APPENDIX B Poisson process and derivation of Bellman equations 1. Poisson process Let us first define the exponential distribution. Definition B.1. A continuous random variable X is said to have an exponential distribution with parameter λ > 0 if its cumulative distribution function (cdf) is given by: F (t) = P {X < t} = 1 − e−λt for all t ≥ 0. This implies that the probability density function (pdf) is equal to: f (t) = λe−λt for all t ≥ 0. The exponential distribution has mean Z+∞ 1 E [X] = t f(t)dt = λ 0 and variance £ ¤ 1 V [X] = E X 2 − (E [X])2 = 2 λ It is straightforward to show the following proposition: Proposition B.1. The exponential distribution with parameter (or rate) λ > 0 has the following properties: (i) Independence: P {X > t + t0 } = P {X > t} P {X > t0 } (ii) Memoryless P {X > t + t0 | X > t} = P {X > t0 } ∀t, t0 ≥ 0 Observe that the exponential distribution is the unique distribution possessing the memoryless property. Following Ross (1996), let us now define a counting process (and its properties) and then a Poisson process. 395 396 B. POISSON PROCESS AND DERIVATION OF BELLMAN EQUATIONS Definition B.2. Let {Xn , n ≥ 1} be a sequence of random variables representing the inter-event times. Define S0 = 0, Sn = X1 + ... + Xn . Then Sn is the time of occurrence of the nth event. Define S(t) = max {n ≥ 0 | Sn ≤ t} , t ≥ 0 Thus S(t) represents the total number of events that have occurred up to time t. A stochastic process {S(t), t ≥ 0} is called a counting process. Definition B.3. A counting process {S(t), t ≥ 0} is said to possess: (a) independent increments if the number of events which occur in disjoint intervals are independent, i.e. for 0 ≤ t1 ≤ ... ≤ tn , the increments S(t1 ), S(t2 ) − S(t1 ), ..., S(tn ) − S(tn−1 ) are independent random variables. (b) stationary increments if the distribution of the number of events which occur in any interval of time only depends the length of the time interval, i.e. the distribution of X(t + t0 ) − X(t0 ) is independent of t0 . A Poisson process is frequently used as a model for counting events occurring one at a time. Let us now define formally a Poisson process. Definition B.4. The counting process {S(t), t ≥ 0} is said to be a Poisson process having rate λ > 0, if: (i) The process has stationary and independent increments; (ii) The number of events in any interval of length t is Poisson distributed with mean λt. That is, for all t ≥ 0, P {S(t) = n} = e−λt (λt)n , n! n = 0, 1, ... (B.1) We have the following alternative definition:1 Definition B.5. The counting process {S(t), t ≥ 0} with S(0) = 0 is said to be a Poisson process having rate λ > 0, if: (i) The process has stationary and independent increments; 1A function f : R → R is said to be an o(h) function if lim h→0 f (h) =0 h 1. POISSON PROCESS 397 (ii) P {S(h) = 1} ≡ P {S(t + h) − S(t) = 1} = λh + o(h); (iii) P {S(h) ≥ 2} ≡ P {S(t + h) − S(t) ≥ 2} = o(h). This definition helps us understand how “randomness in time” can be interpreted. Condition (i) implies that what happens under non-overlapping time intervals is independent. Condition (ii) states that rate λ is constant over time while condition (iii) says that two (or more) events cannot occur at the same time. Ross (1996) shows that these two definitions (i.e. definitions B.4 and B.5) are equivalent. Example B.1. Consider a person who receives a lot of “junk” mails in his/her mailbox. Assume that the number of “junk” mails follows a Poisson process having rate 2 per hour. B.1.1. What is the probability that no “junk” mail arrives between 9 am and 11 am? This probability is defined by P {S(11) − S(9) = 0}. Using Definition B.4 and in partic- ular equation (B.1), we obtain (for λ = 2): 0 −2t (2t) P {S(11) − S(9) = 0} = e 0! = e−2×2 ∼ = 0.0183. Observe that, because of time homogeneity, this probability is the same as the probability that no “junk” mail arrives between 2:00 pm and 4:00 pm or any other times as long as there are two hours difference. B.1.2. What is the expected number of “junk” mails that arrive during 8 hours? The expected number of “junk” mails that arrive during 8 hours is: E [S(8)] = λ × 8 = 16. B.1.3. What is the probability that one “junk” mail arrives between 1:00 pm and 2:00 pm and two “junk” mails arrive between 1:30 pm and 2:30 pm? Using time homogeneity and using hours as units of time, let us start at t = 0 (which corresponds to 1:00 pm here) so that 2:00 pm corresponds to t = 1 (here, 1 hour corresponds to 1 unit of time). Then, 1:30 pm corresponds to t = 0.5 and 2:30 pm to t = 1.5. Thus, the probability that one “junk” mail arrives between 1:00 pm and 2:00 pm and two “junk” mails arrive between 1:30 pm and 2:30 pm can be written as: P {S(1) = 1, S(1.5) − S(0.5) = 2} . 398 B. POISSON PROCESS AND DERIVATION OF BELLMAN EQUATIONS Using the fact that increments over (0, 0.5], (0.5, 1], and (1, 1.5] are independent, we can write the following: P {S(1) = 1, S(1.5) − S(0.5) = 2} 1 P P {S(0.5) = n, S(1) − S(0.5) = 1 − n, S(1.5) − S(1) = 1 + n} . = n=0 Let us explain this last equation. We divide time in three intervals: (0, 0.5], (0.5, 1], and (1, 1.5], that is between 1:00 pm and 1:30 pm, 1:30 pm and 2:00 pm, 2:00 pm and 2:30 pm. Then, in order to have 1 “junk” mail between t = 0 (i.e. 1:00 pm) and t = 1 (i.e. 2:00 pm), it has to be that either no “junk” mail arrives between t = 0 and t = 0.5 (i.e. 1:30 pm) and 1 arrives between t = 0.5 and t = 1 or 1 “junk” mail arrives between t = 0 and t = 0.5 and 0 arrives between t = 0.5 and t = 1. Similarly, in order to have 2 “junk” mails between t = 0.5 and t = 1.5 (i.e. 2:30 pm), it has to be that either no “junk” mail arrives between t = 0.5 and t = 1 and 2 arrive between t = 1 and t = 1.5 or 2 “junk” mails arrive between t = 0.5 and t = 1 and 0 arrives between t = 1 and t = 1.5 or 1 “junk” mail arrives between t = 0.5 and t = 1 and 1 arrives between t = 1 and t = 1.5. By combining all these possibilities, it has to be that: P {S(1) = 1, S(1.5) − S(0.5) = 2} = P {S(0.5) = 0, S(1) − S(0.5) = 1, S(1.5) − S(1) = 1} +P {S(0.5) = 1, S(1) − S(0.5) = 0, S(1.5) − S(1) = 2} . In other words, either no “junk” mail arrives between t = 0 and t = 0.5 and 1 “junk” mail arrives both between t = 0.5 and t = 1 and between t = 1 and t = 1.5, or 1 “junk” mail arrives between t = 0 and t = 0.5, 0 “junk” mail between t = 0.5 and t = 1 and 2 between t = 1 and t = 1.5. 1. POISSON PROCESS 399 We have: 1 P n=0 = 1 P n=0 = 1 P P {S(0.5) = n, S(1) − S(0.5) = 1 − n, S(1.5) − S(1) = 1 + n} P {S(0.5) = n} × P {S(1) − S(0.5) = 1 − n} × P {S(1.5) − S(1) = 1 + n} e−1 n=0 1 P (1)n −1 (1)1−n −1 (1)1+n e e n! (1 − n)! (1 + n)! 1 n=0 n! (1 − n)! (1 + n)! µ ¶ 1 −3 1+ = e = 1.5e−3 ' 0.0747. 2 = e−3 Consider a Poisson process {S(t), t ≥ 0} and denote the time of the first event by T1 . Moreover, for n > 1, let Tn denote the elapsed time between the (n − 1)th and the nth event. The sequence {Tn , n = 1, 2, ...} is called the sequence of interarrival times. We can now determine the distribution of the Tn . We have the following result: Proposition B.2. Tn , n = 1, 2, are independent identically distributed (i.i.d.) exponential random variables having mean 1/λ. This means, in particular, that P {T1 > t} = P {S(t) = 0} = e−λt and P {T2 > t | T1 = t0 } = e−λt etc. Furthermore, the arrival time of the nth event, also called the waiting time until the nth event and denoted by Σn , is given by Σn = n P Ti , i=1 n≥1 Σn has a gamma distribution with parameters n and λ. That is, the probability density of Σn is: fΣn (t) = λe−λt (λt)n−1 (n − 1)! 400 B. POISSON PROCESS AND DERIVATION OF BELLMAN EQUATIONS 2. An intuitive way of deriving the Bellman equations Let us first derive the expected lifetime-utility of an unemployed worker IU . This analysis is valid for both search-matching (Part 1) and efficiency wage (Part 2) models. During a small interval of time dt, the unemployed worker obtains WU and during this time, he/she may find a job and enjoys an expected lifetime-utility level of IE at time t + dt. The probability that he/she finds a job is: adt + o(dt) with lim o(dt)/dt = 0. If he/she does not find a job, dt→0 then he/she enjoys utility IU at time t + dt. Observe that, during this small interval of time dt, the probability that the unemployed worker leaves unemployment and then straightaway loses his/her new job is negligible with respect to dt (since it is a term in (dt)2 ). We have:2 IU (t) = WU (t)dt + 1 [adt IL (t + dt) + (1 − adt)IU (t + dt)] . 1 + rdt This is equivalent to (1 + rdt) IU (t) = (1 + rdt) WU (t)dt + adt IL (t + dt) + (1 − adt)IU (t + dt) ⇔ rIU (t)dt = WU (t)dt + rWU (t)(dt)2 + adt [IL (t + dt) − IU (t + dt)] + IU (t + dt) − IU (t). Now, by dividing everything by dt, we obtain (observe that (dt)2 is negligible compared to dt) rIU (t) = WU (t) + a [IL (t + dt) − IU (t + dt)] + IU (t + dt) − IU (t) . dt By taking the limit when dt → 0, we get · rIU (t) = WU (t) + a [IL (t) − IU (t)] + IU (t) since · IU (t) ≡ dIU (t) IU (t + dt) − IU (t) = lim . dt→0 dt dt · In steady-state, IU (t) = 0 and IU (t) = IU and IL (t) = IL . The steady-state lifetime expected utility of an unemployed worker is given by: rIU = WU + a (IL − IU ) . 2We could have discounted in a different way, IU (t) = 1 [WU (t)dt + adtIE (t + dt) + (1 − adt)IU (t + dt)] 1 + rdt i.e. before starting the period. In this case, it is easily verified that the Bellman equation would have been exactly the same. 3. A FORMAL WAY OF DERIVING THE BELLMAN EQUATIONS 401 Let us now determine the expected lifetime-utility of a non-shirking employed worker IL . We have: IL (t) = WLN S (t)dt + £ ¤ 1 δdt IU (t + dt) + (1 − δdt)ILN S (t + dt) . 1 + rdt By replicating the same analysis as for the unemployed, we easily obtain for employed workers: rIL = WLNS − δ (IE − IU ) . Let us now focus more specifically on efficiency wage models (Part 2). Determining the case of shirking is more complicated since shirking workers can lose their jobs either by an exogenous shock δ or by being caught shirking at rate m. We have ILS (t) = WLS (t)dt + £ ¤ 1 δdt IU (t + dt) + mdt IU (t + dt) + (1 − (δ + m) dt) ILS (t + dt) . 1 + rdt By replicating the same analysis, we obtain: ¡ ¢ rILS = WLS − (δ + m) ILS − IU . (B.2) 3. A formal way of deriving the Bellman equations As stated above, changes in employment status are assumed to be governed by a Poisson process with two states: employed or unemployed. Consider a Poisson process (as defined by Definition B.4 or Definition B.5). As shown in Proposition B.2, the key feature of these stochastic processes is that the duration time spent in each state is a random variable with exponential distribution. More precisely, if we denote the (random) unemployment and employment duration times by Ta and Tδ , then F (Ta ) = P {Ta < t} = 1 − e−a Ta F (Tδ ) = P {Tδ < t} = 1 − e−δ Tδ . This implies that the probability densities are given by: f (Ta ) = a e−a Ta (B.3) f(Tδ ) = δ e−δ Tδ . (B.4) 402 B. POISSON PROCESS AND DERIVATION OF BELLMAN EQUATIONS As a result, the average time spent in each state is equal to (see Definition B.1): E [Ta ] = = Z +∞ Ta f(Ta )dTa 0 Z +∞ a Ta e−a Ta dTa 0 = Z +∞ 0 = − = 1 a £ ¤+∞ e−a Ta dTa − Ta e−a Ta 0 ¤+∞ 1 £ −a Ta ¤+∞ £ e − Ta e−a Ta 0 0 a since lim Ta e−a Ta = lim Ta e−a Ta = 0. Ta →+∞ Ta →0 Similarly, E [Tδ ] = Z +∞ 0 1 Tδ f(Tδ )dTδ = . δ As above, let us first determine the expected lifetime-utility of an unemployed worker, IU . It is given by: IU = ETa ∙Z Ta −rt WU e −rTa dt + e 0 ¸ IL . (B.5) IU is thus the discounted value at time t = 0. The unemployed worker remains unemployed during a random period of time Ta . During this period, he/she earns wU discounted at rate r. Then, after this period Ta , he/she becomes employed and obtains an expected utility of IL discounted at rate r starting at time t = Ta . By developing (B.5), we obtain: IU = +∞ Z ∙Z 0 Ta 0 +∞ ¸ Z −rt WU e dt f (Ta )dTa + e−rTa IE f(Ta )dTa . 0 Since Z 0 Ta −rt WU e dt = WU ∙ ¸ 1 − e−rTa , r 3. A FORMAL WAY OF DERIVING THE BELLMAN EQUATIONS 403 and using (B.3), it can be rewritten as: IU WU = a r +∞ Z 0 ¡ ¢ 1 − e−rTa e−a Ta dTa + aIL +∞ Z e−rTa e−a Ta dTa 0 ⎤ ⎡+∞ +∞ Z Z ¢ WU ⎣ ¡ −a Ta −(r+a)Ta = a −e e dTa ⎦ + a IL e−(r+a)Ta dTa r 0 = 0 a WU + IL . r+a r+a We finally obtain: rIU = WU + a (IL − IU ) . (B.6) Similarly, we can calculate the expected lifetime-utility of an employed worker IL (non shirking in the efficiency wage model). It is: ∙Z NS IL = ETδ Tδ WLNS e−rt dt −rTδ +e 0 By making exactly the same analysis, one easily obtains: ¸ IU . rILNS = WLNS − δ (IL − IU ) . (B.7) (B.8) For the efficiency wage model, we need to consider the case of a shirker. It is more complicated since, when employed, a shirker can lose his/her job because either he/has been caught shirking or the job has been destroyed. Denote by Tm the (random) length of time until the next control of shirking occurs. This implies that Ta is still the (random) unemployment duration time whereas min(Tδ , Tm ) is now the employment duration time for a shirker. Since we know (see, for example, Kulkarni, 1995, ch. 5) that min(Tδ , Tm ) is a random variable characterized by an exponential distribution of parameter δ + m, i.e. F (min(Tδ , Tm )) = P [min(Tδ , Tm ) < t] = 1 − e−(δ+m) min(Tδ ,Tm ) then the expected lifetime-utility of a shirker ILS is equal to: # "Z min(Tδ ,Tm ) ILS = E WLS e−rt dt + e−r min(Tδ ,Tm ) IU . 0 By doing exactly the same kind of manipulations as above, we obtain (B.2).
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz