LAW FIRM PROFITS AND THEIR ALLOCATION— One Firm’s Experience E very law firm wants to improve its prof- itability in a way that is fair to all partners, and that accounts properly for both the tangible and intangible contributions of its partners. This article recounts a conversation about a hypothetical firm that attempted to do just by Joseph Mais 10 Arizona Attorney u May 2000 that. T he law firm of Abel, Baker and Cook recently celebrated its fifth anniversary. After the party, the founding partners, knowing of my interest in law firm economics, took me aside to tell me about the financial history of their firm. “Our first year together, 1995, was a financial disappointment,” according to Sharon Baker. “Each partner received $150,000 in compensation that year, an amount significantly less than we had each made with our former firms.” The three name partners decided to improve profitability by raising their billing rates from $230/hour to $250/ hour, and the billing rates of their three associates from $130/hour to $150/hour. They also agreed to work harder and manage their accounts receivable more carefully. “We were not trying to get rich, but we did believe that if we worked a little harder and managed our business a little better, we could make a little more money,” Steve Abel explained. “As it turned out, we did work a little harder and smarter. But instead of making a little more money, our profits skyrocketed.” “You see,” Michael Cook broke in, “the revenue of a law firm that bills by the hour is basically the product of four things: (i) the number of timekeepers, (ii) their average billing rate, (iii) their average recorded hours and (iv) realization, which is the portion of one’s recorded billings that is collected.” Cook removed a chart from the drawer in his desk and handed it to me. “This chart shows how we materially increased the firm’s profits by making small increases or improvements in our rates, hours and realization, while holding the line on expenses.” (See Chart A.) I studied the chart and soon realized that the firm’s profits had doubled even though the firm’s revenue had increased by less than 30 percent. This was because every incremental dollar of revenue resulted in an additional dollar of profit for the firm. “That is an impressive improvement in just one year,” I agreed. “How did you distribute profits?” “We adopted a formula that attempted to allocate profits to each partner based on his or her economic contribution to the firm,” Cook replied. “Application of our formula was easy in 1996. Because each of us brought in our own work and supported one associate, our model was driven by our own collections, and those of the lawyers we supervised. In 1996, each lawyer worked 1,800 hours and each lawyer collected 97 percent of his or her work. So each partner’s collections were identical and each partner was paid $300,000. “Unfortunately, our profit allocation formula was tested in 1997,” Cook continued. “Abel’s best client was acquired just when my practice was getting hot. When the firm closed its books at the end of 1997, everything was exactly the same as in 1996, except that I had billed 2,400 hours, while Abel had billed just 1,200 hours. We still had $900,000 in profits to distribute, but application of the firm’s profit allocation formula would have resulted in the following allocation profits: Abel Baker Cook $155,000 $300,000 $445,000 “This is because my economic contribution to the firm (as we measured it) was $145,000 higher in 1997 than it had been in 1996 (i.e., 600 incremental hours at $250/hour x 97 percent realization), while Abel’s economic contribution to the firm had decreased from the previous year by a like amount.” “All of us were surCHART A 1995 1996 prised that application Number of Timekeepers 6 6 of a formula we thought was fair and Billing Rates 3 partners @ $230/hour 3 partners @ $250/hour neutral when we 3 associates @ $130/hour 3 associates @ $150/hour adopted it would result in Cook being paid Average Billable Hours 1700 1800 nearly three times as Realization 90% 97% much as Abel in 1997,” Baker said. “Abel noted Revenue $1.65 million $2.10 million that his practice, like Expenses $1.20 million $1.20 million Cook’s, had supported a partner and an assoNet $450,000 $900,000 ($150,000/partner) ($300,000/partner) (Continued on page 36) May 2000 u Arizona Attorney 11 Law Firm Profits (Continued from page 11) ciate, and felt that a reduction in his compensation of no more than $75,000 was appropriate, with Cook receiving a comparable increase. Cook noted, however, that if Abel had made an economic contribution to the firm in 1997 equal to Cook’s, both would have received $445,000 in compensation. We were able to reach an acceptable compromise, but only by suspending application of our formula and taking a longer view of relative contributions. “Pressure on our partnership intensified in 1998,” Baker continued, “when Karen Abbott, the associate who had been working for Abel, told me that she had run out of work and would probably leave the firm if she were not reassigned. Because Cook and I were very busy at the time, we asked her to work on our matters. Unfortunately, Abel continued to struggle and, once again, the year 36 Arizona Attorney u May 2000 ended with firm profits and partner billable hours unchanged from 1997. The only difference between 1998 and 1997 was that Cook and I now each supervised and provided work for all three associates. “Cook came to our compensation meeting at the close of 1998 with an analysis showing that for 1998 and for each of the two previous years, each associate’s efforts had contributed about $75,000 to the profits of the firm. Cook noted that strict application of our ‘economic contribution’ formula (which would allocate all profits from the associates to him and to me) would result in the following allocation of the firm’s $900,000 in profits in 1998: Abel Baker Cook $80,000 $337,500 $482,500 “The arithmetic was indisputable,” Abel said. “But we each knew that I could no longer be part of the firm if we allocated profits in this manner. Once again, we were able to reach an agreement, but Cook and Baker told me that they could not be expected to subsidize my practice indefinitely. In fact, I had been working continuously to rebuild my practice and, fortunately, those efforts paid off in 1999. Once again, I was able to provide fulltime work for myself and Karen Abbott. In fact, the firm had to hire two new associates in 1999.” I suggested that one could draw three lessons from their experience. “First, modest improvements in effort, rates, realization or leverage can make an enormous impact on the profitability of the firm. Your firm’s modest increases in billing rates, hours recorded and realization resulted in a 100-percent increase in the firm’s profits in 1996. “Second, formulaic profit allocation models may be too inflexible to serve the best interests of the firm, particularly if they focus only on the economic contribution of each part- ner in the just-concluded year. Your firm’s model, which would have resulted in Cook making three times more than Abel in 1997 and six times more than Abel in 1998, was destabilizing, and arguably unfair. Fortunately, you recognized this and made the necessary accommodations. “Finally, however, it is also destabilizing (and unfair to the highly productive partners) for a firm to carry a partner whose economic contribution is consistently disappointing. Cook was correct in 1997 when he noted that if Abel had matched Cook’s economic contribution to the firm, Cook would have made more money. A law firm’s compensation system must be flexible enough to give partners like Abel the opportunity to overcome a bad break, but a firm that routinely requires its most productive members to subsidize its least productive members is headed for trouble.” “In fact,” said Baker, “those are the very lessons we took from our experience. Of course, making as much money as possible was not the reason we became lawyers, or decided to practice law together. We believe that if you consistently hire talented and energetic people who aspire to provide outstanding service to all clients all the time, it is not difficult to operate profitably. We spend far more energy trying to become better lawyers than focusing on our bottom line.” Cook offered the last word. “Even if you focus solely on law firm economics, as we have tonight, most firms in the real world are vastly more complicated than ours. Not all partners originate all of their own work, not all clients or practices are equally profitable and not all partners make the same intangible contributions to the firm and the community. These factors need to be considered when assessing how to fairly distribute the firm’s profits. Fair-minded people can come to different conclusions about what is fair, as Abel and I did in 1997. Be we believe that the basic principles you identified are correct.” WE DON’T WANT YOUR MONEY!! The MCLE deadline is quickly approaching, and the late compliance fees can add up!! Review your CLE file now to insure you’ll have the required 15 hours completed by June 30, 2000. For a listing of the available seminars, please see our Web site: www.azbar.org/CLE/. For more information or assistance with the deadline, call the MCLE Hotline at (602) 340-7300, or send e-mail to [email protected] Joseph Mais is an attorney with Brown & Bain, P.A. May 2000 u Arizona Attorney 37
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz