Adaptation working paper Page 1 07/04/2004 CLIMATE ADAPTATION: ACTIONS, STRATEGIES AND CAPACITY FROM AN ACTOR ORIENTED PERSPECTIVE Stockholm Environment Institute Oxford Working Paper Lead authors:1 Tom Downing, Sukaina Bharwani, Stuart Franklin, Cindy Warwick and Gina Ziervogel SEI Oxford Office 10b Littlegate Street Oxford OX1 1QT, UK Tel/Fax: +44 1865 202070/80 [email protected] Contributing authors: Mike Bithel, Edmund Chattoe, Mark New, and Richard Washington Draft: November 2003 Introduction Adaptation to climate—from present hazards to future changes in climate as both resource and hazard—is well on the way toward being mainstreamed as part of sustainable resource management. Many bilateral and international organizations have developed programmes on climate risk management, including early warning systems, disaster preparedness, vulnerability assessment, or seasonal climate prediction—important aspects of climate change adaptation. The literature on specific measures to cope with climatic variability and hazards has been articulate for some years, and corresponding studies of adaptive capacity are proliferating (benchmarked against the IPCC, McCarthy et al., 2001, see Adger et al. 2003 for an example of a broad review). Underlying frameworks, conceptual maps and analytical paradigms are not in short supply. Although adaptation has a long academic history in social sciences, this literature rarely reviews historical developments of thinking about cultural adaptation or risk management (see Abel 1998, Bennett 1976, Ellen 1982, and Henrich 2002 for examples from anthropology). At the same time, however, adaptation to climate change presents distinct challenges, primarily due to the complexity of local-global resource management, the time scales involved and the multi-actor dynamic nature of responding to changes in longer term climatic regimes as well as episodes of climatic hazard. This working paper presents an actor-oriented map of adaptation nomenclature. Our intention is to develop an operational scheme for translating conceptual frameworks of adaptation planning 1 Contributing authors are welcome—let us know if you would like to further develop the working paper, add a case study or suggest additional hypotheses. Adaptation working paper Page 2 07/04/2004 onto decision making models that are oriented toward stakeholders and institutions. Under the general rubric of actor-oriented frameworks, the SEI-Oxford office is developing multi-agent models of responses to climatic variations and climate change (for background on social simulation see Doran et al. 1994, Dyke 1981, Fischer 2002, Gilbert and Troitzsch 1999, Hegmon 1989, and Kippen 1998). A requirement of such endeavours is a clear language for discussing adaptation among a multi-disciplinary team and a scheme for treating adaptation with the formal language of a model. This actor-oriented perspective of climatic variability and climate change imposes specific challenges on our search for a concise set of definitions and analytical terms. An analytical approach should: • Integrate present risk management and responses to climatic episodes (and other perturbations) with long term formulation of strategies and resource planning. • Integrate the formulation of broad strategies with the choice of specific adaptation actions: strategies are built up from actions; actions inherit attributes of strategies. • Differentiate between the strategies and actions employed by different actors. • Link behaviour across geographic scales, so actions at one level are influenced by and influence actions at a higher or lower scale. • Link explicitly to the evaluation of actions, including multi-criteria assessment. • Integrate with rational decision-making (but not rely on optimizing strategies) that can be represented in formal models. • Explore the relationship between actors and the evolution of negotiated behaviour or conflicts; allow actors to learn over time, on their own and as members of institutions or regimes. • Generate hypotheses that can be tested in field work and analytical models. Below, we briefly review existing adaptation terms, including the IPCC Third Assessment Report, then present our nomenclature. Case studies from ongoing research projects illustrate how the approach may be used, initially based on field work in Limpopo Province, South Africa.2 We conclude by suggesting the kinds of hypotheses which the actor-oriented approach could test. Framing Adaptation Literature on climate adaptation tends to into distinct groups. Most papers include a conceptual framework or wiring diagramme. For example, the IPCC Third Assessment Report chapter on adaptation (Smit et al. 2001) includes several flow charts. The Kasperson and Kasperson (2001) vulnerability/adaptation diagramme suggests geographic scale (local-regional-global), intersecting with flows from geophysical hazard and socio-economic vulnerability to impacts, adjustments and adaptations. While ‘wiring diagrammes’ are proliferating, it is clear that there is no consensus on operational definitions and much less on analytical approaches. Common conclusions include (paraphrasing colleagues): 2 An expanded version of this working paper will have case studies from East Anglia as part of a project with the University of Oxford School of Geography and Environment (funded by the Tyndall Centre) and Orissa District of India from a project with the National Centre for Agricultural Economics and Policy Research (funded by the U.N. Environment Programme). Adaptation working paper • • • • Page 3 07/04/2004 We’ve gone from dumb farmers to clairvoyant farmers, but need to understand smart farmers and farmer-victims. We cannot measure adaptive capacity, and therefore have given up on trying to measure success in adaptation. What is the adaptation baseline? Is it the thresholds (guardrails) in a coping range? Or is it the qualitative nature of institutional regimes and their resilience? If we can’t predict climate change vulnerability, how can we plan adaptation? Following on from the search for indicators of vulnerability, coarse-level statistical descriptions and typologies seek to capture relative adaptive capacity. For example, indicators at the country level might include GDP per capita, literacy and transparency of governance. Such exercises imply a view of adaptive capacity as the inverse of vulnerability. For example, the Battelle group have experimented with national adaptive capacity indicators extracted from their global change model (Moss et al. 2000). Case studies of specific actors, locales or sectors are increasingly common. Most rely on qualitative information and institutional analysis, at best weakly linked to formal models or hypothesis testing. For example, Brooke (2004) progresses from climate scenarios in Costa Rica to vegetation and land use impacts to a stakeholder-institutional analysis of adaptation regimes in the Guanacaste region. Various proposals have recommended a systematic analysis of the case study material in an effort similar to the analysis of land use change by the LUCC programme. A common definition of vulnerability is the relationships between climate (as hazard or resource) and impacts, for example as the depth-damage function for flood events. Adding in adaptive options provides a quasi-empirical form for evaluating adaptive potential. For example, a benchmark study for the World Bank coupled a catastrophe model of climatic hazards in Central America with a macro-economic model to explore the role of national savings and international ‘insurance’ in national-level adaptation (Freeman and Warner 2001). Even from this cursory review of existing approaches it is clear that the prevalent frameworks for defining adaptation tend to distinguish between: • The scale of action, whether local actors making specific decisions or institutional capacity to monitor, learn and respond as and when appropriate. • The timing of responses, e.g. whether anticipatory or reactionary. • Effectiveness, whether the maximum potential (including new opportunities) or the vagaries of real-world action (including maladaptation) The IPCC TAR provides the benchmark for definitions regarding climate change (see box). However, additional conceptual work is ongoing, notably through the UNDP Adaptation Planning Framework (see www.undp.org/cc/apf_outline.htm) Tyndall Centre projects (see http://www.geog.ox.ac.uk/research/projects/cloud/index.html) the exigencies of the National Adaptation Programmes of Action (NAPA) exercises (see www.unitar.org/ccp/napaworkshops/ ) and other collective efforts. The research community has faced the same challenge for vulnerability. To some extent the major elements of vulnerability have been well characterised for some years—although there is Adaptation working paper Page 4 07/04/2004 continuing confusion about specific definitions and operational vulnerability assessments. Earlier papers have suggested a formal nomenclature for vulnerability terms (see the Downing paper in Smith, Klein and Huq 2003). Adaptation terms defined in IPCC WGII Third Assessment Report Adaptation Adjustment in natural or human systems in response to actual or expected climatic stimuli or their effects, which moderates harm or exploits beneficial opportunities. Various types of adaptation can be distinguished, including anticipatory and reactive adaptation, private and public adaptation, and autonomous and planned adaptation: • • • • • • Anticipatory Adaptation—Adaptation that takes place before impacts of climate change are observed. Also referred to as proactive adaptation. Autonomous Adaptation—Adaptation that does not constitute a conscious response to climatic stimuli but is triggered by ecological changes in natural systems and by market or welfare changes in human systems. Also referred to as spontaneous adaptation. Planned Adaptation—Adaptation that is the result of a deliberate policy decision, based on an awareness that conditions have changed or are about to change and that action is required to return to, maintain, or achieve a desired state. Private Adaptation—Adaptation that is initiated and implemented by individuals, households or private companies. Private adaptation is usually in the actor's rational self-interest. Public Adaptation—Adaptation that is initiated and implemented by governments at all levels. Public adaptation is usually directed at collective needs. Reactive Adaptation—Adaptation that takes place after impacts of climate change have been observed. See also adaptation assessment, adaptation benefits, adaptation costs, adaptive capacity, and maladaptation. Adaptation Assessment The practice of identifying options to adapt to climate change and evaluating them in terms of criteria such as availability, benefits, costs, effectiveness, efficiency, and feasibility. Adaptation Benefits The avoided damage costs or the accrued benefits following the adoption and implementation of adaptation measures. Adaptation Costs Costs of planning, preparing for, facilitating, and implementing adaptation measures, including transition costs. Adaptive Capacity The ability of a system to adjust to climate change (including climate variability and extremes) to moderate potential damages, to take advantage of opportunities, or to cope with the consequences. Source: IPCC. 2001. Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Annex B: Glossary of Terms (http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc_tar/wg2/index.htm). Adaptation working paper Page 5 07/04/2004 An actor-oriented nomenclature Here we propose a set of specific notations derived from the formal requirements of representing adaptation in agent-based social simulation. The nomenclature represents a continuum from an adaptation action to strategies, which are related to adaptive capacity and adaptive potential. Before describing the terms in detail: • An adaptation action is a specific response that an actor can implement. • An adaptation strategy is a set of actions that an actor can chose from. • Adaptive capacity is the super set of adaptive strategies, that is the combined set of actions that exist within the domain of an individual actor. • Adaptive potential is the ability of actors in a system to create new strategies and actions. An adaptation action (Xa,i) is an action (i) that can be implemented by an actor (a). It corresponds to the notion of a measure in greenhouse gas inventories. An action is a specific action that exists at present and could be implemented. For example, changing the planting date is an action in cropping systems. Each action (Xa,i) includes several attributes, such as: • information required to enact the action, such as market forecasts, • resources required to enact the action, including financial, labour and materials, • expected outcome (which may be a complex function), and • linkages to other actors (an action may require approval by other actors). The adaptation actions that are actually chosen and implemented at a given point of time form a subset of Xa,i. This might be denoted as X*a,i. An adaptation strategy (Aa,j) is the set of adaptation actions, defined as: Aa,j = {Xa,1, … Xa,n} The adaptation strategy, formulated by an actor (a), consists of the specific actions (Xa,i) available to the actor. As a strategy, however, Aa,j includes attributes of a systemic nature. The main feature of a strategy is to include explicit goals or objectives that guide the choice of which actions to implement. These strategies are ‘real’—they have been identified by the actors, they are composed of specific actions that can be implemented, and they can be communicated to other actors (although it is not necessary that every actor knows what other actors will do). An actor is likely to have more than one strategy (j). For example, if the regulatory regime (at a higher level of decision making) moves toward a market economy, then the actor may adopt strategy (Aa,1) whereas a common property regime would imply strategy (Aa,2). There might be some overlap in the elements of each strategy, however different rules would govern their implementation. Adaptation strategies (and by implication the adaptation actions) available to a specific actor depends on social networks. For instance, if the actor is isolated from information, markets and materials and constrained to decision making in the current season, then the adaptation strategies are those in practice in the local area. However, most actors have access to wider networks, at least to the district and probably the national level. At the global level the pool of strategies and actions would be quite large for every sector. Whether they are ‘available’ to the local community depends on processes of technology transfer, innovation and diffusion, and lead entrepreneurs who demonstrate the local case for the strategy and/or action. Adaptation working paper Page 6 07/04/2004 The nature of decision making at the strategic level is less clear than for individual actions within a strategy. For instance, if a farmer decides to improve her crop yields, the available tools are known and choices can be represented as problems in economic, cultural or social network decision making. However, farmer decision making regarding investment in off-farm employment is likely to be more complex and situated in the social, economic and political environment. Negotiation processes are inherent to resolving the choice the strategies and the rules by which actions are implemented within each actors’ strategy. The domain of adaptation actions and strategies is represented by the matrix: Da = Aa,1 = { Xa,1, … Xa,n } Aa,2 = { Xa,1, … Xa,n } … Aa,n = { Xa,1, … Xa,n } With a subset comprising those actions actually implemented (e.g., X*a,n). Adaptive capacity (A’) is related to the set of adaptive strategies: A’ = {Aa,1, … Aa,n} That is, the macro-level attributes of actors capacity to adapt (whether wealth, information, role in social institutions or other factors) can be related to the set of strategies that an actor has available. For the moment, we leave open whether A’ relates to specific actors (with a subscript, a) or is a property of an institution or resource management regime (represented as a collection of actors). This notation leads to a specific hypothesis. If Aa,i = Ø (there are no adaptation actions in the set) then adaptive capacity is low. Or more generally, the number of identified strategies (j in Aa,j) by a group of stakeholders (their portfolio) is often suggested as a measure of adaptive capacity. That is, the existence of a range of options that could be implemented is a measure of adaptive capacity. A better measure of adaptive capacity would be the potential effectiveness of the different strategies. For instance, a generalised risk assessment might be used to estimate the outcomes of a number of stresses and shocks and to estimate the resilience of actors. However, an unresolved issue is how to measure the effectiveness of adaptive capacity. For adaptation actions and actor-specific strategies, we can default to criteria defined by the actors themselves in choosing the specific actions. For instance, a threshold of food self-sufficiency may be desirable and guide the choice of crops grown by smallholders. The measures of adaptive capacity among a set of actors is more difficult. It is likely to include notions of resilience (e.g., livelihood security), reward (e.g., economic costs and benefits), social networks (e.g., maintenance of family obligations) and opportunities (e.g., successfully managing a transition from farming to wage labour). Adaptation working paper Page 7 07/04/2004 Adaptive potential (A”) is one step removed from adaptive capacity (A’). It links the systemic driving forces of socio-institutional change (income, technology, etc.) to actor/stakeholder adaptive capacity. Adaptive potential includes the ability to innovate, whether creating new strategies and actions or to find existing ones outside the actor’s customary network. A” is the relationship between system properties and the adaptive capacity (specific sets of strategies) of actors/stakeholders. Thus, we see A” as a system property not uniquely related to specific stakeholders (and does not have the subscript, a). Modelling adaptive potential might be implemented as a matrix of transfer coefficients, but it is by no means clear what functions are suitable and could be validated. A first step is to take socio-economic reference scenarios and construct plausible linkages to actors’ adaptive capacity. This can be qualitative—some options would not be available—as well as quantitative—the outcome of some options depends on system behaviour, such as the regulated price of water for abstraction. What are some salient features of the proposed notation? First, it is possible to translate the generic framing of adaptation into actor-oriented models. For instance, it is relatively straight-forward to propose specific actions for an agent to draw upon on in a multi-agent model. Secondly, specific hypotheses can be formulated. These might relate to the number of actions or strategies, the attributes of the actions, or the intersection of strategies between competing or cooperating agents. Third, the nomenclature does not relate to a specific stimulus. That is, we have proposed a generic way of implementing adaptation planning in a model. It would be relatively simple to add a leading superscript, say (c) to denote climate change. In practise it might be more difficult to distinguish between adaptive actions relating to a specific stimulus from an actor-oriented planning framework that integrates across stresses to achieve some goal (albeit as a satisficing decision maker). Fourth, the confusion in the IPCC terminology is apparent. In the IPCC glossary, adaptation is the elasticity between exposure to a stimulus and its consequences. It implies something that can be measured (and a baseline established) and is ongoing (actual). However, adaptation also can be the expected value of an elasticity in the future (based on expectations of a stimulus and its response). And, adaptive capacity is a system property of potential ability, neither actual nor related to specific threats. This corresponds more closely to our adaptive potential (A”). However, the IPCC includes climatic variability, so it is wider than climate change adaptation. The IPCC definitions cover a wide range of ground. Should all possible future adaptation be discounted to a present value? Are adaptations related to every climatic stimulus? How is adaptation negotiated when different stimulus suggest conflicting responses? It is hard to define counter-examples of what would not be adaptation or adaptive capacity (as long as it has some benefit in terms of resource management and human welfare). Adaptation working paper Page 8 07/04/2004 The IPCC includes various types of adaptation. But these are no more than a catalogue of specific characteristics, both for the types of specific actions as well as for the systemic processes. They would be attributes of the classes of Xa,i and Aa,i noted above. It is possible to relate aspects of the IPCC definitions to the above notation (see Table 1). The conflation of adaptation to climatic variability and (longer run) climate change can be framed as a hypothesis: • Adaptive capacity to climate variability (e.g., the set of strategies related to drought) increases adaptive capacity to climate change (e.g., a change in the frequency, magnitude and duration of drought in 2050). This is one of the hypotheses in our modelling of seasonal climate prediction and climate change adaptation in Limpopo Province. Scale is embedded in this nomenclature. From the actions of individuals to meta-level properties of adaptive capacity and potential is an increasing scale of abstraction and psycho-social organisation. However, it is not evident that actors are only individuals nor that adaptive potential is necessarily systemic. Institutions (and organisations) can act – a financial system can raise interest rates. Equally, actors inherit some of the properties of institutions to which they belong (and are active in constructing and changing those properties). The progression from Xa,i to A’’ is not simply geographic. Table 1. Adaptation nomenclature and related characteristics Xa,i Timing Reaction to a stimulus (at least a forecast of the stimulus) Aa,j Anticipatory, designed to cover a range of stimulus A’ Autonomous in the sense that it triggers an adaptive strategy and choice of Xi, or structural and anticipatory Meta-level property A” Actor Individual actor or organisation, dominated by private implementation May be common to many stakeholders, close links to public sector, e.g., through regulation As for As,i but often developed by a group of stakeholders, e.g., a public/private partnership Determinates Decision modes, information, human and financial resources Property of institutions Resources (human, financial, social) are important As above, but more emphasis on strategic planning Broader attributes of stakeholders and institutions, related to strategic planning, human and social capital Adaptation working paper Page 9 07/04/2004 An example: Food security in South Africa This section illustrates the notation and typology with an example from South Africa.3 Rural farming households in Limpopo Province employ a number of adaptation strategy sets in their challenging environment. Some strategy sets focus on agricultural-related activities, whilst others focus on off-farm means of securing a livelihood. For example, households might have strategy sets that concentrate on on-farm agronomy, whilst other strategy sets might concentrate on household consumption and expenditure and how to interact and use the market. Livestockrelated strategies, off-farm income, migration and the use of common resources are other types of strategy sets. Different households may have different strategy sets, and rely on them to differing degrees. Some households might employ a number of strategy sets with equal emphasis, while other households might focus on a single strategy. Over time it is likely that households will alter their strategy sets and the relative emphasis on one or another. Within each strategy set a number of actions contribute to the success of the strategy. Some household might pursue many actions that relate to the strategy set, whilst others might specialise in a few key actions. Our example from Limpopo Province focuses on a village that have dryland fields, common grazing land and shares in a community irrigation scheme. They are relatively poor households, but grow a mixture of food and market crops and generally have quite good access to local and even regional markets. For instance, if the irrigation water is adequate, many households grow tomatoes for sale to juice processors in the region. Our field work and modelling, using agentbased social simulation, has focused on the use of seasonal climate forecasts. Table 2 shows three strategy sets typical in this region and a range of actions that fall within each set (based on field interviews over the past three years). Table 2. Rural household strategy sets and actions On-farm agronomy Change cropping density Adjust planting date Invest in irrigation Plant more land Strategy sets (Aa,j) Household consumption & expenditure Eat grain stores rather than saving seed for planting the following year* Eat livestock Sell chicken eggs rather than eating them* Buy new uniforms for children Fertilise more in wet year Send sick household members to the clinic Plant marketable plants rather than subsistence crops* Eat fewer meals per day or week Market trading Determine what is in demand in the market* Negotiate with traders to sell produce Access market information about prices Take produce to market (instead of selling on-farm) Take produce to regional market (with larger number of consumers) rather than local market * Action that bridges between two (or more) strategy sets. 3 Additional case examples are being compiled, and contributing authors are welcome too. Adaptation working paper Page 10 07/04/2004 Each of these strategy sets is affected by climate variability in some way, whether directly or indirectly. By assessing the actions within each strategy set, it is possible to start to determine how the climate might affect adaptation actions and so influence household strategies. Understanding how and when strategy sets change is critical to understanding present adaptation and future adaptive capacity. Each action and strategy set has a number of attributes that help assess the likelihood of the action being followed and its outcome. Above, we suggested that key attributes of actions include: • resources required to enact the action, • expected outcome, and • linkages to other actors A number of actions fall within the on-farm agronomy strategy set for the emerging farmers of Limpopo Province. For example, planting drought resistant varieties, increasing the diversity of crop types, adjustment of planting dates or increasing fertilizer use are all actions that could contribute to pursuing on-farm agronomy as a livelihood strategy set (see Table 3). A matrix of qualitative ratings (low, medium and high in terms of cost or effectiveness) for each of the attributes is included in the table. The ratings are shown for a wet year and a dry year—evidently farmers have different strategies to manage risk and the expected outcomes are contingent upon the nature of the season (as well as other factors). An intensification strategy based on fertilizer application has low information requirements and low to medium requirements for resources or community action. However, the outcome is strongly affected by whether there is enough moisture (whether through rainfall or irrigation) to increase yields substantially. There are also linkages to market strategies—a modest increase in irrigated yield is valuable in a dry year. Table 3. Example of on-farm agronomy in Limpopo Province Strategy set: On-farm agronomy Action: Increase fertilizer application Expected outcome Information required to enact Resources needed Increase yield Knowledge of how fertilizer increases yield Expected rainfall--if too heavy will wash away fertilizer, if not enough then might be a waste to invest in fertilizer when yields will be constrained by moisture Money or fertilizer Improve soil conditions Ratings Wet: Dry: H L L L Ability to transport fertilizer to field M L Linkages to other actors Information source about fertilizer Source of money to buy fertilizer L L Adaptation working paper Page 11 07/04/2004 Other factors might also be considered when assessing the role of each action within the strategy set. For example: • Does pursuing the action have a long-term or short-term goal? • Is the goal of pursuing the action in anticipation of poor yields, for example or a reaction to other driving forces, such as the availability of resources? • Is a change in actions or strategies a function of local changes, such as a new extension officers who supports the use of fertilizer, or institutional forcing, such as subsidies for fertilizer use. The analysis of each strategy set, and the actions within it, can help to establish a baseline of adaptation strategies. With a baseline of current practice, subsequent analysis can focus on adaptive capacity and adaptive potential. These more complex measures require an assessment of the circumstances under which actions and strategies shift so that households can respond or adapt more effectively to the environmental stimuli. Further methodological considerations The framework proposed above is not (as yet) a complete analytical protocol. Three further considerations are necessary: • How do actors make decisions about the choice of strategies and actions? • How can scenarios of global change relate to actor-specific adaptation? • What is the relationship between the hierarchy of adaptation and the wider set of criteria often proposed in the literature? • What formal hypotheses about adaptation emerge from this preliminary analysis? Choice and decision making The adaptation nomenclature suggested here aids in describing the range of choice and clarifying at what level of decision making (when, by whom, in response to what) key choices are made. In modelling adaptation an algorithm is required to replicate the real-world decisions of actors. Within agent based simulation this is a topic of ongoing debate and development (e.g., , Conte and Casterlfranchi 1995, D’Andrade 1995, Kippen 1998). At this stage, we offer the outline of a strategy rather than specific solutions. It is possible to construct agents that have access to complete knowledge about the range of choice and their expected outcomes and make optimising judgements. This might provide insight into some aspects of adaptation potential but is unlikely to capture the more interesting aspects of ‘real world’ behaviour. At other end of the spectrum, an approach to decision making might be based on ‘grounded reality’ and ‘stylised facts’. Choices made by real actors are observed and replicated through a relatively simple rule-based engine. For instance, a sequence of scenarios might be presented to individuals or groups and their responses entered into a data base. Rules relating the conditions of the scenarios can then be developed and incorporated into a model. Such an approach is in progress in Limpopo project described above. While analytically tractable, such rule bases are often static, constrained to relatively simple choices, and appropriate for the kinds of problems where historical conditions and choices are relevant guides to behaviour. Adaptation working paper Page 12 07/04/2004 More sophisticated approaches require resolving some elements of internal decision making and the influence of other actors. Representation of individual goals and objectives could filter the range of choice. Actions that are successful might be endorsed, or weighted more strongly in subsequent decision making. A weighting of what other actors are doing can be achieved, discriminating perhaps among similar actors or those with greater authority. From scenarios to actions The overwhelming majority of global change scenarios are static visions of future conditions derived from broad trends in environment, economies, technology and society (e.g., Raskin et al. 2002). These ‘driving forces’ are often assumed to apply across scales—geographically to local communities, economically to livelihoods and socially to individual decision making (see Warwick et al. 2003 for a discussion of scale in water scenarios). Table 4 maps common driving forces onto the hierarchy of adaptation proposed here. Immediately apparent from the connections is that global scenarios tend to focus on the conditions of adaptive capacity and the implied decision making in the choice of strategies. For instance, environmental attitudes are presumed to influence household proclivity to adopt say organic farming rather than commercial, high-input farming. Fewer and perhaps weaker connections are made to specific actions and to the global range of potential adaptive responses. Also, it is difficult to make a direct connection between population growth (or size) and specific levels of the adaptation framework. Included in the table is a suggestion of how climate information links to the levels of adaptation. In carrying out specific actions, operational forecasts are possibly important. Outcomes of the chosen actions feedback into subsequent the choice of strategies and actions. The choice of strategies and longer term development of capacity and potential are related to risk management. A key requirement for actor-oriented scenarios would be to resolve the flow of information and range of responses from potential to actions. That is, scenarios should make explicit which actors have access to global domains of potential responses and which actors are responsible for translating the global toolkit into locally available and suitable actions. The timing of such processes will be critical—not all actors readily will have the ability to increase their range of strategies or actions. Translating adaptation criteria to actors Adaptation to climate change (and climatic variability and hazards) has received significant attention in the literature for at least a decade. Early work, summarised in the IPCC TAR (Smit et al. 2001) presented a range of typologies and lists of criteria by which to judge adaptation responses. How do these criteria relate to the actor-oriented approach proposed here? An early (and convenient) typology of attributes of adaptation was compiled in a CICERO/World Bank project (Ringius et al., 1996, Downing et al. 1997). The attributes and criteria from this typology are matched against the levels of adaptation in Adaptation working paper Page 13 07/04/2004 Table 5. The focus on actors and stakeholders maps onto the decision making in actions and strategies. Attributes of specific actions (such as the timing of costs and benefits) fits within the attributes of actions. Most of the attributes and criteria are relevant to strategy sets and adaptive capacity. However, few of the criteria suggested in existing typologies really address the longer term domain of adaptive potential and the ability to learn and adopt new strategies. Apparently, most typologies assume (quite rightly) that presently available coping strategies are sufficient and the barriers are not new technologies but the social, economic and institutional framework for adopting successful strategies. Table 4. Mapping global scenarios onto adaptation actions Driving forces Adaptation Climate information Forecast Outcome Risk Notes Population Economy Actions (X) ‘Downscaled’ from larger conditions, logic of decision making, and trends and status of economy, institutions and environment Technology Governance & institutions Strategies (A) Environmental attitudes Health Capacity (A’) Central to ‘top-down’ scenarios, link to strategies Potential (A’’) Not strongly connected except through technology Preferences & modes of decision making Environment & resources Inferred from capacity, strong links to economy, governance, environment Notes: Climate information relates to: Forecast of a climatic event or outcome in operational decision making; the outcome or impact of climatic events; and longer term risk management anticipating potential climate states. Adaptation working paper Page 14 07/04/2004 Priority stakeholder Is there a stakeholder or vulnerable group that should be given priority for targeting adaptive strategies? Resource conflicts Are there conflicts over resource use between or among different stakeholders? Would such conflicts affect the ability to design and implement specific adaptive strategies? Multiple benefits Does the adaptation have benefits for a number of objectives and stakeholders? Specificity to predicted climate change Does the adaptation only have benefits if climate changes in the expected direction? Effectiveness How effective is the adaptation in coping with the expected climate change? Is there a critical threshold beyond which the response will not be effective 2. Resilience and purposeful adaptation Effective adaptive response build upon present capabilities to enhance resilience to climatic variations. Beyond this level of response, purposeful adaptation may be justified in some sectors and for some projects. 3. Strategic Does the action have a role in developing institutional capacity or in planning future responses? 4. Timing There is a gap between the implementation of adaptation strategies and the realization of their benefits. Facilitating adaptation Many of the most cost-effective adaptive response have yet to be identified. In such cases, fundamental research and stimulation of innovation may be warranted. Development pathways The role of adaptation in shaping future development needs to be assessed. Costly response now may limit investment and constrain development. This is a general issue, but may apply for specific projects and activities. Matching planning horizon What is the planning horizon required to design and implement the adaptation? For how long is the adaptation useful? Irreversible impacts Matching the timing of an adaptive response and its benefits may need to consider the possibility of irreversible impacts and option values. √ √ √ Potential 1. Stakeholder analysis Adaptive responses are specific to or most appropriate for certain stakeholders Capacity Specific Criteria Strategy Attribute Action Table 5. Adaptation criteria and actors √ √ √ √ √ √ √ √ √ √ Adaptation working paper 5. Cost benefit Economic evaluation of projects is well-defined, although contentious issues of discount rates, valuing environmental quality, and equity remain. 6. Constraints for adoption Adaptations will only be effective if they are widely adopted, with relatively efficient means of dissemination and maintenance. Page 15 Initial investment by stakeholders The initial investment by stakeholders may be a constraint, either because of poverty and lack of credit among some stakeholder or because the expected return is low compared to other economic investments. The difference between public and private objectives and economic decision making may be important in such cases. Timing of benefits The return on investment depends on the timing of the benefits. Most of the strategies suggested under a resilient development scenario would have fairly immediate benefits. Those that depend on long term climate change would have a stream of future benefits that might be very low in the near future. Both social and market discounting tend to reduce the present value of future benefits. Realization of benefits The benefits may not accrue to the stakeholder that makes the investment. The beneficiaries are future generations, or other present social and economic groups. This is a common problem of equity in public interventions in resource management. A common issue is coping with climatic hazards is public liability and financing (through taxation) of vulnerable populations. Information Information about the strategy, its utility and means of implementing it may be lacking. Also, available information may not be communicated effectively. Technical development The adaptation may not be technically reliable, or it may require a level of technical development that is not available for all stakeholders. Natural resources and environment Agroclimatic, land use and other resource constraints may limit adaptation options. Social, cultural and political barriers Many of the most significant barriers to innovation are institutional, encompassing the social norms of behaviour, cultural means of communication and decision making, and political processes of empowerment and participation. 07/04/2004 √ √ √ √ √ √ √ √ √ √ √ Adaptation working paper Page 16 07/04/2004 Hypotheses regarding adaptation measures and strategies What hypotheses emerge from this framework? While we maintain that the context (of adaptation capacity, A’) is essential, we can use the terms introduced above to suggest hypotheses in ways that further case studies and model results might begin to resolve: 1. If Aa,i = Ø (there are no adaptation actions in the set) then adaptive capacity is low. That is, the existence of a strategy without specific actions also identified (along with their attributes for decision making) does not contribute greatly to adaptive capacity. An example might be a move to organic farming for export of specialist crops without the farmer knowing what is required in order to achieve the strategy. 2. The number of identified strategies (j in Aa,j) by a group of stakeholders (their portfolio, a measure of diversification) is a measure of resilience and adaptive capacity. That is, the existence of a range of options that could be implemented is a measure of adaptive capacity. 3. Alternatively, a small number of actions or strategies, if successful historically, indicates specialisation and a shift from survival to integration in market economies. Such specialisation is a measure of adaptive capacity. Having a large number of strategies practiced by an actor competes for managerial expertise, skill and resources. 4. Information on seasonal climate forecasts (or climatic variability and longer run change) is of greater benefit with a larger number of actions available to the actor. 5. Adaptive capacity is not simply the number of strategies but some weighting of their likelihood of success. 6. Most critical for long term climate change is learning and adoption of strategies that already exist but are not available in the immediate network of the actor. 7. Changing the emphasis or priority of strategies requires or responds to factors at the community or national level (or beyond). Such hypotheses can be translated into statements that can be tested in formal models with support from field work. Conclusions This working paper has put forward a formal notation and hierarchy of adaptation terms. It draws upon an actor-oriented approach and the demands of agent-based social simulation. The framework clarifies some conflicts in existing terms and provides a strong link to formal research and models of adaptive behaviour. A formal framework of this sort opens up a set of empirical tests for further research. For example: • How similar are actions (X) across actors and environments? • How effective are actions in response to climatic threats? What might an aggregate response curve look like? Are there areas where the anticipated effects are beyond present coping ranges? • How effective are actions across multiple stresses? • Are there synergies in strategies and actions for different stresses? Adaptation working paper Page 17 07/04/2004 We conclude that an actor-oriented approach is possible as a bridge between qualitative, in-depth field work and formal testing of system properties of resilience and adaptive capacity. Fully implementing such a system would provide richer scenarios of future threats and a platform for interactive exploration of behaviour. Acknowledgements The stimulus for this working paper initially has been two projects of the SEI and School of Geography and Environment at the University of Oxford, funded in part by the Tyndall Centre. The Cloud project is exploring the utility of seasonal climate outlooks in adaptation to climate change in South Africa. An integrated regional project on adaptation by farmers focuses on the linkages between land and water management in East Anglia. Collectively, we have benefited from many discussions with colleagues around the world. Of particular note have been the meetings of the AIACC project (including the vulnerability and adaptation course in Trieste), UNDP Adaptation Planning Framework process, Tyndall cluster meetings and UNEP side events at UNFCCC conferences. References Abel, T. (1998). Complex adaptive systems, evolutionism, and ecology within anthropology: Interdisciplinary research for understanding cultural and ecological dynamics. Georgia Journal of Ecological Anthropology, 2:629. Adger, N., Huq, S., Brown, K., Conway, D., and Hulme, M. (2003) Adaptation to climate change in the developing world. Progress in Developing Studies 3(3): 179-195. Bennett, J. W. (1976). The Ecological Transition: Cultural Anthropology and Human Adaptation. Pergamon Press Inc. Brooke, C. (2002) Adaptation to climate variability and change: El Niño events and humanlandscape interactions. PhD Dissertation. Oxford: School of Geography and Environment. Conte, R. and Castelfranchi, C. (1995) Cognitive and Social Action. London: UCL Press. D’Andrade, R. (1995). The Development of Cognitive Anthropology. Cambridge University Press. Doran, J., Palmer, M., Gilbert, N., and Mellars, P. (1994). Simulating Societies: The computer simulation of social phenomena, chapter The EOS project: modelling Upper Paleolithic social change, pages 195221. UCL Press. Downing, T.E. (2003) Lessons from famine early warning and food security for understanding adaptation to climate change: Toward a vulnerability/adaptation science? In Climate Change, Adaptive Capacity and Development. Smith, J.B., R.J.T. Klein and S. Huq (eds.). London: Imperial College Press. Downing, T.E., Ringius, L., Hulme, M. and Waughray, D. (1997) Adapting to climate change in Africa: Prospects and guidelines. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change 2(1): 19-44. Ellen, R. (1982). Environment, Subsistence and System: The Ecology of Small-scale Social Formations. Cambridge University Press. Adaptation working paper Page 18 07/04/2004 Fischer, M. D. (2002). Integrating anthropological approaches to the study of culture: The "hard" and the "soft". Cybernetics and Systems 2002: Proceedings of the 16th European Meeting on Cybernetics and Systems Research, (1):367372. Freeman, P. and K. Warner (2001). Vulnerability of infrastructure to climate variability: how does this affect infrastructure lending facilities? Washington: World Bank and ProVention consortium. Gilbert, N. and Troitzsch, K. G. (1999). Simulation for the Social Scientist. London: Open University Press. Hegmon, M. (1989). Risk reduction and variation in agricultural economies: a computer simulation of Hopi agriculture. Research in economic anthropology, 11:89121. Henrich, J. (2002). Decision-making, cultural transmission and adaptation in economic anthropology. www.umich.edu, pages 146. Kasperson, J. X. and R. E. Kasperson (2001). International Workshop on Vulnerability and Global Environmental Change, 17-19 May 2001,Stockholm Environment Institute (SEI) Stockholm, Sweden: A workshop summary, Stockholm, SEI. (see www.sei.se) Kippen, J. (1998). On the uses of computers in anthropological research. Current Anthropology, 29(2):317320. McCarthy, J. J., O. F. Canziani, et al., Eds. (2001). Climate change 2001: Impacts, adaptation, and vulnerability. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press for the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). Moss, R., A. Brenkert, et al. (2000). Measuring Vulnerability: A Trial Indicator Set. Washington: Batelle Pacific NW Lab. Raskin, P., Banuri, T., Gallopin, G., Gutman, P., Hammond, A., Kates, R. and Swart, R. (2002) Great Transition: The Promise and Lure of Times Ahead. Boston: SEI. Ringius, L., Downing, T.E., Hulme, M., Waughray, D. and Selrod, R., (1996) Climate Change in Africa - issues and challenges in agriculture and water for sustainable development. CICERO Report 1996:8, Oslo, Norway. Smit, B. et al. 2001: Adaptation to climate change in the context of sustainable development and equity. In McCarthy, J.J., Canziani, O., Leary, N.A., Dokken, D.J. and White, K.S., editors, Climate change 2001: impacts, adaptation and vulnerability. IPCC Working Group II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 877–912. Smith, J.B., R.J.T. Klein and S. Huq (eds.), 2003: Climate Change, Adaptive Capacity and Development. London: Imperial College Press. Warwick, C., Bakker, K., Downing, T.E. and Lonsdale, K. (2004) Scenarios as a tool in water management: Considerations of scale and application. In Water Resources Perspectives: Evaluation, Management and Policy, A.S. Alsharhan and W.W. Wood (editors). Oxford: Elsevier Science.
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz