also sees the lagging productivity growth of the services sector as the reason for its rising employment share. Increase in the share of services in employment and also to some extent in the national product is also 69 | P a g e explained in what is seen as change in the “inter-industry division of labour”. Industry has increased the use of services as intermediate inputs and many of the processes and activities of a ‘service’ nature which were carried out by manufacturing firms as part of their activity and accounted for as part of manufacturing and industry are increasingly outsourced to enterprises included in the ‘service’ category. The differences in income elasticity of demand still appear to be the driving force behind changes in product structure of an economy in an ‘agriculture-industry-services’ sequence. The supply side factors such as technology, scale and territorial concentration of production and changes in inter-industry division of labour leading to relocation of activities from one sector to another now provide increasingly significant explanation of structural shifts in output in recent years. Increasing share of labour force in services has been attributed by most economists to the low productivity in services as compared to manufacturing. A common pattern of today’s developed countries has no doubt followed historical pattern of economic development. Share of agriculture has seen a steady decline in total output. Industry registered an increase for a considerably long period, and then has shown a decline. Share of services has steadily increased all through, but the rate of increase seems to have accelerated in the latter half of the twentieth century. The period characterised by the emerging dominance of services in the economies of developed countries is also seen as signalling the dawn of a ‘post-industrial society’ (Clark, 1984). The timing of the different phases of structural changes and speed of such changes has of course been different among different countries. In the ‘pre-modern’ era, which according to Kuznet’s assessment ended at different points of time during the nineteenth century in different countries (e.g. before1800 in Great Britain, 1835 in France, 1861 in Italy, 1870 in USA, 1878 in Japan, etc.), agriculture accounted for a half to two-thirds of the total output. It seems to have taken about 75 to 100 years for this share to decline to about one-fourth in the case of most European countries, though similar shift was achieved more swiftly in North America and Japan, the relative latecomers in modern economic development. In spite of differences in time of entering the era of modern development and in the speed of transformation, the share of agriculture had declined to less than 15 per cent in most of these countries by middle of 70 | P a g e the twentieth century and has seen a further continuous decline since then, reducing it to less than 5 per cent in all of them, by the end of the twentieth century. At the beginning of the ‘modern’ development industry held a share of around 25% in most of the developed countries of today. It grew steadily and reached the peak of about one-half by 1950’s in all these countries irrespective of the period when they entered the industrialisation phase. All the developed countries have seen a decline in the share of industry in their output since the 1950’s. The changes in the share of industry have been observed to be hump-shaped (Kuznets, 1966, World Bank, 1988 and Echevarria, 1997). It is interesting to note that in most of the countries industry has the same share in output in the beginning of the twenty-first century as it had in the beginning of their journey to ‘modern’ economic growth. Thus in 2002, the share of industry in national output in the United Kingdom was 26 per cent, comparable to 23 per cent in 1801, in France 25 per cent same as in 1841, in Germany 23 per cent compared to 24 per cent in 1841, in Italy 29 per cent comparable to 22 per cent in 1901 and in USA 23 per cent comparable to 20 per cent in 1841 (Kuznets, 1966 and World Bank, 1983 and 2004). The services sector has experienced a secular increase in its share right through the period of modern economic growth in all countries except for an initial decline in a few countries namely Great Britain, France and Germany. The share crossed the 50 per cent mark by 1901 in Great Britain, saw a decline till about mid-1950 and crossed 50 per cent again by 1960. Most other countries, France, Germany, Italy and Japan had crossed this mark for the first time by 1960. The United States had hit a 50 per cent mark for services in its GDP earlier. There has been a continuous and a relatively fast increase in the share of services since the 1960’s and now it stands at 68 to 75 per cent in all the countries. The highest being 75 percent in the case of the United States, followed by the United Kingdom at 73 per cent, France at 72 per cent in 2002. It is somewhat lower at 68 per cent in Japan. The above description of changes in sectoral shares during the period of modern economic growth in today’s developed countries tends to suggest a common or a ‘normal’ pattern of development. This has been seriously questioned by a group of economists led by Chenery (Chenery and Syrquin, 1975), who have argued that for any 71 | P a g e meaningful discussion on the subject countries need to be divided into different groups by size–large, small with primary exports and small with industrial exports. Empirical work using categories of very large, large and small categories, however, shows no difference in average performance among the nations in the three groups, except that the share of industry begins to rise at a lower per capita income levels in the large than in the small countries (Perkins and Syrquin, 1989). It is interesting to observe that by the end of the twentieth century most developed countries showed a remarkably similar structure of their economies irrespective of the period when different phases of structural changes occurred. Thus agriculture contributes less than 5 per cent in GDP, industry 25 to 30 per cent and services around 70 per cent in all of them. Table: 4.1 Output and Employment Shares in Selected Developed Countries (2002) Countries Shares in output (%) Agriculture Industry Shares in employment (%) Service Agriculture Industry Service U.K. 1 26 73 1 25 74 U.S. 2 23 75 2 24 74 France 2 22 76 3 25 72 Japan 1 31 68 5 31 64 Germany 1 30 69 3 33 64 Italy 3 29 69 5 32 63 Australia 4 26 69 5 21 74 Sources: Kuznets, 1966 and World Bank 1983 & 2004 It is also equally interesting to note in general that the structure of employment is found to be remarkably similar as that of the national product. Figures of shares of different sectors in GDP and employment in 2002, as given in Table: 4.1 1 reveal a striking symmetry between the two variables. In all the seven developed countries selected agriculture contributes less than 5 per cent of GDP as well as of employment. Industry share in GDP is in the range of 22 and 30 per cent and its share in employment varying between 21 and 33 per cent follows similar pattern as of GDP among the countries. Services account between 68 and 75 per cent of GDP and 63 and 74 per cent in employment in all the countries. What is equally, if not more striking is that structural 72 | P a g e shifts in output have generally been faithfully accompanied by similar shifts in employment. So that when output share of agriculture in the United Kingdom declined from 32 per cent 1801 to 22 per cent in 1841 and further to 6 per cent in 1901, its employment share also declined correspondingly to 35, 23 and 9 per cent. When output share of industry rose from 23 per cent in 1801 to 40 per cent in 1901 and 56 per cent in 1955 and declined to 42 per cent by 1980, the corresponding change in its employment share were from 29 per cent to 54 per cent, 57 per cent and 38 per cent. Product and employment shares of different sectors in other countries have not behaved as ‘perfectly’ as their counterparts in the United Kingdom but their long-term movements have also not shown a degree of asymmetry that could result in significant widening of inter-sectoral productivity and income differentials. It can be summarised the main interesting features of the historical pattern of changes in the economic structure that accompanied economic development of today’s developed countries over the past two centuries are first, all countries irrespective of the time they embarked upon the ‘modern’ economic growth had a similar sequence of changes in their economic structure starting with a predominance of agriculture to industry and subsequently in favour of services. Second, while a decline in the share of agriculture and increase in the share of services took place continuously over a period of about two centuries but the share of industry changed in a hump-based fashion, initially increasing continuously for a period of about one and half or one century and then experiencing a decline over the last fifty years. Irrespective of the time when industrialisation started, ‘deindustrialisation’ in terms of a decline in the share of industry is observed to have started around the middle of the twentieth century in all countries. Third, the structure of the economies of most developed countries looks like a replica of each other, each of them having a miniscule share of agriculture, industry claiming about one-fourth and services around seventy per cent of the national product. Fourth, changes in the structure of labour force generally accompanied those in product structure, thus the share of each sector in employment moving in line with the output share of that sector. What is most interesting to note is the fact that today the employment structure of most developed countries is strikingly similar to their product structure reflecting a high degree of inter sectoral equality in productivity and income level. 73 | P a g e Indian economy revealed similar structural characteristics in 1950 as most developed countries of today showed at the time they embarked upon the road to industrialisation. With about 60 per cent of GDP accounted for by agriculture, industry contributing about 13 and services about 27 per cent the Indian economy in 1950 was structurally comparable to the economy of the Great Britain in late eighteenth century and of Germany at the beginning of the nineteenth century and of the United States and Italy of mid-nineteenth century and of Japan in 1900. Similar comparisons hold in respect of the share of labour force in different sectors. Agriculture accounted for about threefourths, industry for about 11 and services 16 per cent of total employment in 1950 in India. Economic development in India over a period of half a century seems to have followed the same pattern of structural changes that the developed economies of today underwent over a period ranging between 100 to 150 years. The share of agriculture in GDP declined from around 60 per cent in 1950-51 to 14.64 per cent in 2009-10. Industry increased from 13 to 28.27 per cent and of services from 28 to 57.09 per cent. This pattern of shifts has been continuous throughout the period of over half a century, but the speed of the shift has been faster since 1990-91. The first forty years saw a decline in the share of agriculture from 59 per cent to 35 per cent, the next 20 years from 35 to 15 per cent. Share of services increased from 28 to 40 per cent in the first 40 years and from 40 to 57 per cent in the next 20 years. Share of industry has grown slowly but has stagnated since 1990-91. The most striking feature of the structural change in the Indian economy in recent decades has been the pre-eminence of services sector as the major contributor to growth raising its share rather sharply in the national output. Industry particularly manufacturing which has been observed historically to be the main contributor of growth has at least in the initial period of economic development played only a minor role in India’s economic growth. Questions have been raised whether India is already at a level of development to sustain such a change in the sources and pattern of economic growth. In other words while developed countries entered the phase of predominance of services in their economies after going through a phase of industrialisation, and industry having attained a share of 50 per cent in the economy. India is on the way to become a postindustrial ‘service economy’ without industrialising. 74 | P a g e Generally two propositions have been advanced to explain such a swift and a historical transition of an economy directly from an agricultural to a service economy bypassing industrial development. It is argued that technological advancements over the past few decades have led to increasing demand for services even at a relatively low level of per capita income and also the distinction between products and services has become rather blurred. Development of communication technologies and movements of people across countries have produced demonstration effect creating similar pattern of demand in developing countries as in the developed countries leading to larger demand for and consequently production of services (Panchamukhi, Nambiar and Mehta, 1986). As a result, elasticity of demand for services has become greater than unity even in countries with relatively low per capita income levels (Sabolo, 1975) leading to a rise in the contribution of services in national product. Second, the classical model of structural changes with economic development was based on the experience of nations with more or less autarkic regimes with little international trade, a situation in which domestic product structure of each country has to reflect its demand pattern. With increasing openness of economies and trade playing significant role in them changes in demand pattern can be met through trade and countries can have a product pattern very different from the pattern of consumption demand largely based on comparative advantage. These propositions imply a new path of development different from the one observed to have operated in the countries which went through development process earlier and if true should hold not only in India but also in other countries with similar levels and structures of economic development. A comparison with economies of developing countries, particularly in South, South East and East Asia will be in this regard. Countries chosen for this comparison here are China, Indonesia, Malaysia, Pakistan, India, Philippines, Thailand and Republic of Korea (Table 4.2). Share of the services sector has increased in all these countries since 1960. In Indonesia, it increased from 25 per cent in 1960 to 38 per cent in 2002, in Malaysia it declined during 1960 to 1980 but raised from 36 per cent in 1980 to 44 per cent in 2002. Pakistan saw an increase from 38 to 54 per cent and the Philippines from 46 to 53 per cent between 1960 and 2002. In Thailand it increased from 41 per cent in 1960 75 | P a g e to 48 per cent in 2002. For China estimates are available since 1980 when the share of services sector in GDP stood at 21 per cent and rose to 34 per cent in 2002. In Republic of Korea, which has a much higher level of per capita income, services expanded from 43 per cent of GDP in 1960 to 55 per cent of GDP in 2002. India registered by far the fastest increase in the share of services from 30 per cent in 1960 to 51 per cent in 2002. Table: 4.2 Changes in Sectoral Shares (%) in GDP in Some Asian Countries (1960-2002) Country Agriculture Industry Services 1960 2002 1960 2002 1960 2002 30 (1980) 15 49 51 21 34 Indonesia 50 18 25 45 25 38 Thailand 40 9 19 43 41 48 Philippines 26 14 28 33 46 53 Malaysia 36 9 18 47 46 44 37 4 20 41 43 55 Pakistan 46 23 16 23 38 54 India 55 24 16 25 29 51 China Republic of Korea Source: Reproduced from T.S. Papola (2005) Note: For China estimates are available since 1980. In its share in GDP agriculture, expectedly, registered a decline in all these countries during 1960-2002, the largest decline being in the case of Thailand from 40 to 9 per cent and of course Korea from 37 per cent to 4 per cent. The share of industry experienced significant and continuous increase in most of these countries. Thus in Indonesia it increased from 25 per cent in 1960 to 42 per cent in 1980 and 45 per cent in 76 | P a g e 2002. Corresponding figures for Thailand are 19, 29 and 43 and for Malaysia 18, 41 and 47 per cent. In India, the increase in the share of industry was much smaller. In 2002 share of industry in GDP in India was 25 per cent, while it was much higher at 51 per cent in China, 45 per cent in Indonesia, 43 per cent in Thailand and 47 per cent in Malaysia. Pakistan is the only country in the group with a lower share of industry than India and the only one along with the Philippines to have experienced a decline in it during 1980-2002. Thus the proposition that the growth in the technologically advanced and globalised world of late twentieth century had to be primarily service-led in which industry plays a second fiddle does not seem to hold universally. In most developing countries similarly placed with India and growing at a reasonably high rate industry has played an important role as services in their growth. Even with a significant rise in the share of services countries like China, Indonesia and Malaysia have a higher share of industry than of services and all of them along with Thailand and Korea have over 40 per cent share of industry in their GDP as compared to about 25 per cent in India. Another significant difference between the growth pattern of these countries and India is seen in the shift of labour force with changing sectoral structure of the economy, particularly in the employment share of services. What is common in most of these countries and India is a relatively slower shift of labour force from agriculture to non-agricultural sectors. Thus while the GDP share of agriculture in China declined from 30 per cent in 1980 to 15 per cent in 2002 its employment share declined from 69 to 47. Corresponding shifts between 1960 and 2002 were: From 50 to 18 per cent in GDP and from 75 to 44 per cent in employment in Indonesia, and from 40 to 9 per cent in GDP and 84 to 46 per cent in employments in Thailand. Only in Malaysia the decline in labour force in agriculture has been commensurate with that in GDP which is from 63 to 18 per cent in the labour force compared to 36 to 9 per cent in GDP. In India, shifts during 1960-2002 have been from 55 per cent to 24 per cent in GDP and from 74 to 60 per cent in labour force. The shift in labour force in relation to decline in GDP share has been much slower in India than in other countries. Industry always had a much lower share in labour force than in GDP in all the countries and the two shares have moved similarly over the period. 77 | P a g e In Indonesia when GDP share of industry increased from 25 per cent in 1960 to 45 per cent in 2002 its employment share also increased from 8 to 17, in Thailand corresponding movements were from 19 to 43 and 4 to 21 per cent and in Malaysia from 18 to 47 and 12 to 32 per cent. In China while GDP share of industry increased from 49 in 1980 to 51 per cent in 2002 but that of employment increased from 18 to 21 per cent. In India industry share in GDP increased from 16 to 25 per cent and employment share from 11 to 18 per cent during 1960-2002. Thus the share of labour force in industry has moved similar to that of GDP in all countries including India but a similar proportion of labour force produces much larger share of output in other countries than in India. Table: 4.3 GDP and Employment Shares in Services (2002) Country Share (%) In GDP In Employment China 34 31 Indonesia 38 39 Thailand 48 33 Philippines 53 47 Malaysia 44 50 Republic Of Korea 55 62 Pakistan 54 34 India 51 22 Source: Same as Table 4.2. If we look at the difference in the growth of employment vis a vis of GDP in services. In all other countries the share of employment in services has increased more or less in line with that of GDP but in India employment share has shown much smaller increase than the GDP share. For example in China the share of services in GDP grew from 21 in 1980 to 34 per cent in 2002, their share in employment also increased from 13 to 31 per cent. In Thailand, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines and Korea, employment share increased much faster than the GDP share. In India while the share of services in GDP increased from 29 per cent in 1960 to 51 per cent in 2002, their share in employment increased from 15 per cent to 22 percent only. In other words growth of 78 | P a g e services in India has been much less employment-intensive than in other countries. As a result while in most other countries the share of services in 2002 is similar both in GDP and employment (China 34 and 31, Indonesia 38 and 39, Malaysia 44 and 50, and Korea 55 and 62 per cent). In India the two percentages are as apart from each other as 51 and 22 (Table 4.3). There has been a structural change in its sectoral composition of Indian economy over the years. This structural change and the uneven pattern of sectoral growth and the recent spurt of service led growth is likely to cause substantial change in the production and demand linkages among various sectors which in turn could have significant implication for the overall growth of the economy. At the same time the changes in the policy environment as a result of the economic reforms process WTO agreement and growing integration with the world economy in the post reform (Post 1991) period is also likely to have significant impact on the linkages between different sectors of the economy. It is widely recognized that the burden of structural adjustment and fiscal stabilization has been registered in its most virulent form in the agriculture sector. The post-reform period has witnessed significant decline in capital formation in the agriculture sector especially in the public sector. The trade liberalization has led to shifts in cropping patterns towards cash crops such as cotton, oil seed, sugar cane etc. reducing not only food availability but also increasing the volatility of agricultural incomes (Jha, 2010). As a part of the structural change within the industry sector the importance of agro-based industries has come down in the post-reform period. The jobless growth of the organized manufacturing sector and the decline in employment elasticity of the service sector in the post-reform period has put intense pressure in the farms sector which ends up with vast numbers of workers moving out of the farm sector into self-employment for mere subsistence. The relationship between agriculture and industry has been seen from different channels. First agriculture supplies food grains to industry to facilitate absorption of labour in the industry sector. Secondly agriculture supplies the inputs like raw cotton, jute, tea, coffee etc. needed by the agro-based industries. Thirdly industry supplies industrial inputs such as fertilizer, pesticides machinery etc. to the agriculture sector. 79 | P a g e Fourthly agriculture influences the output of industrial consumer goods through demand. Fifthly agriculture generates surplus of savings which can be mobilized for investment in industry and other sectors of the economy. Sixthly fluctuations in agricultural production may affect private corporate investment decisions through the impact of the terms of trade on profitability. Because of the mutual inter-dependence and symbiotic relationship between agriculture and industry the contribution of agriculture to industry is well known, especially in developing countries. Whereas some of these channels emphasize on the supply side or production side others stress the linkages through the demand side. The production linkages basically arise from the inter-dependence of the sectors for meeting the needs of their productive inputs whereas the demand linkage arises from the interdependence of the sectors for meeting final consumption. Further based on the direction of interdependence the linkages can also be categorized into two groups. One is the backward linkage which identifies how a sector depends on others for their input supplies and the other is the forward linkage which identifies how the sectors distribute their outputs to the remaining economy. The linkage between agriculture and service sectors is one-way unlike the two-way interdependence between agriculture and industry and it is mainly backward linkage. On the other hand industry has two-way linkages with the service sector and the level of linkage is much higher compared to agriculture sector. Further service sector has stronger backward linkages compared to forward linkages with both agriculture and industry (Singh N-2007 and Gordon and Gupta 2004). Service sector also provides substantial infrastructure support and inputs for the two sectors engaged in production namely primary and secondary sectors. It would be useful to review the changes in the sectoral composition of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in terms of share of agriculture, industry and services sector in the Indian economy. Table 4.4 presents temporal behaviour of the share of economic activities under primary, secondary and tertiary sectors in the national income for the period 1951-52 to 2009-10. Over the year, there is a major shift away from the agriculture towards services sector and industrial sector. 80 | P a g e Table: 4.4 Sectoral Share of GDP at Factor Cost (At 2004-05 Prices) [in Per cent] Year Agriculture Industry Services 1951-52 51.45 16.69 29.63 1960-61 47.65 20.09 30.19 1970-71 34.16 23.62 33.26 1980-81 35.69 25.66 37.65 1990-91 29.53 27.63 42.55 2000-01 22.31 27.32 50.37 2009-10 14.64 28.27 57.09 Source: Handbook of Statistics on Indian economy 2010-11. The share of primary sector has declined from 51.45% in 1951-52 to 14.64% in 2009-10. On the other side during the same period the share of services sector was consistently increasing and reached 57.09% in 2009-10 from 29.63% in 1951-52. Over this period, share of industry increased to 28.27% in 2009-10 from 16.69% in 1951-52. A decade-wise annual trend growth rates in each sector indicates a shift towards higher growth only from the early eighties contributing to a GDP growth of 5.17% (Table-4.5). Table: 4.5 Sector-wise Trend Growth Rate of GDP (At 1999-2000 Prices) {%} Year GDP at FC Agriculture Industry Services 1950-51/1959-60 3.68 2.71 5.99 4.40 1960-61/1969-70 3.29 1.51 5.15 4.74 1970-71/1979-80 3.45 1.74 5.07 4.45 1980-81/1989-90 5.17 2.97 6.41 6.35 1990-91/1999-00 6.05 3.34 6.63 7.32 2000-01/2007-08 7.76 3.09 7.46 9.55 Source: Handbook of Statistics on Indian economy 2007-08. Before that primary sector growth rate was below 2.0% in the sixties and seventies compared to a higher growth rate of 2.74% during the fifties. Secondary sector too witnessed a similar picture of high output growth in the fifties (6%) and a 81 | P a g e comparatively lesser rate 5.15% and 5.07% in the subsequent decades. Further higher rates of growth achieved in the primary and secondary sectors at 3% and 6.41% during the eighties remained unchanged in the decade that followed. In the 1990s though GDP growth was higher than the 1980s it was driven mostly by the services sector. It is the tertiary sector that has witnessed phenomenal growth from 4.40% in the fifties to 6.35% in the eighties and 7.32% in the nineties to 9.55% in the 2000s. 82 | P a g e Chapter-V GROWTH PERFORMANCE OF THE STATES The main concern of this chapter is to evaluate economic performance of states in India over the period 1980-81 to 2009-10. The differential economic performance of the states is examined by comparing the levels and growth rates of per capita income among the states during different periods. At a general level, the extent of variation in the Indian economy can be illustrated by the broad measures of the size of the state economies. There are 29 state in India with their own democratically elected assemblies. Among these, 10 states have population of more than 5 crore. There are eight states with population below half a crore. Table-1 provides the profile of the states in terms of size of the population and economies. In a view of the level of economic development, it is apparent from the fact that only seven states have a per capita GSDP more than rupees 50,000 and only one has a per capital GSDP of more than rupees 1,00,000 though this is relatively smaller states in terms of population and economic activities. Among the state with a population of more than 5 crore, Bihar and Uttar Pradesh have the lowest per capita GSDP below rupees 20,000 and Maharashtra and Gujarat which are the industrially advanced states have the per capita GSDP of more than rupees 50,000. India is a country of extraordinary diversity, where some states are as large as many countries in Europe. Regions differ enormously in terms of geography, language, demography and social norms. Importantly, there are significant differences in levels of economic development across Indian states. India is a rare example of a developing country with long-time series data for its constituent states. Although the data has its limitations, comparability across Indian states is likely to be better than the average crosscountry study (Trivedi 2002).Before analyzing the growth performance at the state level, we begin with a brief review of the growth performance at the all India level. 83 | P a g e Table: 5.1 Size and Income of India’s states (2009-10) At Constant Prices (Base Year 2004-05) S.No. States Population (crore) GSDP (crore) Per Capita GDP (Rupees) 1. Andhra Pradesh 8.365 347344 40731 2. Assam 3.004 69143 23279 3. Bihar 9.685 125875 12683 4. Jharkhand 3.087 73618 25810 5 Goa .168 19318 116287 6. Gujarat 5.791 330671 57267 7. Haryana 2.485 151563 61045 8. Himachal Pradesh .707 35907 50783 9. Jammu & Kashmir 1.151 36329 30886 10. Karnataka 5.855 257125 42527 11. Kerala 3.422 177209 52984 12. Madhya Pradesh 7.058 168851 22538 13. Chattisgarh 2.450 71221 31052 14. Maharashtra 11.049 701550 63497 15. Manipur .267 6767 25344 16. Meghalaya .258 9814 34118 17. Orissa 4.04 118201 29716 18. Punjab 2.851 139056 49453 19. Rajasthan 6.621 184189 26836 20 Tamil Nadu 6.684 350258 52112 21 Tripura .356 13061 34433 22 Uttar Pradesh 19.584 365761 18564 23 Uttaranchal .974 47599 16787 24 West Bengal 8.834 296843 33398 All India 117.00 4507637 38526 Source: Directorate of Economics and statistics of respective state Governments and for All India – CSO, Government of india, (As on 1-3-2012) & National Income Statistics Centre for Monitoring Indian Economy (July 2011). Mid Year population from CMIE 2011. 84 | P a g e Table: 5.2 Annual Growth Rate of the Major Sectors (From 1980-81 to 2009-10) in percentage. Years 1980-81 1981-82 1982-83 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08 2008-09 2009-10 Agriculture 14.44 4.86 -0.14 10.75 1.48 0.2 -0.39 -1.73 16.85 0.40 4.28 -2.31 7.06 3.18 4.74 -0.98 10.40 -2.97 7.12 2.41 -0.61 6.46 -8.14 10.84 0.07 5.53 4.13 6.34 -0.27 0.41 Industry 5.24 8.01 1.42 7.88 4.08 4.38 5.76 5.57 9.10 8.30 7.33 0.34 3.22 5.50 9.16 11.29 6.39 4.01 4.15 5.96 6.03 2.61 7.21 7.32 9.81 9.72 12.17 9.67 4.44 9.16 Services 4.62 5.19 7.13 5.72 6.10 7.67 7.59 6.35 6.95 8.88 5.19 4.69 5.69 7.38 5.84 10.11 7.53 8.93 8.28 11.19 5.37 6.88 6.97 8.06 8.13 10.91 10.06 10.27 9.98 10.50 Real GDP at FC 7.17 5.63 2.92 7.85 3.96 4.16 4.31 5.53 10.16 6.13 5.29 1.43 5.36 5.68 6.39 7.29 7.97 4.30 6.68 7.59 4.30 5.52 3.99 8.06 6.97 9.48 9.57 9.32 6.72 8.59 Source: CSO, Government of India During the three decades period from the early 1950’s t0 80’s, the Indian economy was witnessing so called “Hindu rate of growth” of 3.5 per cent per annum, though growth rate had increased to 5.5 per cent in the 1980’s and further to 6 per cent in1994 -2004. The growth has been by far the best in the 2004-10. While the growth rate of the Indian economy has been increasing in recent times, one phenomenon which was 85 | P a g e observed was that the growth performance of the three major sector s of the Indian economy, namely, agriculture, industry and services has been diverse. The growth in the agriculture sector has been the most volatile and also the least among the three sectors most of the times. While the growth in the industrial sector has remained more or less constant, growth in the services sector has risen sharply. It is very clear from the Figure 5.1. Figure: 5.1 Annual Growth rates of the Major Sectors. 20 15 10 Agriculture 5 Industry Services 0 -5 -10 The consequence of the diverse growth rate in the three sectors has resulted in a structural change in the contribution of the sectors in the total GDP. The share of the agriculture sector in the overall GDP has declined from 35.69 percent in 1980-81 to 14.45 percent in 2009-10. The share of the industrial sector has increased from 25.66 percent in 1980-81 to 28.27 percent in 2009-10. The share of the services sector has almost doubled from 37.65 per cent in 1980-81 to 57.09 per cent in 2009-10. 86 | P a g e Table: 5.3 Share of the Sectors in GDP from 1980-81 to 2009-10. Year Agriculture Industry Services 1980-81 35.69 25.66 37.65 1981-82 35.35 26.23 37.49 1982-83 34.25 25.85 39.03 1983-84 34.97 25.86 38.25 1984-85 34.17 25.88 39.04 1985-86 32.91 25.97 40.36 1986-87 31.42 26.30 41.62 1987-88 29.86 26.81 42.76 1988-89 31.35 26.56 41.51 1989-90 29.89 27.10 42.58 1990-91 29.53 27.63 42.55 1991-92 28.54 27.33 43.91 1992-93 28.89 26.77 44.05 1993-94 28.24 26.73 44.76 1994-95 27.80 27.42 44.52 1995-96 25.73 28.44 45.63 1996-97 26.19 28.03 45.51 1997-98 24.47 27.95 47.53 1998-99 24.39 27.28 48.24 1999-00 23.72 26.87 49.85 2000-01 22.31 27.32 50.37 2001-02 22.42 26.57 51.02 2002-03 20.13 27.39 52.48 2003-04 20.32 27.20 52.48 2004-05 19.03 27.93 53.05 2005-06 18.27 27.99 53.74 2006-07 17.37 28.65 53.98 2007-08 16.81 28.74 54.45 2008-09 18.77 28.13 56.11 2009-10 14.64 28.27 57.09 Source: CSO, Government of India. 87 | P a g e Figure: 5.2: Share of different Sectors during the period 1980-81 to 2009-10. 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% Services 40% Industry 30% Agriculture 20% 10% 0% Given this overall picture, now we engage our attention to the situation of the states. At the state level, the State Domestic Product (SDP) represents output. Undoubtedly, significant structural changes have taken place in the sectoral composition of income at states level broadly on the pattern observed at the national level. A steady fall in the share of agriculture to about 15%, a moderate rise in the share of the industry to around 28% and a steady rise in the share of services to about 57% in 2009-10. The share of agriculture in total GSDP had remained at around 45-50% in 198081 in respect of a large number of states such as Assam, Bihar, Himachal Pradesh, Haryana, Manipur, Madhya Pradesh, Odisha, Punjab, Rajasthan, Sikkim, Tripura and Uttar Pradesh. The Share of agriculture in Gross Domestic Product at the level of aggregate economy was around 36% in 1980-81 as per the CSO, Government of India’s National Accounts Statistics (NAS). Thus high agriculture share was observed both in agriculturally advanced states with high per Capita income (Punjab and Haryana) and in many states with low per capita income indicating general backwardness. Punjab is the only state which has retained the share of agriculture in GSDP at 40% or above until the end of the 1990s (Table 5.4). 88 | P a g e Table: 5.4 Shares of Agriculture, Industry and Services Sector in total GSDP at constant prices-state wise. 2000-01 2010-11 1980-81 1990-91 2000-01 2010-11 1980-81 1990-91 2000-01 2010-11 Services 1990-91 Industry 1980-81 Agriculture Andhra Pradesh 42.85 36.66 28.85 20.69 20.11 22.15 24.65 24.74 37.04 41.19 46.49 54.62 A & N Island 55.32 58.94 29.98 10.17 17.70 8.40 22.84 24.57 26.98 32.66 47.18 65.29 Arunachal Pradesh 44.48 42.56 32.91 29.73 24.51 24.31 22.88 31.41 31.01 33.13 44.21 38.85 Assam 45.43 38.32 33.46 26.34 14.68 16.95 22.37 23.28 39.89 44.73 44.17 50.38 Bihar 45.99 38.23 43.63 26.42 26.36 31.29 10.66 19.77 27.65 30.48 45.71 53.81 Chattisgarh N.A N.A 19.39 21.42 N.A. N.A 41.34 40.41 N.A. N.A 39.27 38.16 Delhi 4.03 2.99 1.36 .75 25.25 28.91 22.85 14.12 70.72 68.09 75.79 85.12 Goa 19.09 12.10 8.46 4.80 35.05 36.08 41.70 45.14 45.87 51.82 49.84 50.06 Gujarat 37.27 25.24 14.68 13.19 30.42 37.52 41.55 32.36 32.31 37.24 43.77 44.45 Haryana 53.39 44.87 32.23 16.67 19.86 24.42 28.30 29.34 26.77 30.71 39.47 53.99 Himachal Pradesh 46.81 36.88 21.37 19.02 20.11 25.37 37.21 41.04 33.08 37.75 31.42 39.94 Jharkhand N.A. N.A 20.17 14.02 N.A. N.A 51.13 42.00 N.A. N.A 28.70 43.98 Karnataka 43.13 32.63 29.60 16.97 23.31 26.19 26.04 29.53 33.56 41.18 44.35 53.50 Kerala 36.57 31.18 18.90 10.11 25.29 24.00 21.28 21.04 38.14 44.81 59.82 68.84 Madhya Pradesh 48.90 41.04 26.75 22.35 24.27 28.55 32.95 30.61 26.83 30.40 40.30 47.04 Maharashtra 26.74 21.37 15.60 8.71 36.03 36.31 29.94 29.62 37.23 42.32 54.46 61.67 Manipur 46.23 35.20 30.63 25.16 10.39 13.71 20.19 31.03 43.38 51.09 49.18 43.81 Meghalaya 36.64 24.75 24.82 16.66 19.50 21.81 23.15 29.42 43.86 53.44 52.03 53.92 Nagaland 29.51 27.88 31.72 27.69 16.25 26.43 15.51 16.25 54.24 45.69 52.77 56.08 Odisha 50.19 35.80 28.24 18.08 19.53 26.69 27.26 34.11 30.28 37.51 44.50 47.81 Puducherry 18.61 12.77 6.94 4.56 54.27 57.48 51.43 41.00 27.12 29.75 41.63 54.43 Punjab 49.11 47.06 40.03 23.86 20.03 24.17 23.67 30.79 30.86 28.77 36.30 45.35 Rajasthan 41.62 44.99 25.41 22.59 23.92 22.24 30.62 30.93 34.46 32.77 43.97 46.47 Tamil Nadu 24.33 21.58 17.23 8.27 35.00 35.15 34.13 31.54 40.66 43.27 48.64 60.19 Tripura 52.46 40.43 23.27 24.05 10.07 9.45 27.11 25.41 37.47 50.12 49.63 50.54 Uttar Pradesh 50.38 41.16 35.57 22.99 16.86 22.01 24.14 24.24 32.77 36.82 40.29 52.77 Uttranchal N.A. N.A 34.22 11.30 N.A. N.A 24.17 36.23 N.A. N.A 41.61 52.44 West Bengal 30.06 29.02 26.14 18.53 31.19 29.45 23.29 19.97 38.75 41.54 50.57 61.50 States /U.T. Source: CSO, Government of India. Bihar from a low per capita income group also has agriculture share above 40% till 1999-00 and the share has declined to near 36% in 2005-06. In respect of many other states, the share of agriculture sector has declined to the range of 20-30% in 2005-06. The national average stood at about 22:42 in 2000-01, 18.27% in 2005-06 and 14.64% in 89 | P a g e 2009-10. The relatively low national average could be because; a few states are relatively advanced industrially or in services sector activities, such as Maharashtra, Gujarat, Tamil Nadu and Kerala. Gujarat has under gone a large transformation with share of agriculture in GSDP declining from 38% in 1980-81 to 13% in 2010-11. The largest transformation has however, been experienced by Karnataka reducing share of agriculture in its GSDP from 43% to 17% during 1980-81 to 2010-11.Kerala is the other state where structural transformation has been fast. Slowest transformation is observed in Punjab and West Bengal. Over the period of almost 30 years the contribution of non-agricultural sectors has increased from 54 to 66 percent in Punjab. It still derives about one third of its SDP from agriculture highest in any state. Madhya Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh are also in the same category. These have agriculture shares below national average with their shares even being averaged at around 15% or less as depicted in Table5.4. A shift from agriculture to services is observed in the case of the most of the major states. In some cases where industrialization has been rapid declined in agriculture has been accompanied, to a large extend by an increase in industry. In the case of Gujarat, the share of agriculture declined from 38 to 16 percent, that is, by 22 percentage point, it was accompanied by an equal increase in the share of industry and of services by 11 percentage point each. Similarly, a decline in the share of agriculture was accompanied not only by increase in the share of services but also that of industry to a significant extent. In Punjab, agriculture has seen a relatively smaller decline in its share, it is the only state in which it still contributed almost one third (32.6%) of GSDP. The decline in the share of agriculture has however benefitted industry more than services. On the other side, in Kerala and Karnataka services have taken the major share of the loss in the share of agriculture. West Bengal is another alone case with everything happening rather slowly, agricultural GSDP has declined by 11 percentage point only (against 24 percent at the national level) industry share has significantly declined and that of services was much less than the national average. Tamil Nadu is yet another exceptional case where share of agriculture has sharply declined, it is now at the lowest (11 percent) in any state, share of industry has also significantly declined, and all the gains have gone to 90 | P a g e services sector only. Among smaller states and UTs, a very sharp shift from agriculture to non agriculture sector is observed in the case of Goa and Puducherry. In the case of Goa share of agriculture declined from 21 to 4 percent which was mostly compensated by an increase in the share of services from 40 to 56 percentages, Puduchery saw a decline in the share of agriculture from 29 to 4 percent, industry increased its share by 45 percentage points from 20 to 65 percent. In the case of the services sector, the rising share has been experienced in almost all states. Rapid increases in their services sector share has been witnessed by Kerala and Maharashtra, these have increased from around 38-40% in the 1980s to about 68% and 62% in 2010-11 respectively. Agriculturally dominating states like Punjab also had an increase in the share of services sector from around 30% to 45% during the same period. Small states like Delhi had the highest share of 70% in services throughout the period and it has increased further to near 85% in 2010-11. Eastern states like Meghalaya, Tripura and Nagaland also had a share of 50% or more in services during the most part of the period under review. Emerging new states viz., Uttrakhand (to more than 50%) and Chattisgarh(to near 40%) witnessed increasing share of services sector while that of Jharkhand hovered around less than 30% in the 1990s which increased to 43% in 201011. It is clear from the Table 5.5 that Gujarat has been the fastest growing state during the entire period 1980-81 to 2008-09 and in all the sub –periods since 1991, having recorded a GSDP growth rate of 9.48% during 1991-2001 and 11.71% during 2001-2009. Odisha has experienced the second highest growth, after Gujarat during 2001-09. Kerala is another state where both growth rate and structural transformation have been fast. Among the North Eastern states, Mizoram, Nagaland and Sikkm are the fastest growing states, having recorded a GSDP growth rate of 10& per annum during 1981-2009. The growth rate of Punjab has been one of the lowest around 5% against the National average of 7% during 1980-81 to 2008-09. During 2000-01 to 2008-09 when the national economy grew at 8.3% per annum Punjab’s economy grew at 5.4%. Tamil Nadu has also not done very well in terms of the growth of its GSDP. The state experienced an average 91 | P a g e growth rate of 6.5% over the period 1980-81 to 2008-09, though it has accelerated to 7.6% during 2001 to 2008-09. Table: 5.5 Trend Growth Rate in Total GSDP States 1980-81/1990-91 1990-91/2000-01 2000-01/08-09 1980-81/2008-09 Andhra Pradesh 4.11 5.31 8.57 5.43 A & N Island* 5.6 5.05 13.52 6.76 Arunachal 11.82 3.67 9.97 6.49 Assam Pradesh* 3.4 2.4 5.4 3.11 Bihar 4.57 3.2 7.17 3.81 Delhi 8.67 0.13 9.84 4.57 Goa* 4.65 7.15 11.2 6.4 Gujarat* 3.82 7.69 10.24 6.64 Haryana** 5.97 5.13 8.6 5.94 Himachal 4.85 6.35 7.74 5.98 Karnataka Pradesh* 4.84 7.07 8.73 6.34 Kerala* 2.46 5.57 8.38 5.27 Madhya Pradesh 3.43 4.63 5.04 4.43 Maharashtra* 5.84 6.49 8.39 6.44 Manipur 2.82 9.98 5.43 5.52 Meghalaya 4.92 10.48 6.84 7.82 Nagaland** 18.8 8.81 6.36 12.96 Odisha 4.03 4.02 9.19 4.42 Puducherry 4.15 12.18 10.63 8.38 Punjab 5.04 4.69 5.39 4.67 Rajasthan 6.5 6.22 7.66 6.23 Tamil Nadu 5.06 6.48 7.59 5.88 Tripura* 5.58 12.76 8.03 9.1 Uttar Pradesh 4.64 3.97 3.91 4.35 West Bengal* 4.65 6.66 6.57 5.81 India 5.52 6.12 8.26 6.09 Source: www.mospi.bov.in Note: 1. *Latest available data is for the year 2007-08. 2. ** Latest data available is for the year 2006-07. 92 | P a g e Although the Indian states have long shared common political institutions and national economic policies, there is wide diversity in other factors such as the level of human resource development, the quality of infra structure, the economic policy environment and the quality of governance. There is an altogether different profile of India, a country with the largest number of poor and destitute in the world. India also accounts for the largest number of illiterates; and the largest number of unemployed. It has the largest number of anaemic women and children, and huge infant/child and maternal mortality. Indians constitute about 17 per cent of world population. But we account for about 35 per cent of the poor and 40 per cent of the illiterates in the world. There are more poor and illiterates today than at the time of independence sixty years ago. Our infant mortality is still about 60 per 1000 live births, which is one of the highest in the world. More than 50 per cent of Indian women and children are anaemic due to acute nutritional deficiency. India also experiences a high incidence of morbidity and mortality on account of various waterborne diseases, tuberculosis, diabetes, etc. These are not normal characteristics of a modern nation which is aspiring to be a world economic power. A decent society cannot be built on the ruins of hunger, our inherited past and the aspirations for the future are neglected beyond limit. As a result huge damage is done to their physical and mental health. If the trend continues, our chances of gaining from globalization on the strength of our human resources are slim. As per the UNDP Human Development Report 2009 (HRD 2009), India ranked 134 out of 182 countries of the world placing it at the same rank as in 2006. However, the HDI value of India has increased gradually from 0.427 in 1982, 0.556 in 2000 and went up to 0.612 in 2007, but it is still in the medium Human Development category with even countries like China, Sri Lanka and Indonesia having better ranking (Table 5.6). 93 | P a g e Table: 5.6 Human Development Index Country 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2006 2007 Poland -- -- 0.806 0.823 0.853 0.871 0.876 0.880 Brazil 0.685 0.694 0.710 0.734 0.790 0.805 0.808 0.813 Russia -- -- 0.821 0.777 -- 0.804 0.811 0.817 Turkey 0.628 0.674 0.705 0.730 0.758 0.796 0.802 0.806 Thailand 0.658 0.684 0.706 0.727 0.753 0.777 0.780 0.783 China 0.533 0.556 0.608 0.657 0.719 0.756 0.763 0.772 Sri Lanka 0.649 0.670 0.683 0.696 0.729 0.752 0.755 0.759 Indonesia 0.522 0.562 0.624 0.658 0.673 0.723 0.729 0.734 Vietnam -- 0.561 0.599 0.647 0.690 0.715 0.720 0.725 Egypt 0.496 0.552 0.580 0.631 0.665 0.696 0.700 0.703 India 0.427 0.453 0.489 0.511 0.556 0.596 0.604 0.612 Source: Human Development Report , 2009 In fact India lags behind in various social indicators of development. There is a huge gap between India and developed world and even many developing countries. In respect of health and education, which needs to be bridged at faster pace. According to HDR, life expectancy at birth in India was 63.4 years in 2007 as against 80.5 years in Norway, 81.4 years in Australia 74.0 years in Sri Lanka and 72.9 years in China. Adult literacy rate (aged 15 and above) in 1999-2007 was 66.0 percent in India as against near 100 percent in China and 92.0 percent in Indonesia. In the case of combined gross enrolment ratio in education also India was much below the level achieved by some other comparable countries like China, Norway and Thailand etc. Poverty is another major issue in India. In the country as a whole, the number of persons below the poverty line declined from 44.5 percent in 1993-94 to 36 percent in 1993-94 and to 26.10 percent in 1999-00 and increased to 27.5 percent in 2004-05. As per the official estimates, the incidence of poverty has declined over the years though it remains still at a very high level. However not only the rate is still high, but also the rate of decline in poverty has not accelerated along with the growth in the GDP. 94 | P a g e Table: 5.7 Trends in poverty in India Poverty (head count index) percentage Year Number of Poor (million) Rural Urban Total 1973-74 56 49 55 321 1983-84 46 41 45 323 1993-94 37 32 36 320 2004-05 28 26 28 302 Source: Reserve Bank of India occasional papers. Moreover, the absolute number of poor people below poverty line has declined only marginally from 320 million in 1993-94 to 302 million in 2004-05. This performance is all the more disappointing since the poverty line on which the estimate of the poor is based is the same as it was in 1973-74 when per capita incomes were much lower. If we take the World Bank measurement of poverty about 41.6 percent (as per PPP) of population is below poverty line which is much higher than the official national poverty ratio of about 28 percent. It can further be stated that around 80.0 percent of the poor are from rural areas. From the table 5.8 it is clear that poverty is mostly concentrated in few states, viz Bihar (41.4 percent), Madhya Pradesh (38.3 percent), Maharashtra (30.7 percent), Odisha (46.4 percent) and Uttar Pradesh (32.8 percent). These states are among those which has higher poverty ratio than the national average of 27.5 percent in the year 2004-05. Poverty is concentrated among agricultural labourers, casual workers, schedule cast and Schedule Tribes. 95 | P a g e Table: 5.8 Poverty rates across states State / UT 1983-84 1993-94 1999-00 2004-05 Andhra Pradesh 28.9 22.2 15.8 15.8 Arunachal Pradesh 40.9 39.4 33.5 17.6 Assam 40.8 40.9 36.1 19.7 Bihar 62.2 55.0 42.6 41.4 Goa 18.9 14.9 14.4 13.8 Gujarat 32.8 24.2 14.1 16.8 Haryana 21.4 25.1 8.7 14.0 Himachal Pradesh 16.4 28.4 7.6 10.0 Karnataka 38.2 33.2 20.0 25.0 Kerala 40.4 25.4 12.7 15.0 Madhya Pradesh 49.8 42.5 37.4 38.3 Maharashtra 43.4 36.9 25.0 30.7 Manipur 37.0 33.8 28.5 17.3 Meghalaya 38.8 37.9 33.9 18.5 Mizoram 36.0 25.7 19.5 12.6 Nagaland 39.3 37.9 32.7 19.0 Odisha 65.3 48.6 47.2 46.4 Punjab 16.2 11.8 6.2 8.4 Rajasthan 34.5 27.4 15.3 22.1 Sikkim 39.7 41.4 36.6 20.1 Tamil Nadu 51.7 35.0 21.1 22.5 Tripura 40.0 39.0 34.4 18.9 Uttar Pradesh 47.1 40.9 31.2 32.8 West Bengal 54.9 35.7 27.0 24.7 Delhi 26.2 14.7 8.2 -- All India 44.5 36.0 26.1 27.5 Source: Reserve Bank of India Occasional Papers. 96 | P a g e Table: 5.9 Male-female Literacy Gap in India States/UT Literacy Rate 1991 census Male Female Literacy Gap Literacy Rate 2001 census Male Female Literacy Gap Rajasthan 55.0 20.4 34.6 75.7 43.9 31.9 Jharkhand 55.8 25.5 30.3 67.3 38.9 28.4 Uttar Pradesh 54.8 24.4 50.5 68.8 42.2 26.6 Bihar 51.4 22.0 29.4 59.7 33.1 26.6 Madhya Pradesh 58.5 29.4 29.2 76.1 50.3 25.8 Chhattisgarh 58.1 27.5 30.6 77.4 51.9 25.5 Odisha 63.1 34.7 28.4 75.4 50.5 24.8 Uttarakhand 72.8 41.6 31.2 83.3 59.6 23.7 Haryana 69.1 40.5 28.6 78.5 55.7 22.8 Gujarat 73.4 48.9 24.5 79.7 57.8 21.9 Arunachal Pradesh 51.5 29.7 21.8 63.8 43.5 20.3 Andhra Pradesh 55.1 32.7 22.4 70.3 50.4 19.9 Manipur 71.6 47.6 24.0 80.3 60.5 19.8 Karnataka 67.3 44.3 22.9 76.1 56.9 19.2 Maharashtra 76.6 52.3 24.2 86.0 67.0 18.9 Tamil Nadu 73.8 51.3 22.4 82.4 64.4 18.0 Himachal Pradesh 75.4 52.3 23.2 85.4 67.4 17.9 West Bengal 67.8 46.6 21.3 77.0 59.6 17.4 Assam 61.9 43.0 18.8 71.3 54.6 16.7 Sikkim 65.7 46.8 18.9 76.0 60.4 15.6 Puducherry 83.7 65.6 18.1 88.6 73.9 14.7 Goa 83.6 67.1 16.6 88.4 75.4 13.1 Delhi 82.0 67.0 15.0 87.3 74.7 12.6 Punjab 65.7 50.4 15.3 75.2 63.4 11.9 Nagaland 67.6 54.8 12.9 71.2 61.5 9.7 Kerala 93.6 86.2 7.5 94.2 87.7 6.5 Meghalya 53.1 44.9 8.3 65.4 59.6 5.8 India 64.1 39.3 24.9 75.3 53.7 21.6 Source: Selected Socio Economics Statistics, India, CSO. 97 | P a g e The trend in the gender disparity is another important indicator of growth. India has made significant strides in terms of reducing the gender disparities as reflected in various indicators. For instance, the female life expectancy at birth, the female literacy level and the share of women employed in the non agricultural sector have improved since 1990. The male female literacy and literacy gap during the last two censuses across states are given in the table 5.9. Though the literacy gap across states has visibly come down over the decade, in many states and Union Territories, it is more than the national average. Literacy gap is highest among the North Indian states with the exception of Punjab, Himachal Pradesh and Chandigarh. However, for Punjab, the low literacy gap is more to do with the low literacy rates which is worrisome phenomenon considering that Punjab ranks in terms of per capita in NSDP. Table: 5.10 Percentage of population living with housing amenities(Lighting.) 1999-2000 2005-06 Rural Urban Rural Urban No Lighting 0.5 0.3 0.5 0.2 Kerosene 50.6 10.3 42.2 7.2 Other oil 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.1 Gas 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 Candle 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.3 Electricity 48.4 89.1 56.3 92 Other 0.1 0.1 0.5 0.1 Not Recorded 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 All 100 100 100 100 Source: Selected Socio Economic Statistics, India, CSO. Another aspect of looking into the development of the region is the provision of basic facilities. Table 5.10 provides the data on the percentage of population with housing amenities . While there is significant improvement in the availability of electricity, there is huge difference in rural urban. While only 8 percent of urban population is not having electricity, the share is 44 percent in the case of rural areas. The above indicators provided significant facts on differences in the socio economic conditions across regions. 98 | P a g e Table: 5.11 Selected Indicators of Human Development for major States Infant Mortality Rate Life expectancya at State (per 1000 live births) birth (2002-2006) Male Andhra (2010) Female Total Male Female Total Birth rate (per 1000) (2010) Death rate (per 1000) (2010) 62.9 65.5 64.4 44 47 46 17.9 7.6 Assam 58.6 59.3 58.9 56 60 58 23.2 8.2 Bihar 62.2 60.4 61.6 46 50 48 28.1 6.8 Gujarat 62.9 65.3 64.1 41 47 44 21.8 6.7 Haryana 65.9 66.3 66.2 46 49 48 22.3 6.6 Karnataka 63.6 67.1 65.3 37 39 38 19.2 7.1 Kerala 71.4 76.3 74 13 14 13 14.8 7.0 58.1 57.9 58 62 63 62 27.3 8.3 Maharashtra 66.0 68.4 67.2 27 29 28 17.1 6.5 Odisha 59.5 59.6 59.6 60 61 61 20.5 8.6 Punjab 68.4 70.4 69.4 33 35 34 16.6 7.0 Rajasthan 61.5 62.3 62 52 57 55 26.7 6.7 Tamil Nadu 65.0 67.4 66.2 23 24 24 15.9 7.6 60.3 59.5 60 58 63 61 28.3 8.1 64.1 65.8 64.9 29 32 31 16.8 6.0 62.6 64.2 63.5 46 49 47 22.1 7.2 Pradesh Madhya Pradesh Uttar Pradesh West Bengal India Source: Sample Registration System, Office of the Registrar General, India, Ministry of Home Affairs Note: a Data relating to Bihar, M.P. and U.P. includes Jharkhand, Chittisgarh and Uttarakhand respectively. 99 | P a g e In case of infant mortality rates, the disparity is very high (Table 5.11). It ranges from 13 in Kerala to 62 in Madhya Pradesh against national average of 47.In 2010 among the states which had higher birth rate than the national average of 22.1 percent that year the highest was in Uttar Pradesh (28.3) followed by Bihar(28.1), Madhya Pradesh (27.3), and Rajasthan (26.7) (Table 5.11). Kerala is on the top in life expectancy (74) , infant mortality rate (13) and in case of birth rate and death rate it is 14.8 and 7.0 respectively. Kerala has been praised for its achievement on human development specially eduction and health. Employment growth in the organised sector, both public and private combined has declined during the period 1994 and 2007. This has happened to the decline of employment in the public organised sector. Employment in the organised sector grew at 1.20 percent per annum during 1983-94 but declined to (-)0.03 percent per annum during 1994-2007. Table: 5.12 Rate of growth of employment in organised sector. (% per annum) Sector 1983-94 1994-2007 Public Sector 1.53 -0.57 Private Sector 0.44 1.30 Total Organised 1.20 -0.03 Source: Economic Survey 2009-10, Government of India. However, the decline in employment during the later period was mainly due to decline in the public sector establishments from 1.53 percent in the earlier period to (-) 0.57 percent in the later period where as the private sector showed moderate growth of 1.30 percent per annum. According to NSSO data compared to 1999-00, during 2004-05 the unemployment rate in terms of the usual status remained almost the same in rural and urban areas for males, though it hs increased by around 2 percentage points for females as can be observed from the table 5.13. Overall employment rates are not too high. 100 | P a g e Table: 5.13 Unemployment rates in India according to usual status, current weekly status and current daily status 1993-94 to 2004-05. Male Female Year (round) Usual Status CWS CDS Usual Status CWS CDS Rural 1993-94 (50th round) 2.0 3.1 5.6 1.3 2.9 5.6 1999-00 (55th round) 2.1 3.9 7.2 1.5 3.7 7.0 2004-05 (61st round) 2.1 3.8 8.0 3.1 4.2 8.7 Urban 1993-94 (50th round) 5.4 5.2 6.7 8.3 7.9 10.4 1999-00 (55th round) 4.8 5.6 7.3 7.1 7.3 9.4 2004-05 (61st round) 4.4 5.2 7.5 9.1 9.1 11.6 Source: NSSO, 61st round. Note: CWS: Current Weekly Status, CDS: Current Daily Status. However urban unemployment rates are higher than the rural rates.The unemployment rates according to current daily status (CDS) approach are higher than the rate obtained according to ‘usual status’ approach and ‘weekly status’ approach, thereby indicating a high degree of intermittent unemployment. The unemployment measured though the usual status is very low in the rural areas. 101 | P a g e Economic development and social development are mutually reinforcing. Disparities in economic development and social development are also mutually reinforcing. Socially excluded are economically marginalized. Economically marginalized remain socially excluded. The gains of economic development accrue disproportionately to the socially developed groups. The economic gains will help them to further horn up their social skills which in turn will enable them to gain even more from the economic opportunities. On the other hand, socially backward may gain only marginally from economic development which may not be sufficient for them to improve their social skills to enable them to earn more. This vicious circle transcends from generation to generation. There exist several dimensions of economic and social disparities of development in the country. . 102 | P a g e Chapter-VI REGIONAL DISPARITIES IN SERVICES SECTOR IN INDIA A number of studies have looked at the trends in regional inequality among the regions of the Indian economy. Beginning with Cashin and Sahay (1996), they found that over 1961-91 there was a widening of the dispersion of real per capita NSDP for the Indian states. However Cashin and Sahay reports evidence of weak β convergence. They also point out that the speed of convergence, 1.5 percent per year is slower than that of regional convergence in industrial economies (Australia,U.S, Canada and Japan). Whose rate of convergence has been 2 percent. Bajpai and Sachs (1996) found evidence of divergence of state Domestic Products in the time period 1971-93. They also found evidence of a weak positive relationship between initial State Domestic Product and the economic growth rate in the same time period 1971-1993. Das and Barua (1996), Nagaraj, Varoudakis and Veganzones (2000), Rao, Shand and Kalirajan (1999) and Yagci (1999) also found similar evidence of divergence in India. Yagci reports that higher income sttes have grown faster since 1980 as compared to lower income states. Most of these studies cover the period until mid 1990s. Although a few recent studies cover the entire 1990s, a decade that is useful in understanding the effect that the reforms has had on regional disparity. the most influential studies in this context is by, Ahluwalia (2000,2002) which use population weighted Gini coefficient and show that inequality in real per capita gross state domestic product (GSDP) has tended to rise particularly in the 1990s. Confirming the rising trend of disparity, Shetty (2003) too observes that regional disparity did increase, whether measured at 1980-81 prices or 1993-94 prices for the period from 1980-81 to 2000-01. For convenience the scholars restricted their analysis to only major Indian states on state domestic product (SDP) data in view of data limitations associated with smaller states and union territories in India. Breaking from this trend Shetty calculates the regional inequality based on all states and union territories of India and find that the disparity is 103 | P a g e much higher compared to that which is based on major states only. The estimated Gini coefficients from both Ahluwalia and Shetty show that during the 1980s regional inequality remained stable till about 1986-87 and started increasing slowly thereafter but not as fast as in the 1990s. B.B. Bhattacharya and Sakthivel (2004) analyses the growth rates of aggregate and sectoral domestic product of major states in the pre and post reform decades. The results indicate that while the growth rate of gross domestic product has improved only marginally in the post-reform decade regional disparity in state domestic product (SDP) has widened much more drastically. The coefficient of variation of per capita GSDP which was 0.22 percent per annum in the 1980s doubled to 0.43 percent per annum during the 1990s. Similarly, Rao et al (1999) find enough evidence of widening interstate income disparities for the period from 1960-61 to 1994-95. Computing standard deviation of log of per capita SDP for 14 major Indian states, the dispersion appears to have increased steadily from 0.22 in 1965-66 to 0.40 in 1994-95. A closer look at these values indicates that aggregate inequality did not rise much during the 1980s whereas there is a definite rise during the initial years of the 1990s. These results were also in conformity with Nagaraj et al (1998) that show the coefficient of variation of per capita SDP had tended to fall in the 1960s attributed largely to the impact of green revolution, especially in rural India. However the regional disparity shot up, more sharply in the 1970s, less markedly during the 1980s and continuing to grow during the first half of the 1990s. Similarly Sabyasachi Kar and S. Sakthivel (2007) too observe that regional inequality in India remained largely unchanged during the 1980s but rose dramatically after the adoption of the reforms. This is mainly due to the fact that the per capita output from the industrial and services sectors showed convergence before the reforms and divergence afterwards. 104 | P a g e Table: 6.1 Aggregate Regional Inequality in Indian Economy (1980-2010) Years Aggregate inequality Years Aggregate inequality Years Aggregate inequality 1980-81 .28 1990-91 .30 2000-01 .33 1981-82 .27 1991-92 .30 2001-02 .33 1982-83 .27 1992-93 .34 2002-03 .35 1983-84 .27 1993-94 .33 2003-04 .35 1984-85 .28 1994-95 .32 2004-05 .37 1985-86 .29 1995-96 .34 2005-06 .40 1986-87 .28 1996-97 .35 2006-07 .40 1987-88 .29 1997-98 .34 2007-08 .41 1988-89 .29 1998-99 .36 2008-09 .40 1989-90 .31 1999-00 .33 2009-2010 .41 Source: Calculated from the Data from CSO and CMIE. We find from the table that the aggregate inequality that remained almost unchanged (around .28) during the 1980s but showed a distinctly rising trend during the 1990s and 2000s (from .30 to .41). India has seen a constant rise in regional disparity from 1980 to 2010 followed by a slight fall in 1999-00 (from .36 to .33). Regional inequality dramatically increased in 1992 after the liberalization reforms started. On regional inequality there is an alternative theoretical literature that focuses on the increasing returns associated with the process of growth that may lead to regional divergence. This is the literature on agglomeration economies (Duranton and Puga 2004; Rosenthal and Strange 2004). The central proposition of this literature is that economic activities in general and industrial activity in particular, tend to be attracted to particular geographical locations that are already developed compared to other regions. The result of agglomeration economies is lead to urban concentration in these regions whose income and growth rates keep diverging from those in the peripheral. Glaeser et al (1992) and Henderson et al (1995) have focused on industrial growth in cities. Ciccone and Hall (1996) on the other hand, focus on the states of the US economy and explain their labour 105 | P a g e productivity in terms of measures of agglomeration economies like country level employment densities. Ciccone (2002) studies the same issue for the European economies and finds that the agglomeration effects are slightly smaller compared to the US economy. Dekle and Eaton (1999) in a study on Japanese prefectures find that for finance and manufacturing industries, there is evidence of agglomeration economies. These are some empirical literature that tests for agglomerating forces and their effects across regions. A particular strand of the agglomeration economies literature studies the impact of reforms on regional inequality. Going by Krugman and Livas Elizondo (1996) which is one of the earliest contributions to this literature which defines that there are two types of economic forces affecting regional inequality i.e. centripetal and centrifugal forces. Centripetal forces increase the concentration of manufacturing activity near large markets and hence lead to rising regional inequality while centrifugal forces push manufacturing activity to the periphery thereby decreasing regional inequality. These studies adopt the ‘new economic geography’ framework which assumes that there are economies of scale in production and that in a protected economy manufacturers produce mainly for the domestic market. The economies of scale warrant that production is located only in a few areas and in order to minimize the transport cost of production, these locations have to be close to large markets. On the other hand large markets are themselves created by those employed in the manufacturing locations. These factors together generate centripetal forces that lead to the development of a few regions while other regions fall behind, increasing the regional inequality in the economy. The authors Krugman and Livas Elizondo suggest that when trade is liberalized the centripetal forces become weaker because producers can now depend on external demand. Hence proximity to local markets becomes irrelevant, while the higher wages and land rent in the established markets act as centrifugal forces compelling them to relocate to less established regions. Thus trade reforms help to bring down the regional inequality in an economy. However this conclusion has been challenged by other contributions to this literature. Paluzie (2001) shows that if labour is mobile within the economy, then protectionist policies do not increase regional inequalities. Moreover, with trade reforms, established regions with some initial advantages may benefit more and hence regional inequality may go up. 106 | P a g e By studying the regional inequality among 16 major states of India during 1980-81 to 2009-10. The states selected for this study are Andhra Pradesh, Assam, Bihar, Gujarat, Haryana, Himachal Pradesh, Karnataka, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Odisha, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. Three newly formed states Namely Chattisgarh, Jharkhand and Uttranchal are taken from the time period 2000-01 to 2009-10. Before that in order to avoid complexities arising out of the re-organization of states data till 1999-2000 is used this is the last year from which data from the undivided states are available. Bihar, Madhya Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh, therefore refer to undivided states up till 1999-2000. These states together account for 91% population of India and the remaining 9% is spread in 13 smaller states and 7 Union territories including Delhi(GOI 2001). The GSDP and the population Data for this study are obtained from the Central Statistical organisation (CSO) and National Income Statistics Centre for Monitoring Indian Economy (CMIE).We cover statewise time series data on sectoral composition in percentages of GSDP as originating from agriculture, Industry and Services for each of the states at constant prices for all the years covering the data with four base years : 1980-81, 1993-94, 1999-2000 and 2004-05. The regional inequality is measured by the weighted coefficient of variation of the per capita income of these states. This measure is calculated as given below- 𝐶𝑉𝑤 = √∑ni(𝑦𝑖 − y ∗ )2 𝑃𝑖 𝑃 𝑦∗ Where:Yi is the per capita GSDP of ith region Y* refers to per capita GDP Pi is the population of ith state. P is the national population and n refers to number of states. 107 | P a g e Since the coefficient of variation is used to measure regional inequality, to decompose the aggregate inequality to show the sectoral contributions and similar changes in their trends a decomposition framework discussed in De Janvry and Sadoulet (2001) in used as they uses the same statistic to measure inequality, Let there be n regions such that the aggregate output of each region is given by Xi, i=1--------n, Let there be m sectors that contribute to each regions aggregate output Xi, such that the output of each sector in each region is given by Xij, i=1-----n, j=1-----m 1 Xi = Σj Xij Then Let X be the arithmetic mean of Xi and Xj be the arithmetic mean of Xij, Next define Pj as the ratio between the average outputs of the jth sector and the average output of the economy. Xj Pj = Thus 2 X Let C(Xi) be the coefficient of variation of aggregate output and let C(Xij) be the coefficient of variation of the jth sector’s output across regions. Also let rij, i be the correlation coefficient between the jth sector’s output and the aggregate output across regions. Then the percentage decomposition of total inequality is given by De Janvry and Sadoulet (2001). Σ j C(Xij) Pj x rij,i x C(Xi) Rearranging equation C(Xi) = Σ i =1 3 3 It can be written {C(Xij) x Pj x rij,i} 4 Equation 4 indicates that the aggregate inequality in an economy measured by the coefficient of variation of aggregate output across regions can be decomposed to give each sector’s contribution. Furthermore the contribution of each sector is equal to the product of108 | P a g e The inequality within the sector measured by the coefficient of variation of the services sector output across regions. The relative size of the services sector measured by the average output of the services sector as a proportion of the average output of the economy. The strength of the linkages between the services sector and the economy measured by the correlation coefficient between the services sector’s output across regions and the aggregate output across regions. This means that the contribution of services sector is equal to the product of intra sector inequality, the relative size of the sector and the strength of the linkages between the sector and the economy. The inequality for the aggregate economy is affected not only by the services sector’s inequalities but also by the relative size of the sector and their interlinkage with the economy. The interlinkages of services sector with the whole economy has an important role due to the fact that a high correlation between services sector and the economy implies that a region that has a relatively high output from that sector also has a relatively high aggregate output, while a region that has a relatively low output from that sector also has a relatively low aggregate output. This means that for a given level of inequality in the sector, an increase in the correlation coefficient increases the economy’s inequality. As far as the services sector is concerned, the reforms completely changed the trends in its contribution from the constant trends during the 1980s to the sharply increasing trends during the 1990s and 2000s. By looking at the trends in the values of the three factors that determine the sectoral contribution we can throw more light on this issue i.e. The coefficient of variation of the services sector. The relative size of the services section and The strength of the interlinkage between the services sector and the aggregate economy. 109 | P a g e Table: 6.2 Services sector’s contribution to Aggregate inequality and its component. Years Intrasector Relative size Interlinkage 1980-81 .32 .34 .90 Inequality 1981-82 .32 .34 .89 1982-83 .32 .35 .89 1983-84 .33 .34 .88 1984-85 .33 .35 .88 1985-86 .35 .35 .91 1986-87 .34 .37 .89 1987-88 .33 .38 .89 1988-89 .33 .36 .88 1989-90 .34 .37 .89 1990-91 .35 .37 .87 1991-92 .36 .38 .89 1992-93 .38 .38 .87 1993-94 .38 .39 .90 1994-95 .37 .38 .89 1995-96 .38 .40 .93 1996-97 .39 .40 .91 1997-98 .39 .41 .92 1998-99 .41 .42 .93 1999-00 .37 .46 .91 2000-01 .37 .47 .92 2001-02 .38 .48 .91 2002-03 .39 .49 .92 2003-04 .39 .48 .91 2004-05 .43 .48 .90 2005-06 .44 .48 .92 2006-07 .45 .49 .92 2007-08 .46 .49 .91 2008-09 .45 .51 .90 2009-10 .45 .52 .91 Source: Calculated from the Data from CSO and CMIE Sectoral .10 contribution .10 .10 .10 .10 .11 .11 .11 .10 .11 .11 .12 .12 .13 .12 .14 .14 .15 .16 .15 .16 .16 .17 .17 .18 .19 .20 .20 .21 .21 110 | P a g e Table 6.2 presents the breakup of the sectoral contribution in terms of intra sector inequality, relative size and interlinkages for the three decades. From the table we find that the services sector shows very interesting trends. It is clear that the contribution of services sector that remained almost constant in the pre reform period, there was a distinct rise in regional disparity in the post-reform periods. After the reforms the services sector contribution to rose quite sharply (from .10 to .21) resulting in the consistant rise in aggregate inequality throughout the 1990s (from .30 to .36) and 2000s (from .33 to .40). The only year for which the aggregate inequality as well as intra sector inequality shows a noteworthy dip (from .36 to .33) and (from .41 to .37) respectively is in the year 1999-00. The reason behind this sudden decline may be due to the lower growth rate between 1998-00 due to stagnation or negative growth of East Asia economies. Figure 6.1a Regional Inequality in India in 1980s.(Coefficient of Variation) 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 Aggregate Inequality Services sector Inequality 0.15 0.1 Contribution of Services Sector to Aggregate Inequality 0.05 0 111 | P a g e Figure- 6.1b Regional Inequality in India in 1990s.(Coefficient of Variation) 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 Aggregate Inequality 0.25 0.2 Services Sector Inequality 0.15 0.1 Contribution Of Services Sector to Aggregate Inequality 0.05 0 Figure- 6.1c Regional Inequality in India in 2000s (Coefficient of Variation) 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.35 Aggregate Inequality 0.3 0.25 Services Sector Inequality 0.2 0.15 0.1 Contribution of Service Sector to Aggregate Inequality 0.05 0 112 | P a g e The figure 6.1a, 6.1b and 6.1c shows the population weighted coefficient of variation for the three decades. It becomes clear from this figure that regional disparity remained largely unchanged during the 1980s but showed a distinctly a rising trend during the 1990s and 2000s. Since the trends remained largely unchanged during the 1980s the centripetal and the centrifugal forces balanced each other during this period. While the agglomeration economies provided the centripetal force, the centrifugal forces worked probably generated by the government’s efforts to achieve a spatially balanced growth by channelling development towards backward areas however in the 1990s and 2000s the rise in regional inequality clearly supports the hypothesis from Paluzie (2001) which predicts increasing regional disparity following reforms. This implies that the centripetal forces became stronger than the centrifugal forces during this period. This may have happened because the reforms weakened the centrifugal forces and strengthened the centripetal forces in the post reform period. It appears from the figures that (Figure 6.1a.1b and 1c) this pattern of changes in the services sector inequality seems to be in line with the changes in aggregate inequality. In the pre reform period, the government’s policies targeted to check regional divergence worked through multiple channels. One channel worked through the public sector, where sizeable parts of the public investment were made in relatively backward areas. The other channel worked through the private sector, which was encouraged through the use of fiscal incentives and industrial licensing to invest in these areas. In the other words the state played a crucial role in bringing down inequality in the services sector during this period. In the post reform period services sector shows the divergence due to a number of reasons:Generally the rate of investment is regarded as one of the most important factors explaining growth in any economy, and it is therefore appropriate to consider whether inter-state differences in growth are associated with differences in the rate of investment in individual states. It is very likely that in practice this led to a reallocation of investment in favour of states perceived as having better infrastructure facilities, better labour skills and work culture and a more investor friendly environment. This could lead to a substantial increase in investment in the better performing states and a consequent 113 | P a g e increase in their growth rate, with a corresponding reduction in investment in less well endowed or well governed states and a deceleration in their growth. The quality of infrastructure is also regarded as an essential determinant of growth in the states such as electric power, road and rail transportation, ports and airports and telecommunications. Good infrastructure not only increases the productivity of existing resources going into production and therefore helps growth, but also helps to attract more investment which can be expected to increase growth further. There could be several reasons for increasing regional inequality in India. One explanation could be that India is in early stage of development and therefore is on the wrong side of the “Inverted U” pattern of regional inequalities (Williamson, 1965). Another reason could be the relatively high barriers to interstate trade in India. A third reason could be the perverse nature of the central government’s regional development policies and the inter-governmental transfer system. Accelerated private investments also generate their multiplier effects on social development. Better quality educational and health facilities have been financed by the private sector which reduced the pressure on public facilities. More than 70 percent of the engineering graduates are coming out from the colleges of just four states viz.’ Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, Maharastra and Tamil Nadu. The IT boom in these states can be explained, to a large extend by the explosion of engineering education in these states. There has been a consistent rise in service exports, especially of software and computer related services since 1990s. Increase in service exports has been due to advancement in technology and trade liberalization. Since these facilities were mostly available in the relatively developed states in the western and the southern part of the country, this preference increased the regional inequality between these states and the poorer ones. Share of exports in the services sector rose from about 3.2 percent in 199091 to about 15.1 percent in the 2008-09 (Source: RBI Handbook of statistics). A major development in India's export scenario in recent decades has been a fast growth in export of services even during the period of crises in the global economy. 114 | P a g e The allocation of plan funds across the states has been made in accordance with the level of income of the states, that is the poorer states have been receiving proportionately larger amount of development funds relative to their richer counterparts, Such type of positive discrimination rising regional disparity may be the outcome of lower efficiency with which public capital is utilised and also of infrastructural disparity across the states. The industrial licensing system was dismantled as a part of the reforms, which also determined the location of investment gave the private sector the freedom to choose its location and minimise the transportation cost to large domestic market. The result was a shift of their production base to the metropolitan areas of the richer states, which covered most of the large domestic markets in the country. The manufacturing exports sector needed to minimise transportation costs to international markets and hence preferred to locate it near the coastal areas that had good infra structure. Since these facilities were mostly available in the relatively developed states in the western and the southern parts of the country this preference increased the regional inequality between these states and the poorer ones. 115 | P a g e Chapter-VII SUSTAINABILITY OF SERVICES SECTOR India’s emergence as one of the fastest growing economies in the 1990s is largely attributed to the rapid growth of its services sector. The services sector grew in this decade at an average of 7.9% per annum, far ahead of agriculture (3%) and manufacturing (5.2%). The contribution of services to gross domestic product (GDP) has been more than 50 % per annum since year 2000. The share of services sector in trade has also increased substantially. This growth has been accompanied by increasing foreign direct investment (FDI) approvals in services sector. Though these trends are mainly in line with global trends, two features are distinctive to India’s services sector. First, in the period 1950s to 1990s the share of agriculture in GDP declined by about 25 percentage points while industry and services sector gained equally. The share of industry in GDP has stabilized since 1990 and consequently the entire subsequent decline in the share of agriculture in GDP has been picked up by the services sector. This trend of rising share of services in GDP and corresponding decline in the share of agriculture and manufacturing sector is seen in the growth process of high-income countries and generally not in developing countries. During the 1990s, the contribution of the services sector to the growth of GDP in India was nearly 46% in comparison to 54% in middle-income countries and 43% in least developed countries. The contribution of the services sector to the growth of GDP in China was 34%. Secondly, employment in services has not been in proportion to their rising share in GDP and trade in India. Employment in services sector has been in proportion to their rising share in GDP in rest of the world. In 1999-2000 services contributed around 24% of employment in India. Services contributed to 30% in middle-income countries. It contributed 70% in Singapore and 116 | P a g e around 35% in Thailand. These features of India’s services-led growth cast doubts on its sustainability in the long run. Growth in India’s services sector has not been uniform across services. While some sectors experienced a double-digit growth rate like communication and business services some have experienced a fall in their growth rates like railways, real states and dwellings. The sector that have witnessed negative growth rates and those that have experienced slow growth rate are also the sectors that have large potentials for generating employment like construction, transport and professional services. Prime drivers of growth were business services. It grew by almost 20%, communication services grew by about 13.6%, banking services grew by about 13% and hotels and restaurants grew around 9%. Among the services witnessing a decline in growth were railways, dwellings and real estate, legal services, public administration and defence services. In terms of share in GDP the most important services are wholesale and retail trade at 14% followed by community services at 8.4% and banking and insurance services at 7%. Growth of employment differed significantly across services in the period 1994-2000 as compared to 1983-1994. Growth of employment fell in community, social and personal services from 3.85% to 2.08%. Fall in employment in this sector has important implications for employment potential of the entire services sector since this sector witnessed a rise in its growth and share in GDP in the 1990s. Other sectors where employment growth fell are electricity, gas and water supply. In 1999-00 the share of different services in employment was as follows: Trade, Hotels and Restaurants around 34% Community, Social and Personal Services around 31% Construction around 16% Transport, Storage and Communication Services around 13% The trends in employment elasticity of different services sectors have also changed considerably in the 1990s (Table 7.1). The trends show that employment elasticity in the economy declined sharply from 0.41 in the 1980s to 0.15 in the 1990s but it increased substantially in transport, storage and communication sectors. Employment 117 | P a g e elasticity has fallen in sectors that are growing faster and make a relatively higher contribution to GDP like community, social, personal services and financial services. Employment elasticity fell also in wholesale and retail trade, which provided maximum employment in the services sector. Table: 7. 1 Trends in employment elasticity and growth in employment. Employment Elasticity Sub-Sectors Trade Transport, Storage and Communication Financial Services Community Social Personal Services Total and 1983-84 1993-94 to to 1993-94 1999-00 0.63 Annual Growth in Employment (UPSS) (%) 1983-84 1994-00 0.55 3.57 5.04 0.49 0.69 3.24 6.04 0.92 0.73 7.18 6.20 0.50 0.07 2.90 0.55 0.41 0.15 2.04 0.98 Source: Government Of India, 2001. It is thus seen that though services have been the fastest growing sector in the last decade and have contributed more than 50% to GDP but still they provide less than 25% of total employment. Employment growth within the services sector has been uneven. Those services which have witnessed very high growth rates like business and communications services have a low share in GDP or employment. Employment elasticity has declined in most of the services with significant share in GDP like trade, community services and banking and insurance in the latter half of the 1990s. This growth has three plausible explanations. First, sectors that have large potential for generating employment like construction transport and professional services have grown slowly. Faster growing sectors like services, communications and financial business services have a low potential for employment generation. In addition, employment elasticity has declined in the fast growing services like financial and 118 | P a g e community services. The rising productivity levels in the faster growing services themselves may be a reason for lack of growth in their employment potential. Because of the difficulty in measuring their output there are only few studies which have estimated productivity growth in services. One of these studies, by McKinsey & Co. (2001) estimates labour productivity in six segments of India’s services sector namely: Telecommunication Software Retail banking Housing Construction Energy distribution and retail distribution It finds that software services have the highest productivity levels followed by telecommunication, banking, and construction. These are also services that are growing faster and have high shares in GDP and employment. Higher labour productivity in these segments may have slowed down growth in employment in services. Communication and software services have witnessed an increase in their trade and therefore have grown substantially but they have a small employment potential. Therefore we can say that trade liberalization in services has not helped in generating large employment. Services sector growth studies by Gordon and Gupta (2004) and Banga and Goldar (2004) empirically assess the reasons for the growth of India’s services sector in the 1990s conclude that both demand and supply factors have led to this growth. On the demand side the high growth of services output was mostly attributed to factors such as increasing input usage of services by other sectors, mainly manufacturing sector (higher domestic demand); higher foreign demand due to trade liberalization and high income elasticity for services. On the supply side, the increased trade in services following trade liberalization policies and other reforms in the 1990s induced this growth. On the demand side Banga and Goldar (2004) show that the contribution of services input to output growth in manufacturing (organized) was about 1% in the 1980s and it increased to about 25% in the next decade. Gordon and Gupta (2004) show 119 | P a g e that the use of services sector input to industry increased by about 40% between 1979-80 and 1993-94. The role of elastic final demand for services is difficult to measure since it is difficult to split the growth in private final consumption expenditure into expenditure on goods and that on services. They use a rough estimate and conclude that there has been a sharp growth in the final demand for services in the 1990s. On the supply side, the percentage share of exports of services vis-à-vis merchandise exports in GDP has steadily risen. The share of services in trade increased to 24.9% in 1998 from 19.3% in 1995. Services that contributed substantially to India’s exports in the early 1990s were transport, travel, communication and financial services. However, the composition of India’s exports of services has changed over the years. In the period 1990-95 and 1996-2002 the relative share of travel in exports has fallen from 39% to 23% and of transportation services from 24% to 15%. In contrast the share of software services has risen sharply from 34% to 60%. In fact, India has become a net foreign exchange earner in total services after 1997-98. Net foreign exchange earning services are mainly travel, communication and software services. India is a net importer in services like transport, management and financial services. Thus, the growth of India’s services sector may be attributed to: Structural changes that have led to increase in usage of services by other sectors. Trade liberalization in services. Other reforms carried out in the 1990s. India’s services sector has witnessed tremendous growth in the last ten years but its employment potential has not grown proportionately. There has been no corresponding growth in manufacturing which is one of the largest consumers of services. This has cast doubts on the sustainability of services-led growth. Services that have increased their share in GDP and trade have small employment potential and their employment elasticity has fallen due to rising labour productivity. One possible reason for this lopsided growth in services is lack of a coherent policy with respect to services. Reforms at the sectoral level have evolved in an ad-hoc uneven manner due to lack of an 120 | P a g e integrated services policy. Liberalizing a particular service like retail trade will fall short of the desired impact if it is not supported by liberalization in real estate. Similarly, reforms in tourism will remain half measures unless corresponding reforms are undertaken in domestic air travel. Due to the large externalities of services it is important to provide services as efficiently as possible. The three services having the largest backward and forward linkages are trade, transport and construction. Transport (road, railways and air) and construction services have large external economies and linkages but in India these two sectors have been slow-growing. Improving these infrastructure facilities will not only enhance the country’s attractiveness to foreign investment but also improve the competitiveness of domestic investment. These sectors also have large potential for generating employment. Trade in services can suffer from both external and domestic constraints. External constraints or trade barriers are mainly in the form of limits on foreign equity participation, recognition, licensing of provisions, immigration, labour market regulations and discriminatory treatment with respect to taxes, subsidies and other policies. Domestic constraints may result from infrastructure inadequacies, poor quality and standards, lack of clear-cut responsibilities between central and state governments and other policy-related disincentives. Given the large potential for trade in these services there is a need for specific policies and they should be designed to encourage trade in health and education sectors. In particular, given the low-cost quality treatment available in India there is a large scope for health tourism. India also has a competitive advantage in the practice of alternative medicine. These areas should be developed and exploited for trade opportunities. Since the health sector is on the concurrent list a number of regulations are imposed by the state governments. Though there is no cap on FDI in health services still the share of health services in total trade and FDI remains low (only 0.4% of FDI approvals in health). There is a need to have a clear-cut demarcation of responsibilities of Centre and State in this sphere. To improve trade in education services there is a need to study the system of regulation and accreditation of educational institutions in foreign countries and accordingly develop own accreditation system. To compete successfully with the existing reputed educational testing services such as GRE, GMAT and TOFEL, our reputed testing services such as CAT, GATE, JEE and others must upgrade and 121 | P a g e modernise. There is also a need to improve on educational database regarding number of educational institutions, their enrolments (domestic and foreign), faculty strength, financial sources and quality and accreditations. There are services that are less than moderately liberalized or are restricted with high external trade barriers and low growth like legal professional services, accountancy and rail transport. These services also have a low share in exports, which reflects both domestic and external constraints to their trade. On the whole, infrastructure services like transport and construction are slow growing and have a low share in trade in spite of the efforts to lower external trade barriers to them. In other words high domestic constraints impede their growth and trade. In contrast, the financial infrastructure of India appears to be stronger and services like software, banking, insurance and telecommunications show low external trade barriers and high growth rates with high to moderate share in total exports. Health and education have experienced high growth rates and have a large potential for trade. In trade liberalization of services the social costs involved also need to be considered. This is particularly relevant for the Indian economy given the employment dimension of the services sector. An argument put forward against trade liberalization in services is the displacement of labour towards sectors where an economy has competitive advantage. If these sectors lack large employment potential trade can lead to growth in unemployment. Some of the services that have traditionally been under the public sector like railways have surplus labour. Higher extent of trade liberalization in these sectors might result in large displacement of labour. Similar concerns also apply to sectors like retail distribution which employs a large number of unskilled labour. Displacement of labour in these sectors might cause considerable social unrest. There is utmost importance to have a coherent and integrated services policy which is analogous to the industrial policy and agricultural policy resulting in systematic reforms in different services. Liberalization has to be in a phased manner accompanied by social policies in sectors that have surplus labour like retail and wholesale trade and railways. Full gains of trade liberalization in services will follow only if certain economywide efforts are made to make the general environment more conducive to trade and 122 | P a g e investments in services. Macroeconomic policies like high tariff rates, large fiscal deficits, and rigid labour laws adversely affect the competitiveness of services. Economywide efforts to improve the business environment and removing domestic constraints sustain the dynamism of India’s services sector. Since the late 1980s much discussion has been taking place to assess whether the service led growth of the Indian economy is sustainable or not. Bhattacharya and Mitra (1990) stated that the deviation in growth rates of the three sectors may have negative impact on inflation, balance of payments and income distribution. Since there are strong linkages from services to industry the growth in manufacturing sector will give an impetus to services. To enhance growth synergies among sectors relatively stronger growth of services sector is undesirable as the input demand of services sector is industry intensive rather than agriculture intensive (Kaur, Bordoloi and Rajesh 2009). Growth in the manufacturing sector is also desirable for trade balance and employment generation (Papola 2005). India must develop its manufacturing whose multiplier effect and impact on job creation are significant to meet the challenges of demographic profile and reduce poverty (Li & Yang, 2008). One of the critical issues that have been discussed in the literature is the role played by services in the growth process. Though, a forceful case is put forward that services can become the major driving force of economic growth but in case of India the sustainability of a service-led growth has been questioned by many (e.g., Mitra 1988, Bhattacharya and Mitra 1990 and Arunachalam and Kumar 2002). It has been argued that income from the service sector is growing much in excess of the demand generated for services by the commodity sector and since income might grow faster than employment in the organised services therefore service-led growth can have serious implications for inflation, income distribution and balance of payments. It is argued that this growth is not sustainable in the long run. This argument becomes stronger since economic theory suggests that a decline in the share of agriculture sector and manufacturing sector is a phenomenon that is generally associated with the growth process of a high-income economy and not a developing country. 123 | P a g e To test the issue of sustainability of service-led growth in India Gordon and Gupta (2004) attempts to find out whether India is an outlier in this case by using cross-country data on sectoral shares in GDP and fitting a trend line. They find that the share of service sector in GDP is associated positively with per capita income. The countries with higher per capita income also have a larger share of services in GDP. In case of India they find that in 1990 share of India’s service sector in GDP was very close to the average share predicted by the linear relationship. By 2001 India’s share of services moved above the average share by as much as 5 percentage points as a result of rapid growth of services in India. In spite of this they do not find India to be an outlier at present. They argue that if different sectors in India grow at the average growth rates experienced in 1996-2000 then by 2010 the share of services would increase to 58 percent. This would bring size of India’s services sector relative to GDP closer to that of an upper middle income country even though India would still belong to the low income group. Hansda (2001) addresses the issue of sustainability of service-led growth of India in terms of inter-sectoral linkages as emanating from input-output tables for 1993-94 for 115 activities at the disaggregated level. The results indicate that while services and agriculture do not share much inter-dependence. Industry is found to be most serviceintensive with 70% of its activities being direct services-intensive. The inter-sectoral linkages are explored further by estimating Rasmussen indices of backward and forward linkages. The indices show that service sector is more growth-inducing as compared to other sectors in terms of backward and forward linkages. He therefore argues that growth in service sector will induce growth in other sectors such as trade, transport and construction. These sectors are found to have high domestic constraints and therefore require immediate policy reforms. Adequate infrastructure facilities will not only enhance the country’s attractiveness to foreign investment but will also improve competitiveness of domestic investment. Since these sectors have large potential for generating employment. Growth in these sectors will also help in resolving the dilemma of jobless growth in the services sector. Most of these services still have considerable restrictions on FDI limits. Emphasis should be now laid in improving growth of these services by reducing external as well as domestic constraints, which have been identified by the specialised studies. 124 | P a g e Some economists caution that if the service sector bypasses the industrial sector then economic growth can be distorted. They say that service sector growth must be supported by proportionate growth of the industrial sector; otherwise the service sector growth will not be sustainable. It is true that in India the service sector’s contribution in GDP has sharply risen. The service sector has grown at a higher rate than industry which too has grown more or less in tandem. The rise of the service sector therefore does not distort the economy. The issue of sustainability of services growth, i.e., whether the lack of rise in the share of manufacturing sector and the corresponding shift to services is sustainable or not is further examined by Banga and Goldar (2004). In this regard the study estimates the impact of higher use of services input on productivity growth of manufacturing sector. They construct a multilateral total factor productivity index for 41 major industry groups for the period 1980-81 to 1999-00. Regressing the total factor productivity index on a set of explanatory variables including the ratio of services input to employment, the study finds a positive relationship between use of services input and industrial productivity. Their results show that the increase in use of services in manufacturing in the 1990s has favourably affected productivity in the manufacturing sector. In the light of this result the study argues that India’s service sector will be successful in creating its own demand since higher use of services in the manufacturing sector has not only lead to higher output growth in manufacturing sector but also improved productivity in the manufacturing sector. It can therefore be said that India’s experience with respect to service-led growth may be unique but it cannot be regarded as an outlier as yet. Growth in services is found to be growth inducing and has led to higher productivity in the manufacturing sector in the 1990s and therefore it is possible for the service sector to sustain its growth. However, more research is required in this field to reach to any firm conclusions. It is emphasised that the ‘service economy’ is structurally different from economic system from the previous era of mass industrial production but it is crucial to note that the structural change does not necessarily imply that services become more important in final consumption. Services become ever more crucial to co-ordinate and control production processes of differentiated consumer products that are subject to economies of scale. Increased expenditure on producer services also enhances the efficiency of production by 125 | P a g e allowing higher level of specialisation in production. It can be derived that services are becoming more and more crucial to the growth process of an economy. They can not only sustain their own growth process but can also improve the growth rate of manufacturing sector by improving the efficiency of production. Indian economy has been undergoing structural changes that generally accompany economic development over a longer period since independence. Acceleration in growth rate gave an impetus to these changes during the 1980’s and they have taken place at a faster rate in the post‐reforms period. The major characteristics of growth over the last three decades which distinguishes it from the experience of the earlier three decades consist not only a significantly higher rate but also few other important departures from the earlier pattern. Emergence of services as the major contributor to growth in GDP and eventually as the predominant sector of the economy is one such feature. Growing importance of the external sector with rapid growth both of imports and exports is another feature. Decline in the share of agriculture in GDP, which has been taking place in earlier decades as well took place at a much faster rate. Employment content of growth has seen a steep decline during this period. There is the question whether the growth with the current structural characteristics will at all be sustainable in the medium and long run. It is commonly feared that economic growth primarily derived from services may not be sustainable in a developing country without attaining a significant degree of industrialisation. India has registered a reasonably high growth over a rather long period primarily sustained by services growth. Whether this could continue in future would depend on the composition of growing services in terms of whether they contribute to the capacity of the economy to develop especially in the commodity producing sectors of agriculture and industry. Growth in services has led to higher use of services in manufacturing sector. This has in turn led to higher output and productivity growth in the manufacturing sector which implies that the service sector will be able to generate its own demand in the future. Studies also show that the growing dynamism of India’s service sector is to a large extent due to growing external markets for services and the gradual though partial liberalisation of domestic economy. Most of the studies on the Indian economy support 126 | P a g e the view that domestic reforms and higher liberalisation in terms of lowering of barriers to trade and allowing FDI have improved growth in the corresponding services. This increased external demand may also play an important role in sustaining the dynamism of services. To resolve the problem of lack of employment growth in services there is a need to achieve uniformity in the growth of different services. This becomes even more important if we consider the interdependency of different services. An important aspect of services is the ability to generate sizable external economies or diseconomies that are not reflected in the price signals. Also, closely linked is the problem of linkages, both backward and forward, with the rest of the economy and with its growth rate. Inefficiencies in services therefore can exert a multiplying effect on the economy as a whole and efficiency in providing services can make a considerable difference to the sectoral growth rates. For achieving higher efficiency in financial services like banking and insurance we need efficient IT-related services. One of the probable reasons for lopsided growth in services is the fact that reforms in India at the sectoral level have evolved in an ad-hoc way. There has been no coherent overall policy for services in line with the industrial policy and agricultural policy. Consequently the depth and pace of reforms lack uniformity across sectors. Along with the national and international efforts to liberalise trade India also needs to undertake some domestic reforms like institutional and regulatory reforms so as to maximise the benefits of higher trade and FDI in services. Assessment of performance of India’s different services shows that there exists some services which have low external barriers and high growth rate but these services have not been able to enjoy a suitable share in India’s exports of services. We find that health and education sectors have high potential for trade since they have low external barriers and high growth rates. This indicates substantial domestic constraints in these services. With respect to slow growing services which have low share in exports like professional services, legal, postal and accountancy etc. We find that these services have restricted liberalisation. Both external and domestic constraints restrict growth in these services. Some of the important external and domestic constraints that have been 127 | P a g e identified by specialised studies and which need to be removed are: With respect to legal services, many of the domestic policies need to be altered. For example, the Indian law which prohibits formation of partnership with enrolled professionals of foreign countries in legal services limits the scope for an Indian firm to build its capacity to advice on foreign law or international law or in a newly developed area. This needs to be suitably altered. Prohibition on partnership with multi-disciplinary knowledge prevents capacity building in areas where technology progresses beyond comprehension of lawyer. Restrictions on joint ventures or establishment of firms in India by foreigners should therefore be relaxed but since this would be a major reform strategically it would be better to delay it by few years. In accountancy services, India does not yet have large firms with international visibility. There is a need to embrace international accounting standards and reporting requirements. The process of adoption should be treated as urgent and concomitant changes should be undertaken in domestic statutory legislation. Though there exists a strong case for trade liberalisation of services one should not forget that growth is not the sole objective of an economy. Therefore social costs of trade liberalisation of services should also be considered. For the Indian economy this issue becomes even more relevant given the employment dimension of services sector. Services sector in 1999-2000 employed almost 68 percent of urban employment. One of the arguments that is put forward against trade liberalisation is displacement of labour towards sectors where an economy has competitive advantage. However some of the services sectors that have traditionally been under public sector like railways, postal services etc. are saddled with excessive labour and higher trade liberalisation in these sectors might result in large displacements of labour. Similar concerns are also found in sectors like retail distribution sector that employs large number of unskilled labour. Displacement of labour in these sectors might cause lot of social unrest. Trade liberalisation in these sectors therefore must be undertaken in a phased manner accompanied by appropriate policies to curb unemployment. Thus trade liberalisation policies have to be supported by complementary social policies so as to avoid substantial social costs that might undermine the support for reforms. 128 | P a g e Limited empirical research exists in the area of services in India. What remains the biggest hurdle in future research on trade and investment in services is the lack of reliable, timely and easily interpretable data. The data that is more widely available do not currently encompass all forms of trade in services, in particular intra-firm trade in services is not recorded. What is required is trade data on services at a more disaggregated level which is consistent with value-added and employment data and is comparable across time. Efforts should therefore be made to develop a suitable database for furthering empirical research in this field. There is a dire need to formulate an Index of Services in order to have a coherent policy on services. Appropriate measures to estimate output in services need to be identified and by attaching suitable weights to disaggregated services, index for services can be formulated. Given the heterogeneity of services formulation of separate indices can also be considered. Along with the above policy insights it must be kept in mind that full gains of trade liberalisation in services can be acquired by an economy only if certain economy-wide efforts are made to make general environment more conducive to trade and investments in services. Macroeconomic policies like high tariff rates, large fiscal deficits and rigid labour laws may have as adverse effect on competitiveness of services as on goods. Excessive regulations, discretion in the allocation of licenses and permits, corruption and poor quality of infrastructure could adversely affect the growth of services sector. Studies have shown that business environment in India is not very competitive as compared to other developing countries (Dollar and Goswami 2002). The regulatory and administrative burdens are considerably high and so are the labour market restrictions. This points to the need for regulation in services which arises primarily from market failures attributable to natural monopoly and inadequate consumer information. Strong and financially independent regulators and economy-wide efforts to improve business environment can go a long way to sustain the dynamism of India’s services sector. 129 | P a g e Chapter-VIII CONCLUSION The trends in regional disparities in India over a period of 30 years have been examined and there are wide variations in economic performances of states and the differences have only increased over time. Economic reforms have not delivered on employment front as much as they have delivered on the GDP front. Level of change in employment has not been as large as in GDP. Services have increased their share in GDP from 36 percent in 1972-73 to 45 percent in 1993-94. It further rose to 59 percent in 2009-10 but the corresponding increase in employment share has been much slower from 15 percent in 1972-73 to 21 percent in 1993-94 and to 27 percent in 2009-10. Continuation of this pattern of structural changes has serious implications not only for equity but also for the sustainability of a high growth rate as well. Growth of services sector has been more uneven and has been generally higher in the better developed states, particularly during 2000s thus resulting in increasing divergence among states in their levels of economic development. The rise in regional inequality during the 1990s and 2000s is largely due to a sharp rise in inequality in the services sectors. The rising relative size and interlink ages of services sectors with the economy also contributed to rising inequality in this period. In the absence of adequate growth in other sectors of the economy, the services sector in the long run would be adversely affected by demand constraints and its performance would then depend upon the uncertainly in demand from the rest of the world through exports. The process of growth is accompanied by dual skill over effects i.e. growth in manufacturing sector improves growth in service sector since it creates additional demand for services which arises due to structural changes that makes contracting out cheaper and more efficient for manufacturing sector's growth. Services sector, in turn leads to higher growth in manufacturing sector since it to leads to higher demand for new products and brings about improvement in productivity of manufacturing sector. Also as production of services requires inputs from other sectors, 130 | P a g e there could be supply constraints due to slowdown in the growth of productive capacity in the rest of the economy. It is found that inter-state disparities in rates of GSDP growth increased during the 1990s over 1980s. In the period after 2000 while some of the poorer state have experienced a faster than average growth but growth of some of the developed states has slowed down during this period. Although it is still much higher than it was before the reforms. Inter-state variations in rates of GSDP growth are found to be strongly associated with the pace of services growth during 1980 to 2010. A high aggregate growth rate is generally accompanied by increasing disparity. A deregulated policy regime can lead to an increase in disparities as the developed regions have a competitive advantage and government policies favouring poorer regions are no longer in operation on the one hand while on the other hand disparities may also decline as the regions get opportunities to freely utilise their comparative advantage. Accelerating economic growth is closely linked to growth in service sector of the Indian economy at the present juncture is receiving greater attention. It is therefore very important for an economy to provide services as efficiently as possible and this may require not only increasing investments in services but also continuously improving on them through improved technology and many of the developing countries that are undertaking domestic reforms in their service sector and liberalising services do not have a well integrated policy for the sector. The opportunities in this fast growing employment-oriented, FDI attracting sector, with vast export-potential are striking. Keeping in mind the importance of services in the growth process, it is essential to have a well-defined service policy in line with agriculture and industrial policies. Reforms in services should therefore be an outcome of well-integrated policy for services and should be undertaken in segmental manner maintaining the balance between growth of different services sector because the sustainability of a relatively high GDP growth of the recent years driven by growth of the services sector alone would be difficult to maintain over a long horizon. The Indian states had strong tendencies to diverge in per capita income over the period. An important finding is that the rate of divergence has increased considerably 131 | P a g e during the post-reform period relative to the pre-reform one. This signifies that the ongoing economic reforms since 1991 have led to an increase in the regional disparities in income. The states were moving only towards their differing steady-state income levels. Hence it may be argued that the observed differences in per capita incomes have been due to dispersion in the steady-state levels among the states, which was found to be due to differences in production structures and physical, social and economic infrastructure among them. The results suggest that economic policy measures for improving physical, social and economic infrastructure can have significant effect on long-run growth potential as well as convergence across states. Since the observed divergence in per capita income across the states have been due to variations in their steady-states targeting public investment in infrastructure for the states with lower steady-state levels could improve overall growth performance and reduce regional imbalance. Unless appropriate steps are taken to correct disparities in the spread of infrastructure through regional policies and inter-governmental transfers, divergence in per capita incomes across states will continue to widen. The existing policy of transferring proportionately larger amount of funds to relatively poorer states appears to be in the right direction. Efficient utilization of these funds by the states for infrastructural development could help in a great way to improve their overall growth performance and reduce regional disparities in development. The ongoing economic reforms that have led to an increase in regional disparities in income need appropriate modification if the policy makers are really interested in reducing regional disparities in development in the country. The acceleration in the growth of the services sector in India was due to fast growth in communications, banking services, business service, IT and community services. The remaining sectors grew at a constant or trend growth rate. The challenges in this area are to retain India's competitiveness in those sectors where it has already made a mark such as IT and ITES and Telecommunications. Their deeper and broader use in the domestic sectors would also have potential to increase the efficiency and productivity of other goods and services. The globally traded services such as financial services, health care, education accountancy and other business services, where India has a large 132 | P a g e domestic market but only a very small part of the full potential has been tapped so far. Regulatory improvements will also be important as many domestic regulations and market access barriers could come in the way of fully tapping this growth accelerating sector. The challenges also lies in making inroads into some traditional areas such as tourism and shipping where other countries have already established themselves but where the potential for India is nevertheless very high. Since there are diverse sectors within services, the issues and policies cannot be separated into water tight compartment. These challenges and issues could further strengthen the services sector which is the driving force for India to realize double digit growth potential both overall and at state level, while providing more and better job to help achieve more inclusive and balanced growth. Services are looked at sceptically in our country and it is claimed that they are no more than add on to manufacturing. This conventional attitude needs to be changed for good. In the US the share of manufacturing in GDP is around 23 per cent and share of services is more than 70 per cent. It is also reflected in employment pattern. Future investment and job creation in India will not be driven mainly by manufacturing. Indeed manufacturing may yield relatively few jobs in our country. Its result being companies can triple production without hiring a single new worker but a huge number of jobs will be created in service industries. It will also soak up the bulk of investment. There are some universal trends in employment patterns which we cannot afford to ignore. Newer technologies will need fewer people in manufacturing. On the other hand more jobs will be created in services, sub-contracting and unorganized sector. Traditional trade demarcations may not have the same place in a modern economy. Flexibility in operations is needed and knowledge will be required for employees. There is no doubt that a large number of illiterate and semi-literate workers in our industry will face problems as a result of it. There will be increase in the requirement of part time and temporary workers. Activities will get specialized and a large number of specialized vendors and sub-contractors will constitute manufacturing networks. As location of industries will no longer be decided by the government and will be based on economic choices so employees will have to be prepared for relocation. 133 | P a g e Industry clusters will emerge and all areas will not get equal investment or equal job opportunities. Indian industrialists will be very unwise to focus on manufacturing alone in given scenario. Government needs to shift its thinking to create institutional structures that encourage private investment in services and remove road blocks and delays. These steps will create far more jobs than public sector investment. In response to the declining share of agriculture in national income, a shift in the occupation of the rural population away from agriculture and towards those sectors that are growing most rapidly will have to be encouraged. Such an occupational shift from agriculture to services has already started. But the proportion of the work force in agriculture is still far greater than the proportion of agriculture in the national income. Obviously, greater attention is to be paid in managing the shift from an agricultural economy to one that is dominated by services. The growth of services such as those related to tourism or transport in the rural areas can be supported by families who find the returns from agriculture inadequate. Steps would have to be taken to increase the potential of the rural population to benefit from the growth of services. The handicap of an inadequate awareness of technology would need to be overcome by not only increasing the availability of education in rural areas but also ensuring that it overcomes the requirements of modern services. Effective instruments will also need to be created to pool rural capital so as to enable investment in high technology services, including linking up directly with global financial and communication networks. Such a transition may not be very smooth but certainly not impossible if preferred steps are undertaken with a vision for future development. The study bears several important policy implications in designing an appropriate growth strategy. It highlights that the sustainability of a relatively high GDP growth in recent years driven by growth of the services sector alone would be difficult to maintain over a long horizon. This is because in the absence of adequate growth in other sectors of the economy, the services sector in the long run would be adversely affected by demand constraints and its performance would then depend upon the uncertainty in demand from the rest of the world through exports. Also, as production of services requires input from other sectors, there could be supply constraints due to slow down in the growth of 134 | P a g e production capacity in the rest of the economy (Rakshit 2000). Storm (1997) arrives at a similar conclusion that if a step up in manufacturing exports is to contribute to noninflationary acceleration of GDP growth; it needs to be supplemented by adequate policies aimed at raising agricultural output. A critical problem facing India’s economy is the sharp and growing regional variations among India’s different states in terms of poverty, availability of infrastructure and socio-economic development. Four low-income states namely Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, Odisha and Uttar Pradesh are more than one third of India’s population. Severe disparities exist among states in terms of income, literacy rates, life expectancy and living conditions. The five-year plans, especially in the pre-liberalization era attempted to reduce regional disparities by encouraging industrial development in the interior regions and distributing industries across states but the results have not been very encouraging since these measures. It in fact increased inefficiency and hampered effective industrial growth. After liberalization, the more advanced states have been better placed to benefit from them, with well developed infrastructure and an educated and skilled work force which attract the manufacturing and service sectors. The governments of backward regions are trying to reduce disparities by offering tax holdings, cheap land and focusing more on sectors like tourism which although being geographically and historically determined can become a source of growth and develops faster than other sectors. The government should take steps to develop the informal segment especially that in the tertiary sector as in the Report of Special Group on Employment Generation 2002. In 1999-2000 only 8.34 per cent of the total labour force was employed in the organized sector and the remaining 91.66 per cent was absorbed in the unorganized sector. Besides it there is sufficient empirical evidence which indicates that a large segment of informal sector workers are employed in tertiary activities. As Mitra’s (1994) study shows, in around 70 per cent of the Class I cities i.e. each with a population of 1,00,000 and above, tertiary activities accounted for more than 60 per cent of the informal sector. Further Hemmer and Mannel (1989) and Sithuraman (1981) also found that 75 per cent of the informal sector was located in tertiary activities by adopting sector specific strategies 135 | P a g e because employment generation through this sector is also the least cost option (ILO 1991). If the services sector is properly developed along with the other two important and basic sectors the existing strong complementarily amongst the three sectors will increase in the near future, it can become instrumental in employment generation and individual prosperity as it combines the multiple sectors of technology and manufacture. The introduction of newer technologies necessitates skill up gradation in all three sectors, which would further accelerate the growth of the services sector. The agriculture sector might witness more intense use of IT than what it is doing now, be it in the use of remote sensing through satellite for regular monitoring of crops, social conditions, water resources, weather forecasts through satellites and ground borne systems or in the use of modern communications to be in contact with markets. Similarly in the industrial sector the reorientation of skills from a lower to a higher level will became almost a necessity with the use of sensors, modern electronics and IT. Consequently the growth of skilled and professional services would alleviate the acute problem of the educated unemployed. Former President Abdul Kalam and YS Rajan (1998) highlight the complementarity of the three sectors in the following words:“A country like India cannot hope to build its future on the services sector alone though it can be and will be a major component of the economy. India cannot afford not to build its strengths in agriculture for reasons of food and nutritional security nor can it afford to ignore manufacturing strengths for reason of economic and national security. Based on the strength of these two sectors it can build a major economic infrastructure for the services sector and use it to generate great wealth and employment for her people.” In India the distribution of natural resources has itself created large severely underdeveloped regions in the country which have been recently brought into sharp focus. The problem needs to be addressed by well thought out strategies including deliberate transfer of resources to underdeveloped regions. This is vital because proper grants of all regions of the country are essential for its prosperity in terms of political and social systems and for the economic viability of the nation itself. 136 | P a g e Like other developing countries India also suffers from the acute and explosive problem of regional imbalances. The first three Five Year Plans were directed towards achieving the objective of higher growth rates. Scarcity of resources and efficiency of investment often made it imperative for decision makers to concentrate developmental efforts in those segments of the economy and those regions of the country where the rates of return were expected to be high. This type of implementation of planned development programmes resulted in widening regional imbalances in the levels of development and in strengthening of the dualistic structure of economy. Despite robust economic growth, India continues to face many major problems. The recent economic development has widened the economic inequality across the country. Despite sustained high economic growth rate approximately 80% of its population lives on less than $2 a day (PPP). Even though the arrival of Green Revolution brought an end to famines in India and 40% children under the age of three are underweight and a third of all men and women suffer from chronic energy deficiency. Organized retail has the potential for reducing inefficiencies and improving the productivity of the retail sector. Studies have shown that in the US, organized retail contributed one-fourth of the rise in productivity growth in the period 1995–99. However, in India organized retail is less than 4% of the total retail sector. It is expected that organized retail by forming linkages with the agriculture sector can lead to productivity growth. Working with organized retail can encourage farmers to improve yields by enabling them to obtain quality supplies, adopt superior farm technology and practices, access timely credit at reasonable rates and bypass unproductive intermediaries. The tieup with organized retail may drive small/medium enterprises to become more efficient in order to meet the stringent delivery conditions of the retail market. Private labelling is the creation of brands in the name of modern retailers, and it has already begun in India in the food and grocery and apparel segments and is expected to expand rapidly. Small-scale manufacturers will be the major beneficiaries of private labels. Retail services, if they become more organized have the potential for improving not only their own productivity but also the productivity of other sectors especially agriculture, which is marked by low productivity growth. In order to increase the size of 137 | P a g e the organized sector and to encourage people to shift from unorganized retailing to organized retailing, the following policy directions should be considered: The retail sector in India is severely constrained by the limited availability of bank finance. Suitable lending policies need to be designed that will enable retailers in the unorganized sectors to expand, employ better technology, and improve efficiencies. Policies that encourage unorganized sector retailers to migrate to the organized sector by investing in space and equipment should be encouraged. The government must actively encourage the setting up of co-operative stores to procure and stock commodities from small producers. This will address the dual problem of limited promotion and marketing ability, as well as market penetration, for the retailer. The government can also facilitate the setting up of warehousing units and cold chains, thereby lowering capital costs for small retailers. With 3.6 million shops retailing food and employing 4% of the total workforce, the food-retailing segment presents a focused opportunity for the government to catalyze growth and employment. Provision of training in handling, storing, transporting, grading, sorting, maintaining hygiene standards, maintaining refrigeration equipment, packing, etc. is an area where the government can play a proactive role. This could give a substantial boost to the productivity of this sector. Quality regulation, certification, and price administration bodies should be created at district and lower levels for the upgrade of the technical and human interface in the rural to urban supply chain. Competition generates productivity. Calibrated and gradual exposure to competition may lead to productivity spill over effects as domestic organized retailers learn ways of building effective supply chains from the foreign retailers. Some competition has already been induced by the government by allowing entry to foreign firms selling single-brand products. However, domestic organized retailers need to acquire a threshold size to have productivity gains from 138 | P a g e competition. Incentives to increase the size of domestic retail firms need to be designed. To sustain the growth of software services, targeted policies and strategies are needed. The sector is already at the frontier of the world and there is a need to capitalize on the gains that growing domestic and external demands offer. The following are some recommendations for sustained improvements for productivity growth: With the changing global situation, especially after the slowdown in the growth rate of advanced countries, the nature of demand for software services (especially IT-BPO) has also begun to change. A recent National Association of Software and Services Companies–Everest research report shows that the outsourcing needs of buyers are changing with companies focusing on value drivers (integrated delivery models offering scale and value and speedy implementation), minimizing risks, and re-evaluating the sourcing model (re-thinking captive versus supplier mix, evolving risk-reward relationships with vendors, and opting for outcome-based pricing). It is important for IT-BPO services providers to build a strong and unmatched value proposition for themselves in specific, focused, niche segments. Super-specialization segments now need to be explored. Policy incentives need to be built for encouraging IT-BPO services to enter such specialty segments. IT-BPO services are not only increasing their depth by entering super-specialty segments, they are also increasing in width by bringing new areas into their ambit, e.g., legal process outsourcing, clinical research outsourcing, mobile applications, energy efficiency, and climate change. These are new areas that require massive investments and knowledge creation. It is recommended that the government takes initiative and encourages IT firms to enter these areas by creating policy incentives. Along with entering new segments and climbing up the value-chain, what is also needed for the sustained productivity growth of the sector is innovation. In line with providing incentives for R&D activities for the manufacturing sector, the government should also focus on developing incentives for innovations in IT 139 | P a g e services. Collaborative research between industry, academia, and government needs to be encouraged. The government can give direct support through greater outsourcing and moving away from low-value, high-volume back-office jobs and customer support activities, and instead moving towards higher value offerings by BPO services providers. The government role in expanding the domestic BPO industry is expected to be critical, as it can boost domestic business by taking forward programs such as e-governance and connectivity. This will further increase the growth of the domestic market and inject productivity growth into the economy. The Indian software services sector has the potential to emerge as an IT hub in the region. But for that to happen, it is important for the government to provide opportunities within its various bilateral Free Trade Agreements. Concessions for IT service providers can be negotiated to increase exports and investments in other countries. Low-value end services can be outsourced to these countries and attempts can be made to develop supply chains. Efforts are required to improve both demand-side and supply-side factors in these services sectors. On the demand side specific policies are required to improve domestic and external demand, and on the supply side targeted policies are required to boost productivity growth. Higher sustainable growth is creating greater demand for financial savings. The Indian banking sector faces many challenges with the economy possessing one of the highest growth rates in the world. Not only does the banking sector require increased penetration to reach out to a wider customer base but it also has to provide the best value to customers in terms of service levels and transparency. Indian banks will have to find ways to optimize each customer relationship as they compete with global players with deep pockets and deep customer insights. To help banks improve their productivity and efficiency and provide much needed support to the industry, recommendations are the following: Banks not only need to invest in infrastructure but they also need to leverage information technology to find more innovative ways to reach customers, such as 140 | P a g e utilizing new delivery mechanisms, economizing on transaction costs, and providing better access to the under-served. Electronic transactions substantially improve the efficiency of banking systems because they are faster in comparison with paper-based transactions. To help banks undertake these costs, more deregulation is required. Another critical challenge is the hiring and retaining of talent in the face of stiff competition from private institutions. Banks will also have to invest in new skill development and training. The government can provide vital support in this respect. As the share of public-sector banks is the highest, skill development and training of staff needs to be undertaken at regular intervals to keep them up-todate with the latest technologies and customer care programs. Indian banks need to build on existing capabilities and also add new ones. This poses a more serious managerial challenge given the dynamic environment in which banks will be forced to continuously learn and reorient themselves while adopting new technologies for risk management, building innovative service mechanisms of delivery, and improving customer care. The consolidation of banks can prove to be an effective tool to achieve this objective. Banks with similar operations have an incentive to merge, thereby eliminating overlapping branches and freeing back office, administration, and marketing resources. Productivity gains from the implementation of new technologies would also be enhanced due to the incurring of large initial investments compared to the scale of operations. This may also lead to risk diversification, which is more relevant for smaller banks concentrated in particular regions serving niche markets. As banks merge and grow bigger they would be in a much better position to introduce customized financial instruments. The government can play a vital role in this through strategic policy intervention. A clear danger is that the current pattern of skill-intensive growth will be accentuated. Increasing inequality of income is paralleled by increasing regional inequality. These trends can create political instability, or lead to growth that peters out, leaving a wealthy class connected with the global market economy, and significant numbers of poor people. 141 | P a g e One of the features of the Indian development model was its ability to balance different interests through formal democratic processes as well as informal political bargaining, albeit at the cost of higher growth. The challenge now is to create a new social contract that softens the growth-equity trade-off so that both can be better achieved. As has been the case for a long time in India, social stratification does act as an inhibitor to equity. Many of the poorest parts of India with the worst human development indicators have high proportions of tribals or dalits (former untouchables). Interestingly, the software industry provides an example of what is possible. Initially, the view of computer science as a cerebral activity with high social status made it attractive for upper castes in India, especially in the South, where quota systems had restricted access to government jobs for the highest castes. Over time, however, the industry has attracted entrants from all backgrounds. Global competition has promoted a meritocratic relatively egalitarian culture in the industry. Women too are increasingly drawn into a specialty that does not suffer from the traditional social constraints associated with other disciplines such as civil and mechanical engineering. In general growth and urbanization have begun to chip away at traditional manifestations of social stratification. It will be important for policies to be designed that improve access to education through targeted subsidies and supply increases, rather than increased use of quotas. Agriculture remains one of the biggest challenges for India’s future development though it must be recognized that agricultural modernization cannot be a substitute for growth in labour-intensive manufacturing. After the diffusion of the Green Revolution which introduced high-yielding varieties of several cereal crops along with increased fertilizer use and irrigation agricultural growth has slowed. Part of the problem is that farmers have been locked into growing low-value crops by the existing physical and organizational infrastructure and political arrangements. New investments are required throughout the agricultural value chain but these also require innovations in risk management and adjustment assistance that have been slow to develop especially for agricultural producers. Individual bureaucrats, visionary entrepreneurs and enterprising politicians together played a role in previous agricultural development as did foreign expertise 142 | P a g e (Kohli and Singh, 2005). Clearly a concerted approach to revamping this dimension of development strategy is required for India. Many of the changes required have to do with relaxation of controls but others require institution building which is more difficult. Improvements in agricultural growth and rural development more broadly will address some of the concerns with respect to inequality and have a value from that perspective as well. While rural development through road building, better telecommunications connections and investments in health and education can help to create non-agricultural rural employment but it remains the case that urban, industrial employment must increase dramatically. As agricultural productivity increases labour will be freed up and must be absorbed into industry and services. Given the limitations of services as an employer of unskilled labour, Indian policy reform must be geared toward creating the conditions for large-scale labour-intensive manufacturing for the domestic as well as the international market. This may be the single most important change needed in India, for sustained growth – it represents a very traditional but logically sound goal for development strategy. The problem has been in agreeing on and implementing a set of policies that will support this goal. Microeconomic reforms of labour markets, smallbusiness finance, industrial and vocational training and land use policies are all likely to be needed (e.g., Kelkar, 1999; Srinivasan, 2007; Panagariya, 2008. The urgency of creating job-friendly growth is highlighted by India’s demographic dividend which will give it a bulge in the working-age population. To the extent services growth is led by sectors like transport and communication a relatively large subsector of services it can sustain high overall growth in the medium term. In the long run however the infrastructure services would have to induce faster growth in industry to sustain a high aggregate growth. There are inequalities arising out of occupation and location specificities which have also increased. The share of agriculture has substantially declined in GDP but not in workforce, so agriculture non‐agriculture disparity in per worker income has sharply increased. Incomes of wage earners have grown at much slower rate than of the owner of capital. Rising share of the organised sector in output but not in employment has further widened the already large income disparities between those engaged in the two sectors. 143 | P a g e Inter regional disparities in spite of some poorer regions doing better lately continue to be large. Increasing disparities are no doubt likely to be a source of social discord but will also threaten the sustainability of high economic growth as increasing income inequality would result in a demand constraint. It must also be noted that the high and increasing inequalities leading to growing dualism for example between agriculture and other sectors and between organized and unorganized sectors with large differences in productivity. It would also lead to supply side constraints to growth in terms of availability of wage‐goods and inputs and intermediates for production in the formal sector. Increasing asymmetry between income and employment shares of agriculture is likely to pose a serious problem for growth as well as livelihoods. If the continuing decline in the share of agriculture in GDP is not accompanied by a significant decline in workforce share, it will not only lead to widening of disparities and stagnation in purchasing power with large mass of rural population, but can even lead to an absolute decline in incomes of agricultural workers if agricultural growth is negligible or negative. Raising agricultural growth and productivity is no doubt very important but the need to shift a large part of agricultural workforce to non‐agricultural activities is rather urgent. Linked with the structural transformation of workforce is the larger issue of employment. The post‐reform economic growth has failed to deliver on employment front inspite of its being highly successful in delivering on GDP front. A high growth has not been able to generate employment even at a rate achieved with less than half GDP growth rate in the past. Part of the reason lies in technology which has become less employment intensive across economic activities and product groups but a good part of the reason lies in the structure of growth. Most services especially those which have dominated India’s economic growth in recent years are highly capital intensive and India’s exports have become increasingly less labour intensive because of the compulsions of international competitiveness to use more efficient capital intensive technology. Most growth has been derived from sectors and activities that have low employment potential. A service‐led and export‐led growth is highly unlikely to improve the employment intensity. A faster growth of the 144 | P a g e manufacturing industry along with a greater domestic orientation of production is therefore necessary for growth to ensure a reasonably high rate of employment growth. A scheme has been launched for development of nationally and internationally important destinations and circuits through mega projects. So far 38 projects have been identified out of which 23 have been sanctioned. The mega projects are a judicious mix of heritage and cultural, spiritual, and ecotourism in order to give tourists a holistic experience. In order to meet the huge skill gap in the hospitality industry the Government has put in place a multipronged strategy which includes strengthening and expanding the institutional infrastructure for training and education. Besides this other steps are being taken for skill training of youth in the hospitality sector and providing skill certification. While the general security situation has improved considerably. To strengthen the National Tourism Policy 2002’s critical pillar of Safety the Government has adopted the Code of Conduct for ‘Safe and Honourable Tourism’ on 1 July 2010. Along with the continuation of promotional efforts under the Incredible India campaign the Government has introduced the Visa-on-Arrival (VoA) scheme for tourists from five countries namely Singapore, Finland, New Zealand, Luxembourg, and Japan on a pilot basis with effect from 1 January 2010. During January–December 2010, a total of 6549 VoAs were issued under this scheme. The VoA scheme has been extended to the nationals of Cambodia, Vietnam, Laos, and Philippines with effect from 1 January 2011 and Myanmar and Indonesia from 25 January 2011. Despite these efforts there is a lot more to be done given the potential of this sector. In fact at 11.5 per cent the share of travel in India’s exports of commercial services in 2008 is relatively lower than that of many other exporters of services and half the shares of the USA, EU and China Some issues related to the warehousing sector include increasing high quality storage capacity as well as the numbers of trained samplers and graders addressing issues like:- 145 | P a g e Storage loss due to deterioration of the produce during storage. Lack of provision for dealing with cases where stocks are pledged with banks and the depositor either absconds or refuses to take delivery. Delay in delivery and deposit of stocks due to extension of ‘no-entry’ zones in cities. Levy of property tax on warehouses and high fees by ports. The National Housing Bank (NHB) established with the objective of promoting housing finance institutions both at local and regional levels has conceptualized the reverse mortgage loan product exclusively for covering house-owning senior citizens. It has introduced the residential real estate price index (RESIDEX), which is an initiative towards providing the housing finance sector with an index which reflects the trends in the prices of residential properties across the country. The global economic crisis impacted the Indian real estate industry significantly. However, various measures taken by the Government to boost the demand for residential properties as also the relaxation in provisioning requirements by the RBI for banks and NHB for Housing Finance Companies (HFCs) has minimized the impact of economic crisis on this sector. The sector has started recovering following the increasing activity in the Indian economy however with a fundamental difference. Customers are now going for need- based purchases rather than investment based on the euphoria and hype witnessed in 2007 and 2008. The Government has been supporting the IT and ITES sector in many ways. This was continued in the 2010-11 Budget with policies like Government expenditure for improving IT infrastructure and delivery mechanism reduction in surcharge from 10 per cent to 7.5 per cent for IT companies and Government’s E-Governance plan. There are some issues in the IT-ITES sector which need attention. These include shifting from lowend services to high- end services like programming in the light of competition in BPO from other countries and policies in some developed countries like UK to employ locals addressing data protection issues as half of offshore work does not come to India concluding totalization agreements with target countries to resolve the social security 146 | P a g e benefits issue as is being done now and increasing the coverage and depth of IT and ITES services in the domestic sector. There is need to tap outsourcing in niche areas like actuarial and accountancy services as there is good scope for outsourcing actuarial services and accountancy services to India including setting up back offices. But Indian service providers need high-quality training in tax laws of US and other countries besides laws related to insurance, pension, etc. Tie-ups to overcome the weakness of small size of domestic accountancy firms can also help India’s accounting sector grow manifold. Some initiatives that could be taken in the construction sector include using the standard contract document for all domestic civil engineering projects, setting up consortiums to bid effectively for international projects and resolving the issue of precondition in most of the overseas tenders floated by clients wherein equipment to be supplied by the contracting company has necessarily to be sourced from an approved list of suppliers from developed countries. Another area that needs consideration is the possibility of a double guarantee avoidance treaty on the lines of the double taxation avoidance treaty as overseas clients insist on bank guarantees to be issued under the contract being routed through a local bank operating in the country of project execution which results in Indian contracting companies being called upon to pay the bank guarantee charges to Indian banks as also to the local overseas banks which issue the final end guarantees to the client, based on the counter guarantees from the Indian banks. Given the myriad activities in services supporting its growth will require careful and differentiated strategies. The opportunities in this fast-growing, employmentoriented, FDI attracting sector with vast export-potential are striking. However there are many challenges: One of the challenges in this area is to retain India’s competitiveness in those sectors where it has already made a mark such as IT & ITES and Telecommunications. Their deeper and broader use in the domestic sectors would also have a dramatic potential to increase the efficiency and productivity of other goods and services. 147 | P a g e The second challenge lies in making inroads into some traditional areas such as tourism and shipping where other countries have already established them but the potential for India is nevertheless very high. The third challenge is in making forays into globally traded services in still niche areas for India, such as financial services, health care, education, accountancy, and other business services where India has a large domestic market and has also shown recent signs of making a dent in the international market, but only a very small part of the full potential has been tapped. There are also challenges related to collecting better data and developing a better co-ordinated strategy to pull together all the dispersed information. Regulatory improvements will also be important as many domestic regulations and market access barriers could come in the way of fully tapping this growth- accelerating sector. Since there are diverse sectors within services, the issues and policies cannot be separated into watertight compartments. Addressing these challenges and issues could further strengthen the services sector which is the driving force for India to realize double-digit growth potential, both overall and at state level, while providing more and better jobs to help achieve more inclusive and balanced growth. 148 | P a g e BIBLIOGRAPHY Abdul Kalam A.P.J. and Y.S. Rajan (1998), “India 2020-A Vision for the New Millennium”,Penguin India, New Delhi Pp-158-159. Acharya Shankar (2003), “India’s Economy: Some Issues and Answers”, Academic Foundation, New Delhi. Acharya Shankar (2004), “India’s Growth Prospects Revisited” Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 39, No. 41, Pp-4537-42, Oct. 9. Adabar, K. (2004), “Economic Growth & Convergence in India, available atwww.isid.ac.in/~planning/ka.pdf, Accessed on September 13, 2006. Agarwalla A, Pangotra P (2011), “Regional Income Disparities in India and Test for Convergence 1980 to 2006”, Working Paper No. 2011-01-04, Indian Institute of Management, Ahmadabad. Aghion, P., E. Caroli, and C.G. Penalosa, (1999), “Inequality and Economic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories", Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 37, No. 4: 1615-1660. Ahluwalia, M.S. (2000), “Economic Performance of States in Post-reform Period,” Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 25, No. 19 : 1637-1648. Ahluwalia, M.S. (2002a), “Economic Reforms in India since 1991: Has Gradualism Worked?”,Journal of Economic Perspective Vol. 16,No. 3,Pp-67-88. Ahluwalia, M.S. (2002), “State Level Performance Under Economic Reforms in India”, in Economic Policy Reforms and the Indian Economy, ed. By Anne O, Krueger, Oxford University Press, New Delhi, Pp-91-125. Aiyar, Shekhar (2000), “Growth Theory and Convergence Across Indian States: A Panel Study”, in Callen, Tim, Patrica Reynolds and Christopher Towe (eds) India at the Crossroads: Sustaining Growth and Reducing Poverty, International Monetary Fund, Washington DC. Anand, S. and S.M.R Kanbur (1986), “ Inequality and Development, A Critique”,Paper presented at the 25th Anniversary Symposium, Yale Growth Centre, April 11-13, 1986. 149 | P a g e Bajpai, N and Jeffrey D Sachs (1996), “Trends in Inter-State Inequalities of Income in India”, Discussion Paper No. 528, Harvard Institute for International Development, Harvard University. Bajpai N and J.D. Sachs (1999), “The Progress of Policy Reform and Variations in Performance at the Sub-National Level in India”, Development Discussion Paper No. 730, Harvard Institute for International Development.Bajpai, N. and J.D. Sachs (2000), “India’s Decade of Development”, Working Paper No. 46, Centre for International Development, Harvard University, May 2000. Bandyopadhyay, S. (2003), “Convergence Club Empirics,” some Dynamics and Explanations of Unequal Growth across Indian States, Discussion Paper No.2003/77, World Institute for Development Economic Research, United Nations University, Helsinki. Bandyopadhyay S (2011), “Convergence Clubs in Incomes across Indian States: Is there Evidence of a Neighbors Effect?” Department of Economics, University of Birmingham. Banerjee D, A. Ghosh (1988), “Indian Planning and Regional Disparity in Growth”, in A.K. Bagchi (ed) Economy, Society and Polity, Essays in the Political Economy of Indian Planning, In Honour of Professor Bhabatosh Dutta, Oxford University Press, Oxford Pp-104-65. Banerjee P.K. (1994), “India’s Services Sector: Some Select Areas” Foreign Trade Review Vol. 28, No. 4, Pp-364-372. Banga, Rashmi (2005), “Critical Issues in India’s Services-led Growth”, ICRIER Working Paper No. 171 October. Banga, Rashmi (2005), “Role of Services in The Growth Process: A Survey” ICRIER Working Paper No. 159, March. Barro R. and X. Sala-i-Martin, (1990), “Economic Growth and Convergence across the United States”, Working Paper No. 3419, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge. Barro, Robert, J. (1991), “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries” Quarterly Journal of Economics,Vol.106, No.2 Pp-407-443. 150 | P a g e Basu, K. (2005), “Globalization, Poverty and Inequality: What is the Relationship? What can be done?”, Research paper No. 2005/32, World Institute for Development Economic Research, United Nations University, Helsinki. Basu, K. (2006), “India’s Economic Report Card,” Available at www.news.bbc.co.uk, Accessed on January 23, 2007. Basu K and Maertens A (2007), “The Pattern and Causes of Economic Growth in India” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 23(2), Pp143-67. Basu K. (2008), “India’s Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Policy making in a Globalized World” Economic and Political Weekly Feb. 2, Vol. 43. No.6, Pp-53- 61. Bathla S (2003), “Inter-Sectoral Growth Linkages in India: Implications for Policy and Liberalized Reforms”, accessed from www.ccssr.org.cn/new/uploadfile/ 2008680718733 pdf. Baumol, W. J. (1986), “Productivity Growth, Convergence, and Welfare: What the Long-run Data Show”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No.5:1072 1085.272 Bhanumurthy, N.R. and A. Mitra (2004), “Economic Growth, Poverty and Inequality in Indian States in the Pre-reform and Reform periods,” Asian Development Review, Vol. 21, No. 2: 79-99. Bharadwaj K (1987), “Analytics of Agriculture-Industry Relation”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 22, Annual Number 19,20 and 21 May, Pp-15-20. Bhattacharya, B.B. (1984), “Public Expenditure Inflation and Growth: A MacroEconometric Analysis for India”, Oxford University Press Delhi. Bhattacharya, B.B. and Arup Mitra (1989), “Industry Agriculture Growth Rates: Widening Disparity- An Explanation.” Economic and Political Weekly Aug-26 Vol24 No.-34 Pp-1963-70. Bhattacharya, B. B. and A. Mitra (1990), “Excess Growth of Tertiary Sector in Indian Economy: Issues and Implications”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 25, No. 44: 2445-2450. 151 | P a g e Bhattacharya B.B. Arup Mitra (1997), “Changing Composition of Employment of Tertiary Sector: A Cross-Country Analysis”, Economic and Political Weekly Vol-32, No.11, March 15, Pp-529-534. Bhattacharya B.B., Kar S. (2004), “Long-run Growth Prospects for the Indian Economy” in R.K. Sinha ed. Macroeconomic Projections, India 2025: Social Economic and Political Stability, Shipra Publication Delhi. Bhattacharya, B.B. and S. Sakthivel (2004), “Regional Growth and disparity in India: Comparison of Pre- and Post-Reform Decades,” Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 49, No. 10: 1071-1077. Bhide S and R. Shand (2000), “Inequalities in Income Growth in India Before and After Reforms”, South Asia Economic Journal Vol-1 No.1 March Pp-19-51. Bhide, S., R. Chadha, and K. Kalirajan (2005), “Growth Interdependence Among Indian States: An Exploration” Asia-Pacific Development Journal, Vol.12, No.2: 5980. Bhowmik Rita (2000), “Role of Services Sector in Indian Economy: An InputOutput Approach”, Artha Vijnana Vol. XLII No.2, June, Pp-158-169. Cashin, Paul and Ratna Sahay (1996), “Internal Migration, Centre-State Grants, and Economic Growth in the States of India”, IMF Staff Papers Vol. 43, No.1, March Pp.123-171. Central Statistical Organisation (various issues), National Accounts Statistics, CSO, New Delhi. Chakravarty Deepita (2006), “Growing Services in India: An Inter-Sectoral Analysis Based on State-Level Data”,Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 41, No. 27-28, Pp3061-3067. Chan, S. (1989), “Income Inequality among LDCs: A comparative Analysis of Alternative perspective", International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 33, No.1:45-65. Chandrakumarmanglam S, P. Govindasamy (2012), “A Review of Performance and Contributions of Indian Service Sectors Towards Sustainable Economic Development”, European Journal of Social Sciences Vol.29, No.1, Pp-76-95. 152 | P a g e Chatterji, Dipankar (1996), “Measurement of Inter-State Differences in Development: Relative Efficacy of Measures”, The Journal of Income and Wealth, IARNIW, Vol. 18, No.1, January. Chattopadhyay, A.K. and Ghosal, R.K. (2004), “Globalisation, Inequalities in Consumption and Poverty in Rural India", Asian Economic Review, Vol. 46, No.3: 425-439. Chaudhury, Mahindar D (1974), “Behaviour of Spatial Income Inequality in a Developing Economy: India 1950-76”, Paper presented at the Ninth Conference of the Indian Association for Research in National Income and Wealth. Chaudhuri S (2000), “Economic Growth in the State Four Decades –I”, Money and Finance, Oct-Dec. Pp-45-69. Chelliah, R. and K. R. Shanmugam (2007), “Strategy for Poverty Reduction and Narrowing Regional Disparities’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.42, No.34: 3475-3481. Ciccone A and R.E. Hall (1996),’Productivity and the Density of Economic Activity’ American Economic Review Vol.86 pp 54-70. Ciccone A (2002),’Agglomeration Effects In Europe’ European Economic Review Vol.46 pp 213-227. CMIE (2011), National Income Statistics July. CSO (2001) National Accounts Statistics, Back series 1950-51 to 1992-93 April. CSO (2007) : National Accounts Statistic, 2007 and National Accounts Statistics Back series 1950-51 to 1999-2000. Dandekar, V. M. and N, Rath, (1971), Poverty in India- I, Dimensions and Trends, Economic and Political Weekly, VOL. 6, No. 1: 25-48. Dandekar, V.M. (2000), “Gross Domestic Product and Regional Disparities in Development in India”, Journal of Indian School of Political Economy Vol.12 No.1, January-March. Das Abhijit, Rashmi Banga, Dinesh Kumar (2011), “Global Economic Crisis: Impact and Restructuring of the Services Sector in India”,Working Paper No. 311, Sept. ADBI. 153 | P a g e Das Banka Behary (2000), “Economic Liberalization and Inter-Regional Disparities in India”, in Economic Liberalization and Regional Disparities in India, ed. By Baidnath Mishra Rajkishor Meher, A.P.H. Publishing Corporation. Pp-209-222. Das, S. K., and Barua A., 1996. “Regional Inequalities, Economic Growth and Liberalization: A Study of Indian Economy,” Journal of Development Studies,Vol. 32, No. 3: 364-90. Dasgupta, et al. (2000), “Growth and Interstate Disparities in India”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 35 , No. 27: 2413-2422 Dasgupta, P. S., A. K. Sen and D. A. Starrett (1973), “Notes on the measurement of inequality”, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 6: 180-187. Dasgupta S and Ajit Singh (2005),”Will Services be the New Engine of Economic Growth in India”,Centre for Business Research, University of Cambridge Working Paper No.310, September. Datt, G. and M. Ravallion (2002), “Is India’s Economic Growth Leaving the Poor Behind?”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 16, No. 3: 89-108. Datt, Gaurav and Martin Ravallion (2009), “Has India’s Economic Growth Become More Pro-Poor in the Wake of Economic Reforms?” Policy Research Working Paper 5103, World Bank. Datta, M. (2001), The Significance and Growth of Tertiary Sector: Indian Economy, 1950-1997, New Delhi, Northern Book Centre. Deaton, Angus and Dreze, Jean (2002), “Poverty and Inequality in India – A ReExamination”, Economic and Political Weekly, Sep. 7 Vol-37 No. 36 Pp-3729-3748. De Janvery A and E Sadoulet (2001) ,’Income Strategies Among Rural Households in Mexico: The Role of off-farm Activities’ World Development Vol.29 No.3 pp 467480. Dekle R and J Eaton (1999),’Agglomeration and Land Rents: Evidence from the Prefectures’ Journal of Urban Economics. Vol.46. pp 200-214. Dev, M. and C. Ravi, (2007), “Poverty and Inequality: All India and States, 19832005, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 42, No. 6 : 509-521. Dhar, P.K. (2010) Indian economy – its Growing Dimensions, 17th Edition, New Delhi: Kalyani Publishers. 154 | P a g e Dhawan S and K.K. Saxena (1992), “Sectoral Linkages and Key-Sectors of the Indian Economy”, Indian Economic Review, 37, Pp-195-210. Dholakia, B.H.(2002), “Sources of India’s Accelerated Growth and the Vision of the Indian Economy”, Indian Economic Journal Vol. 49, No.4 Pp-27-46. Dholakia, R.H. (1994), “Spatial Dimension of Acceleration of Economic Growth in India”, Economic and Political Weekly-Aug. 27 Vol-29 No. 35 Pp-2303-09. Duranton G and D Puga (2004), ‘Micro-Foundation of Urban Agglomeration Economies’ in J V Henderson and J F Thisse (eds), Hand book of Urban and Regional Economics Vol.4 Elsevier-North Holland, Amsterdam. Echevarria, Cristina (1997), “Changing Sectoral Composition Associated with Economic Growth”, International Economic Review, Vol 38, No.-2 May, Pp 431-52. Edward, P. (2006), “Examining Inequality: Who really Benefits from Global Growth?”World Development, Vol.34, No. 10: 1667-1695 EPW Research Foundation (1998) National Accounts Statistics of India 1950-51 to 1996-97.Third Edition October. EPW Research Foundation (2002) National Accounts Statistics Of India 1950-51 to 2000-01 July. EPW Research Foundation (2003) Domestic Product of States of India 1960-61 to 2000-01 June. EPW Research Foundation (2004) National Accounts Statistics of India 1950-51 to 2002-03 EPW Research Foundation (2007), “Domestic Product of States of India 1960-61 to 206-07”, Second updated Edition. Pp-23-48. Evans, P and G Karras (1996), “Convergence Revisited”, Journal of Monetary Economics Vol. 37, No.2, Pp-249-65. Forbes, K. (2000), “A Reassessment of the Relationship between Inequality and Growth,” American Economic Review, Vol. 90, No. 4: 869–97. Ganesh Kumar, N. (1992), “Some Comments on the Debate on India’s Economic Growth in the 1980s”, The Indian Economic Journal; Vol. 39 No.4 Pp-102-111. 155 | P a g e Gaur Achal Kumar (2010), “Regional Disparities in Economic Growth: A Case Study of Indian States”, Paper Prepared for the 31st General Conference of the International Association for Research in Income and Wealth, St. Gallen, Switzerland. Ghosal Ratan Kumar (2004), “GDP Growth and Feel Good Factor” EPW Vol. 39, No. 20, May 15, Pp-1993-1997. Ghosal Ratan Kumar (2010), “Inter-State Disparity in Growth, Poverty and Inequality in India-A Panel Data Approach”,The Asian Economic Review Vol-52, No.2, Pp377-388. Ghosh Buddhadeb, Prabir De (1998), “Role of Infrastructure in Regional Development: A Study over the Plan period” Economic and Political Weekly Nov. 21, Vol. 33, No. 47-48, Pp-3039. Ghosh B.S. Marjit and C. Neogi (1998), “Economic Growth and Regional Divergence in India, 1960 to 1995”, Economic and Political Weekly. Vol-33 No.-26 Pp-1623-1630. Ghosh, Buddhadeb, Prabir De (2004), “How Do Different Categories of Infrastructure Affect Development?”,Evidence from Indian States; Economic and Political Weekly Vol-39 No. 42 Pp-4645-57. Ghosh Madhusudan (2008), “Economic Growth and Regional Convergence” in Economic Reforms and Indian Economic Development Selected Essays, Bookwell N. Delhi, Pp-87-111. Ghosh, S. and S. Pal, (2004), “The Effect of Inequality on Growth: Theory and Evidence from the Indian States,” Review of Development Economics, Vol. 8,No. 1: 164-177. Glaser E.L, H.D. Kallal, J.A. Scheinkman and A Shleifer(1992),’Growth in Cities,’ Journal of Political Economy. Vol.100 pp 1126-52. Gopalan, Suresh and Zagros Madjd-Sadjadi (2012), ‘Trends Impacting Global Services Off shoring : Will India remain World Leader?’ International Journal of Innovation Management and Technology Vol.3 No.1 February. Gordon J, Gupta P (2004), “Understanding Indian’s Services Revolution” IMF Working Paper Wp/04/171 IMF. 156 | P a g e Government of India (2007) Economic Survey 2006-07, Ministry of Finance Economic Division. Gupta, G.S. and R.D. Singh (1984), “Income inequality across Nations over time:How much and Why”, Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 51, No. 1: 250-257. Gupta, S (1973), “The Role of the Public Sector in Reducing Regional Income Disparity in India”, Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 9, No.2, Pp-243-60. Hansda S (2001), “Sustainability of Services Led Growth-An Input-Output Analysis of the Indian Economy” RBI Occasional Paper Vol. 22 (1,2 & 3), Pp73-118. Henderson J.V, A Kuncoro and M Turner (1995),’Industial Development in cities’ Journal of Political Economy. Vol.103 pp 1067-85. Hussain, A., S. Sirivardana and P. Wignaraja (2004): Lessons for Macro-Micro Policy, chapter Jointly written in, Ponna Wignaraja and Susil Sirivardana (eds.). Pro-Poor Growth and Governance in South Asia: Decentralization and Participatory Development, New Delhi : SAGE Publications . Iradian, G. (2005), “Inequality, Poverty and Growth: Cross country Evidences,”IMF Working Paper No. 28, February, 2005.276 Jenkins, S.P. and P. V. Kerm (2008) "Has Income Growth Become More Pro-Poor?" Paper Prepared for the 30th General Conference of the International Association for Research in Income and Wealth, Portoroz, Slovenia. Jha, R. (2000), “Growth, Inequality and Poverty in India: Spatial and Temporal Characteristics, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 35, No. 11: 921-928. Jha, R. (2000), “Reducing Poverty and Inequality in India, Has Liberalization helped?”, Working paper No. 204, World Institute for Development Economic Research, United Nations University, Helsinki. Jha R (2010), “The Analytics of the Agriculture-Industry Relationship in a Closed Economy: A Case Study of India”, Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 45, No.17, Pp.94-98. Jolly, R. (2006), "Inequality in Historical Perspective", Research Paper No.2006/32, World Institute for Development Economic Research, United Nations University, Helsinki. 157 | P a g e Joshi Seema (2004), “Tertiary Sector-Driven Growth in India”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol-39, No.37, Sep. 11-17, Pp-4175-4178. Kakwani, N. and E. M. Pernia (2000) ‘What is pro poor growth?”, Asian Development Review, Vol.16, No. 1: 12-26. Kalita Mamoni, Aviral Kumar Tiwari (2012), “Testing Income Convergence: Evidence from Indian States Using Panel Linear and Nonlinear Unit Root Tests”,The Economic Research Guardian, Semi-annual Online Journal www.ecrg.ro Vol. 2, No.1, Pp-60-69. Kalra S, Sodsriwiboon P (2010), “Growth Convergence and Skillovers among Indian States: What Matters? What Does Not?” IMF Working Paper Wp/10/96. Kaplow, L. (2005), “Why Measure Inequality?” Journal of Economic Inequality, Vol. 3, No. 1 : 65-78.277 Kar Sabyasachi, S. Sakthivel (2007),”Reforms and Regional Inequality in India” Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 42,No.47, Pp.69-77. Katti Vijaya (1998), “Services Sector and Employment”, Yojana Vol-42 No.8 Pp 5358 August. Kaur G, Bordoloi S, Rajesh R (2009), “An Empirical Investigation of the InterSectoral Linkages in India”. Reserve Bank of India Occasional Papers 30(1), Pp2972. Khanna P.C. (1990), “Structural Changes in the Economies of States”, The Journal of Income and Wealth IARNIW, Vol;-12, No. 1 January. Khomiakova, T. (2008), Spatial analysis of Regional Divergence in India, Income and Economic Structure Perspectives”, The International Journal of Economic Policy Studies, Vol. 8 : 137-161. Krishna K.L. (2004), “Patterns and Determinants of Economic Growth in Indian States”,Working Paper No. 144, September, Indian Council for Research on Internation Economic Relations. Krugman P and R Livas Elizondo (1996),’Trade Policy and The Third World Metropolis’ Journal Of Development Economics Vol.49 No.1 pp 137-50. Kohli Atul (2006), “Politics of Economic Growth in India, 1980-2005, Part-II: The 1990s and Beyond” EPW Vol. 41, No.14, April 8, Pp-1361-1370. 158 | P a g e Kumar T. Ravi and Papia Sengupta (2008), “Linguistic Diversity and Disparity in Regional Growth”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol-43, No.33, Aug. 16-22, Pp9. Kurian N.J. (2000), “Widening Regional Disparities in India-Some Indicators”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 35, No.7, Feb. 12-18, Pp.538-50. Kurian N.J. (2004), “Regional Disparities in India 2025 Social Economic and Political Stability” ed. By R.K. Sinha,Shipra Publications. Pp-404-432. Kuznet, S. (1955), “Economic Growth and Income Inequality”, American Economic Review, Vol. 45, No.1 :1-28. Lakshminarayana S, Saroja Rama Rao and Shrinivasa Rao (1995), “Data Gaps in the Estimation of State Domestic Product”, The Journal of Income and Wealth, IARNIW, Vol. 17, No-1 January. Madheswaran S., Amita Dharmadhikary (2000), “Income and Employment Growth in Service Sector in India”, The Indian Journal of Labour Economics Vol. 43, No.4, Pp835-840. Marjit, S and S, Mitra (1996), “Convergence in Regional Growth Rates: Indian Research Agenda”, Economic and Political Weekly Aug-17 Vol-31 No. 33 Pp-2239242. Mathur, A. (1983), “ Regional Development and Income Disparities in India: A sectoral analysis,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 31, No.3: 475505. Mathur A (1987), “Why Growth Rates Differ Within India: An Alternative Approach” The Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 23, No.2, Pp-167-99. Mazumdar Dipak, Sandip Sarkar (2007), “Growth of Employment and Earnings in Tertiary Sector 1983-2000”, Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 42, No. 11, March 17, Pp-973-81. Mazumdar, Krishna (1990), “An Alternative Method of Measuring Inter-State Disparity in Per Capita State Domestic Product”, The Journal of Income and Wealth, IARNIW, Vol. 12 No.1 January. Mitra, Ashok (1988), “Disproportionality and the Services Sector: A Note”, Social Scientist April Vol-16 No.-4. 159 | P a g e Mitra, A. (1992), “Growth and Poverty: The Urban Legend,” Economic and Political Weekly, Issue No. 13:659-665. Mitra, A. (1997), “Infrastructure and Human Development”, Productivity, Vol.38, No. 2 : 200-206. Mohanty, M. (1983), “Towards a political Theory of Inequality”, in Beteille. A. (ed.) Equality and Inequality: Theory and Practice, Delhi: Oxford University Press. Nagaraj R. (1990), “Growth Rate of India’s GDP 1950-51 to 1987-88: Examination of Alternative Hypothesis” Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 25, No. 26, June 30, Pp-1396-404. Nagaraj, R, Aristomene Varoudakis and Marie-Ange Veganzones (1998), “Long-Run Growth Trends and Convergence Across Indian States”, OECD Technical Papers, No. 131 January Pp-1-58. Nagaraj R (2000), “Indian Economy Since 1980: Virtuous Growth or Polarisation?” Economic and Political Weekly Aug. Vol. 35, No. 32, Pp-2831-39. Nagaraj, R. (2005), “Economic growth and distribution in India, 1950-05: an overview”. Paper prepared for the conference on Development Prospects for the 21 Century, organized by the International Celso Furtado Center for Development Policies, Rio de Janeiro, November 6-7, 2008. Nagaraj R. (2008), “India’s Recent Economic Growth: A Closer Look” Economic and Political Weekly April 12, Vol. 43, No. 15, Pp-55-61. Nagaraj R. (2009), “Is Services Sector Output Overestimated? An Inquiry” Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 44, No.5, Pp-40-45, Jan. 31. Nair, K.R.G. (1971), “A Note on Inter-State Income Differentials in India 1950-51 to 1960-61”, Journal of Development Studies. Vol-7, No. 1, Pp-441-47. Narayan, D (2000) Voice of the Poor, Can Anyone Hear Us. World Bank: Oxford University Press. Nayyar, Gaurav (2008), “Economic Growth and Regional Inequality in India”, Economic and Political Weekly Vol-43, No.6 Feb. 9-15. Odedokun, M.O. and J.I. Round, (2001), “Determinants of Income inequality and its Effect on Economic Growth", Discussion Paper No. 103, World Institute for Development Economic Research, United Nations University, Helsinki. 160 | P a g e Paluzie, E (2001),’ Trade Policy and Regional Inequalities’ Papers in Regional Science 80 pp 67-85. Panagariya, A. (2004), “Growth and Reforms During 1980s and 1990s,” Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 39, No.25, Pp-2581-94. Papola, T.S. (2004), “Globalization, Employment and Social Protection: Emerging Perspectives of the Indian Workers”, The Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Vol47, No.3. Papola, T.S. (2006): “Emerging Structure of Indian Economy: Implications of Growing Intersectoral Imbalance” The Indian Economic Journal, Vol. 54, No.1, Pp-525. Papola, T.S. (2012), “Structural Changes in the Indian Economy: Emerging Pattern and Implications”, Working paper No. 2012-02. June, Institute for Studies in Industrial Development. Patel S.P. and P.S. Pandya (1990), “Some Issues in Determining the Short-term and Long-term Growth Rates of State Domestic Product”, The Journal of Income and Wealth, IARNIW, Vol.12, No.1, January. Pattanaik F, Nayak N.C. (2011), “Employment Intensity of Service Sector in India: Trend and Determinants”, 2010 International Conference on Business and Economics Research Vol. 1, IACSIT Press, Kualalumpur, Malaysia. Perroti, R. (1996) “Growth, Income Distribution and Democracy: What can the Data Say”, Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 1, No. 2 : 149-187. Persson, T. and G. Tabellini, (1994), “Is Inequality harmful for Growth?”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No.3: 600-621. Prasad P.H. (1988), “Roots of Unenen Regional Growth in India”, Economic and Political Weekly Vol-17, No.33, Aug. 13, Pp-1689-93. Pritchett, L (2000), “Understanding Patterns of Economic Growth: Searching for Hills among Plateaus, Mounains, and Plains”, World Bank Economic Review, Vol14, No. 2 Pp. 221-250. Purified, C. (2006), “Mind the gap—Is Economic Growth in India Leaving the Poor Behind?” Working paper No. 103, International Monetary Fund, April 2006. Rakshit M. (2007), “Services-led Growth The Indian Experience” Money & Finance, February Pp-91-126. 161 | P a g e Ranjan K. Aneja, N.K. Bishnoi (2009), “Regional Divergence in Growth in India: A Post Reforms Period Study”,The Asian Economic Review, Journal of the Indian Institute of Economics Vol.51, No.2, Aug. Pp. 249-262. Rao, C.H. Hanumantha and S. Mahendra Dev (2003), “Economic Reforms and Challenges Ahead – An Overview”, Economic and Political Weekly, Special Isue on Andhra Pradesh, March 22-29 Vol.38, No.13, Pp-1130-41. Rao, M.G., R.T. Shand, and K. P. Kalirajan, (1999), “Convergence of Incomes across Indian States-A Divergent View,” Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 34, No. 13: 769-778. Rao V.K.R.V. (1998), “Changing Structure of the Economy” in Indian Economy Since Independence by U Kapila (ed) Academic Foundation, New Delhi, Pp. 677-07. Rath D.P, Raj Rajesh (2006), “Analytics and Implications of Services Sector Growth in Indian Economy”,The Journal of Income and Wealth, Vol. 28, No.1, Jan June, Pp47-62. Ravillion, M. and G. Datt (2000), “When is Growth Pro-Poor? Evidence from the Diverse Experiences of India’s States”, Policy Research Working Papers WPS2263 Washington DC, World Bank. Ravallion, M (1998), “Does Aggregation Hide the Harmful Effects of Inequality on Growth?” Economics Letters Vol.61, No.1, Pp-73-77. Ravallian M, G. Datt (2002), “Why has Economic Growth Been More Pro-Poor in Some States of India Than in others?” Journal of Development Economics Vol. 68, Pp-381-400. Registrar General & Census Commisioner, India (2001), Census of India 2001, Provisional Population Totals, Government of India, New Delhi. Reserve Bank Of India (2002) Regional Dimension of Economic Growth in India, Report on Currency and Finance 2000-01 PP III, 45-III, 48 January. Rodrik, D. (2005) Rethinking Growth Strategies, WIDER Perpectives on Global Development. Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan in association with UNIWIDER. Rodrik, Dani (2000), "Growth versus Poverty Reduction: A Hollow Debate," Finance & Development, Vol. 37, No.4: 35-48. 162 | P a g e Rodrik, Dani and Arvind Subramanian (2004a), “From Hindu Growth to Productivity Surge: The Mystery of the Indian Growth Transition; IMF Working Paper WP/04/77 IMF, May. Rodrik, Dani and Arvind Subramanian (2004b), “Why India can Grow at 7 percent a Year or More: Projections and Reflections”, IMF Working paper WP/04/118, July. Rosenthal S S and W C Strange (2004) , ‘ Evidence on the Nature And Sources of Agglomeration Economics’ in J.V. Hinderson and J.F. Thisse (eds) Handbook of Urban and regional Economics VOl.4 Elsevier-North Holland, Amsterdam. Roy Choudhury, Uma Datta (1976), “Regional Income and Accounts of the StateIntroduction”,Journal of Income and Wealth Vol-1, No.1, October. Roy Choudhury, Uma Data (1990), “Regional Pattern of Development in India”, The Journal of Income and Wealth, IARNIW, Vol.12, No.1, January. S. Mahendra Dev (2000), “Economic Reforms, Poverty, Income Distribution and Employment”,Economic and Political Weekly March. 4, Vol. 35, No.10, Pp-823- 835. S. Mahendra Dev (2007), “Inclusive Growth in India” Agriculture, Poverty and Human Development, Oxford Collected Essays, Oxford University Press. Pp-280291. Sachs, J. D., N. Bajpai and A. Ramiah (2002), “Understanding Regional Economic Growth in India,” Working Paper No. 88, Centre for International Development, Harvard University. Saikia, Dilip (2010), “Trends in Agriculture-Industry Inter-linkages in India: Pre and Post-Reform Scenario”, Institute for Financial Management and Research, Dec. Online at http://mpra.ub.uni- muenchen.de/31204/MPRA Paper No. 31204. Saikia Dilip (2011), “Analyzing Inter-Sectoral Linkages in India”,African Journal of Agricultural Research, Vol. 6 No.33 Pp-6766-6775, 30 December. Saith, A. (2005), ‘Poverty Lines versus the Poor’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 40, No. 43: 4601-4610. Sala-i-Martin, X. (1996), “The classical approach to convergence analysis”, Economic Journal, Vol. 106, No. 437 : 1031-1036 163 | P a g e Saksena K.D. (2005), “Inter-State Development Disparities; Chapter 17 in Economic Reforms”, The Indian Experience, Shipra Publication Pp-423-452. Sarker, P.C., (1994), “Regional Imbalances in Indian Economy Over Plan Periods”, Economic and Political Weekly March 12 Vol-29 No.-11 Pp-621-626. Sarkar P.C. (1996), “Growth Differentials in Incomes of Major Indian States”, The Journal of Income and Wealth, IARNIW, Vol.18, No.1, January. Sastry D.V.S. Balwant Singh, Kaushik Bhattacharya, N.K. Unnikrishnan (2003), “Setoral Linkages and Growth Prospects Reflections on the Indian Economy” Economic and Political Weekly Vol-38, No.24, June 14-20, Pp-2390-97. Satish Kumar, M. And Ashok Mathur (1996), “From Tertiary Sector to Services: Some Conceptual Issues and the Indian Scenario”, The Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Vo. 39, No.1. Sen, A and Himanshu (2004), “Poverty and inequality in India-II: Widening Disparities during the 1990s,” Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 39, No. 39:43614375. Sen C (2011) “FDI in the Services Sector- Propagator of Growth for India?” Theoretical and Applied Economics Vol. 18 No.6 pp 141-156. Sengupta, A., K. P. Kannan and G. Raveendran (2008), “India’s Common people, Who are they, How many are they and How they live”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 43, No. 11 : 49-63. Shand, R. and S. Bhide (2000), “Sources of Economic Growth, Regional Dimensions of Reforms, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 35, No. 42: 3747-3757. Shetty S.L. (2003), “Growth of SDP and Structural Changes in State Economies Inter-state Comparisons”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 38, No.49, Dec. 6, Pp-5189-5200. Singh, Ajit (2005), “Manufacturing Services, Jobless Growth and informal Economy: Will Services be the New Engine of Economic Growth in India?” Presentation in a Seminar at ILO, New Delhi, 16 Feb. Singh Nirvikar, Laneesh Bhandari, Aoyu Chen, Aarti Khare (2003), “Regional Inequality in India”, A Fresh Look, Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 38, No.11, March 15, Pp-1069-73. 164 | P a g e Sinha, N. (2004), “Growth, Inequality and Structural Adjustment: An Empirical Interpretation of the S-curve for the Indian Economy,” Working Paper No. 16, Australia South-Asia Research Centre, Australian National University. Singh, N. (2006), “Services-led Industrialization in India: Prospects and Challenges” Stanford Centre for International Development Working Paper, Working Paper No. 290 November. Sinha, T. and D. Sinha, (2000), “No Virginia, States in India are not converging, Working Paper Series No. 2000-09-01, International Indian Economic Association, September 2000. .Sivasubramonian, S. (2004), “The Sources of Economic Growth in India: 1950-51 to 1999-2000” Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Son, H.H (2003), “A new Poverty decomposition,” Journal of Economic Inequality, Vol.1, No. 2: 181-87. Srinivasan, T.N. (1974), “Income Distribution: A Survey of policy aspect”, in Srinivasan T.N. and Bardhan, P.K. (ed.) Poverty and income Distribution in India, Calcutta: Statistical Publishing Society. Subrahmanyam S (1999), “Convergence of Income Across States” ,Economic and Political Weekly Nov. 20, Vol. 34, Nos. 46-47, Pp. 3327-28. Subrahmanyam S, Rajagopala Rao N (2000), “Liberalization an Income Convergence Across Indian States”,Working Paper. The Centre for Economic and Social Studies. Sundram R.M. (1987), “Growth and Income Distribution in India” Policy and Performance since Independence, New Delhi, Sage Publications. Suryanarayanan S.S. (1995), “The Services Sector in India: Structure, Characteristics and Role in Economic Development”,The Indian Journal of Labour Economics Vol. 38, No.1, Pp-93-99. Syrquin M (1989), “Patterns of Structural Change, in Handbook of Development Economics” by H. Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan (ed) Vol-1 North Holland Pp-20373. Tendulkar, B.D. and L.R. Jain (1995), “Economic Growth, Relative Inequality, and Equity: The Case of India”, Asian Development Review, Vol. 13, No. 2 Pp138-168. 165 | P a g e Tewari Amitabh (2008), “Regional Disparities in India: An Inter-Temporal Analysis”, The Indian Journal of Economics, Vol. LXXXVIII, No.4, Pp.671-79. Ucar N, Omay T (2009), “Testing for Unit Root in Nonlinear Heterogeneous Panels”, Economics Letters. 104:5-8. Virmani, Arvind (2008), “Growth and Poverty: Policy Implications for Lagging States”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 43, No.2, January 12-18, Pp-54-62. Visaria, L. and P. Visaria (2003), “Long term population projections for major states, 1991-2001, Economic and Political weekly, Vol. 38, No. 45: 4763-4775. World Bank (2006b), India Inclusive Growth and Service Delivery: Building on India’s Success, Report No. 34580-IN, May 29. 166 | P a g e
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz