Inspection games with long-run inspectors

DIPARTIMENTO DI ECONOMIA
_____________________________________________________________________________
Inspection games with long-run inspectors
Luciano Andreozzi
_________________________________________________________
Discussion Paper No. 21, 2008
The Discussion Paper series provides a means for circulating preliminary research results by staff of or
visitors to the Department. Its purpose is to stimulate discussion prior to the publication of papers.
Requests for copies of Discussion Papers and address changes should be sent to:
Dott. Luciano Andreozzi
E.mail [email protected]
Dipartimento di Economia
Università degli Studi di Trento
Via Inama 5
38100 TRENTO ITALIA
Inspection games with long-run inspectors.
Luciano Andreozzi
Universita degli Studi di Trento
Facolta di Economia
Via Inama, 5 - 38100 Trento Italy
[email protected]
November 2008
Abstract
A single, long-run policeman faces a large population of myopic wouldbe criminals. This paper shows that this interaction has counterintuitive
comparative static properties. A forward-looking inspector might tolerate
more law violations than a short-sighted one.
Paper presented at the EPCS conference, Belgirate, April 2002, and SIDE-ISLE Conference, Bologna, November 2008. I would like to thank M. Holler, R. Joosten, G. Tsebelis, L.
Franckx and R. Cressmann for useful discussions and suggestions. Usual caveats apply.
1
1
Introduction
Game theoretical models of law-enforcement (Graetz e.a. [12], Tsebelis [16] [17],
Holler [11], Franckx [6], Saha and Poole [14], Cressmann e.a. [5], Andreozzi [1])
show a puzzling analogy with the predator-prey relationships studied in theoretical ecology: they have conterintuitive comparative static properties and
generate oscillations. Let start with comparative statics. Killing predators will
not reduce the number of predators, but will only increase the number of their
preys. Similarly, killing preys will only reduce the number of predators. In the
law enforcement literature a mathematically analogous result holds true. Increasing penalties will not reduce crime, but will only reduce the frequency of
police inspections. In general, the only way to change the behavior of would-be
criminals is to modify the policemen's payo s and vice versa. This result has
been taken as a proof that the standard economic approach to crime deterrence
inspired to Gary Beker's [3] seminal paper (that neglects strategic considerations) might be awed. (Tsebelis [16], Holler [11].)
Oscillations are due to the hypothesis that police agents and criminals form
two distinct populations of short-lived and myopic agents. Policemen inspect
would-be transgressors as long as they expect some of them to violate the law,
but they quit inspecting when they realize that violations are almost never
committed. However, if police do not inspect, then violations become more
frequent and this brings about a new wave of inspections. The analogies with
the oscillations of predator-prey relationships are obvious.
The hypothesis that both actors involved are myopic is not always realistic.
There are cases in which police is best modelled as a single, forward-looking actor, who faces a large population of myopic would-be transgressors. Examples
of this kind of interaction abound. Just think about the relationship between
tax-auditors and tax-payers, or police crews and motorists on highways. The
present paper asks the following question: should one expect to see more or
less crime if the police force is a long-lived, forward-looking agent rather than
a myopic one? (Neher [13] asks a similar question concerning the economics of
crime.) One might conjecture that a forward-looking police force will not quit
inspecting when law infractions become rare, because it anticipates that the
number of infractions will rise again if it does. Hence one would predict no oscillations and a lower level of crime in equilibrium. This paper shows that this
intuition is partially mistaken. Contrary to what one might expect, as the police
force becomes more forward-looking, more crime, not less, might be observed
in equilibrium. Some technical conditions at which such a counterintuitive phenomenon can take place are investigated. I will also show that these conditions
are ful lled by some of the games discussed in the literature, for example by
Saha and Poole [14].
2
Violate
Not Violate
Inspect
a11; b11
a21; b21
Not Inspect
a12; b12
a22; b22
Table 1: The Inspection Game
2
The inspection game
Consider the game in Figure 2. Player A must decide whether to V iolate a given
law or a regulation. B is an inspector, or a police o cer, who might Inspect
him. The entries of the two matrices satisfy the following inequalities: a12 > a22
(violating the law is pro table if police does not inspect), a21 > a11 (respecting
the law is the best strategy if police inspect), b11 > b12 (police prefers to inspect
if the public violates the law) and b22 > b21 (police rather not inspect if the
public respects the law). Let p be the probability with which A plays V iolate
and q the probability with which B plays Inspect. The game has a single mixed
strategy Nash equilibrium:
(p ; q ) = (
b22
b22
b21
b21
;
b12 + b11 a22
a22
a12
a12
)
a21 + a11
(1)
Suppose now that the game is played repeatedly by pairs of individuals drawn
at random from two large populations A (the public) and B (the police). In
each population, strategies that yield a payo larger than the average within that
population are assumed to increase, crowding out strategies that yield lowerthan-average payo s. This might re ect a process of learning, imitation and so
on. (See Weibull [18] for an accessible introduction to evolutionary models of
this kind.)
Formally, let p and q be the fractions of A and B that play V iolate and
Inspect respectively. I will assume that the learning and imitation process will
induce p and q to change over time according to the Replicator Dynamics (RD):
p_
q_
= p(1
= q(1
p)(
q)(
B
1 (q)
A
1 (p)
B
2 (q)) =
A
2 (p)) =
p(1
q(1
p)(q
q)(p
q)
p )
(2a)
(2b)
where
a22 +a21 +a12 a11 > 0 and = b22 b21 b12 +b11 > 0. A
i (p),
are the expected payo s of adopting strategy i (i = 1; 2) in population A
and B. It is a well known fact in evolutionary game theory that the fractions p
and q oscillate constantly, although their averages converge to the equilibrium
values p and q . (See Andreozzi [1] and Cressman e.a. [5] for an application of
this result to the logic of law enforcement.)
B
i (q)
3
Evolutionary policies
The evolutionary model in the previous section is based on the hypothesis that
both populations are made of limitedly rational and myopic players. Suppose
3
now that agent B is a a single organization (the police force, the tax authority
and so on.) The frequency q with which it plays Inspect will now re ect the long
term interest of this collective agent, instead of the aggregation of a multitude of
individual (myopic) choices. Nothing changes in population A, whose internal
dynamics is still represented by the di erential equation (2a).
Since now B is a rational, forward-looking player, she will choose a path
for the frequency q(t) with which she plays Inspect that maximizes the actual
value of the future stream of payo :
B
(p(t); q(t)) = b11 pq + b12 p(1
q) + b21 (1
p)q + b22 (1
p)(1
q)
subject to the constraint that the frequency p(t) of law infractions varies
according to (2a). Formally, B solves the following optimal control problem:
Z1
max( e
rt B
q
(p(t); q(t))dt
(3)
0
s:t:
p_ = p(1
p(0) = p0 2 (0; 1)
p)(q
q(t) 2 [0; 1]
1
q)
8t 2 [0; 1)
where r is B's time discount rate. The current-value Hamiltonian for this
problem is
H(p(t); q(t); m(t)) =
B
(p(t); q(t)) + m(t)[ p(1
p)(q
q)]
(4)
where the costate variable m(t) satis es2 :
@H
@
= rm
m (1 2p)(q
@p
@p
= m(r
(q
q)(1 2p))
(q q + ),
m
_ = rm
+ def
q)
(5)
b22 b12
b12 b21 +b22 .
where q = b11
A stationary optimal path is a triple (p; q; m)
such that p_ = m
_ = 0 for p = p; q = q and m = m, while for every q 6= q,
H(p; q; m) > H(p; q; m). If initially p0 = p, a rational inspector B maximizes
his payo s by setting q = q, so that p_ = m
_ = 0.
Lemma 1 The optimal control problem (3) has a unique stationary optimal
path:
q
= q ;
(q
m =
p
=
(m
(6)
+
q )
r
;
)
(7)
p
(m
2m
)2 + 4m
p
(8)
1 Notice that the initial fraction of law infractions p has been restricted to the open interval
0
(0; 1). This is to avoid that the population gets locked in a steady state in which p_ = 0 even
if the two pure strategies yield di erent payo s.
2 Consider that it is easy (if tedious) to show that @ = (q
q + ).
@p
4
Proof. To see that (q; m; p) is a stationary optimal path for the control problem
(3) consider rst that for any p 2 (0; 1), p_ = 0 i q = q . If q = q , then equation
(5) reduces to m
_ = rm
(q
q + ), and hence
q+ )
(q
m
_ = 0 () m =
r
=m
(9)
Since q = q is an interior solution, we must have
@H(p; q; m)
= (p
@q
that is m p2 + p(
p12 =
m )
(m
p )
m p(1
p) = 0
(10)
p = 0. The roots of this equation are:
p
(m
)2 + 4m p
)
:
(11)
2m
It can be easily shown that the smaller of the two roots lies in the interval
[0; 1]. This is the only value of p that satisfy the optimality condition (10) and
the restriction on the state variable p 2 (0; 1). This completes the rst part of
the proof.
To see that (p; q; m) is the only stationary optimal path, consider that for
q 6= q p_ = 0 i p = 0 or p = 1. However, if p0 2 (0; 1), then p cannot reach
either 0 or 1 in a nite time (because p_ ! 0 as p approaches the borders of the
interval [0; 1]), so that if q 6= q then p_ 6= 0 for all t. This completes the proof.
The Hamiltonian (4) is linear in the control variable q and has a single
interior stationary optimal path.3 This implies that the optimal control problem
3 in the general case in which p0 6= p, has a particularly simple solution: B must
choose q in such a way that the state variable p approaches its optimal stationary
value p in the shortest time. This is the content of the following:
Proposition 2 1.The optimal strategy S for the long run inspector B is:
a) if p < p, then q = 0;
b) if p > p, then q = 1;
c) if p = p, then q = q .
2. Under the optimal strategy S, from any initial condition p0 2 (0; 1)
population A reaches its stationary optimal path level p in a nite time t. After
that time, B sets q = q so that p remains xed at p.
Proof. 1. Because of the linearity of the Hamiltonian (4), the optimal path
is the one that minimizes the time spent out of the optimal stationary path
(p; q; m). (Proofs of this fact can be found in Kamien and Schwarts [9], section
16, Takayama [15] and Clark [4].) Since arg max(p)
_ = 0 and arg min(p)
_ = 1, if
q
q
p < p (p > p), the optimal policy for B is to set q = 0 (q = 1). On the other
hand, if p = p, then q = q so that p_ = 0.
3 To
B (:; :)
see that the Hamiltonian in linear in q consider that the inspector's payo
is linear both in p and in q, and that RD is linear in q, although not in p.
5
function
2. Suppose that p0 < p (the case p0 > p can be treated similarly). In this
case B will set q = 0, so that equation (2a) reduces to a simple logistic equation
p_ = p(1
p)q
(12)
that can be integrated
p(t) =
where k = log
optimal level p is
(p0 1)
p0 .
1
1
exp(k
q t)
;
(13)
It follows that the time it takes to bring p to its
t=
1
[k
q
log(p
1)]:
(14)
which is bounded away from 1: After a time t, B will set q = q so that
p_ = 0:
Proposition 2 shows that population A will spend most of the time at p,
because the inspector will minimize the time it spends outside this state. Hence,
it is interesting to see how changes in the police's time discount rate r a ect p.
Proposition 3 (a) The optimal stationary value p converges to the stage game
Nash equilibrium value p ! p as r ! 1; (b) p > p and p ! 1 as r ! 0 if
q > q + ; (c) p < p and p ! 0 as r ! 0 if q < q + .
+
Proof. a) If r ! 1; m = (q r q ) ! 0. Recall that p is the smallest root of
m p2 + p(
m )
p = 0, which for m ! 0 reduces to p
p = 0, whose
only root is p = p :
+
b) If r ! 1, m = (q r q ) ! +1 if q > q + . Let rewrite condition (10) as
m =
(p
p(1
p )
p)
(15)
The left hand side approaches 1 as m ! +1 and hence p ! 1 (If p ! 0,
then the right hand side would approach 1). Similarly, the left hand side
approaches minus in nite as m ! +1, so that p ! 0.
Proposition 3 is the core of the paper. It proves that if the inspector is
rational, but myopic (r ! 1), it will keep the frequency of law violations
around its Nash equilibrium value p . This is not surprising: if p > p , the
inspector gets a larger payo if she plays Inspect. In so doing, however, she
reduces the frequency of law infractions p until it reaches the Nash equilibrium
level p . At this point Inspect and N ot Inspect yield the same payo . Similarly,
if initially p < p , a myopic inspector will play N ot Inspect because it yields a
larger immediate payo than Inspect. However, this will increase the frequency
of violations p until it reaches p .
When the inspector becomes more forward looking, (r ! 0) it will take into
consideration the future e ects of her current choices. Since he will not play
the strategy that yields the larger immediate payo , the optimal level of crime
6
violations p will be di erent from p . The interesting result of this analysis is
that increasing r will not necessarily reduce p below p . Proposition 3 shows
that this will happen only provided that q < q + . When the opposite inequality
holds true, a more forward looking inspector will tolerate more crime than a
short-sighted one.
4
Conclusions
Andreozzi [2] discusses a variant of the inspection game in which the inspector
can act as a Stackelberg leader of the game and he obtains a result similar to
those presented in Proposition 3. He shows that if the inspector can commit
himself to a probability of inspection, he will induce player A to play V iolate
if q > q + and to play N ot V iolate if q < q + . The present paper extends this
result to the case in which the inspector (who cannot commit to a probability
of inspection) is a long-run player facing a large population of short-sighted
opponents, in the the spirit of Fudenberg and Levine [7] [8]. All the consequences
of this result for the economic approach to law enforcement are discussed in
Andreozzi [2] and will not be repeated here.
References
[1] Andreozzi, L. (2002) \Oscillations in against-pollution policies. An evolutionary analysis," Homo Oeconomicus, 18 (3/4) 2002.
[2] Andreozzi, L. (2004) \Rewarding policemen increases crime: Another surprising result from the inspection game", Public Choice, 121 (1): 69-82
[3] Becker, G. S. (1968) \Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach",
Journal of Political Economy, 76: 169-217.
7
[4] Clark, C.W. (1990) Mathematical bioeconomics: the optimal management
of renewable resources, New York: John Wiley and Sons.
[5] Cressman, R., W. G. Morrison, and J.-F. Wen, (1998) \On the Evolutionary Dynamics of Crime", Canadian Journal of Economics, 31: 1101-1117.
[6] Franckx, L. (2002) \The use of ambient inspections in environmental monitoring and enforcement when the inspection agency cannot commit itself to
announced inspection probabilities", Journal of Environmental Economics
and Management, 43 (1): 71-92.
[7] Fudenberg, D. and D. K. Levine (1989) \Reputation and Equilibrium Selection in Games with a Patient Player", Econometrica, 57 (4): 759-778.
[8] Fudenberg, D. and D. K. Levine (1992) \Maintaining Reputation when
Strategies are Imperfectly Observed", Review of Economic Studies, 59: 561579.
[9] Kamien, M. and N. L. Schwartz (1981) Dynamic optimization. The calculus
of variations and optimal control in economics and management, New York:
North-Holland.
[10] Holler, M. J. (1990) \The Unpro tability of Mixed-strategy Equilibria: A
Second Folk-Theorem", Economics Letters, 32 (4): 319-323.
[11] Holler, M. J. (1992) \Fighting Pollution when Decisions are Strategic",
Public Choice, 76: 347-356.
[12] Graetz, M., J. Reinganum, and L. Wilde (1986) \The Tax Compliance
Game: Toward and Interactive Theory of Law Enforcement", Journal of
Law, Economics, and Organization, 2 (1): 1-32.
[13] Neher, P. A. (1978) \The Pure Theory of the Muggery", American Economic Review, 68 (3): 437-445.
[14] Saha, A. and G. Poole (2000) \The economics of crime and punishment:
An analysis of optimal penalty", Economics Letters, 68: 191-196.
[15] Takayama, A. (1985) Mathematical Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
[16] Tsebelis, G. (1990) \Penalty has no Impact on Crime: A Game Theoretic
Analysis", Rationality and Society, 2 (3): 255-286.
[17] Tsebelis G. (1990) \Are Sanctions E ective? A Game Theoretic Analysis",
Journal of Con ict Resolution, 34 (1): 3-28.
[18] Weibull, J. W. (1995) Evolutionary Game Theory, Cambridge (Mass.) London: MIT Press.
8
Elenco dei papers del Dipartimento di Economia
2000.1 A two-sector model of the effects of wage compression on
unemployment and industry distribution of employment, by Luigi Bonatti
2000.2 From Kuwait to Kosovo: What have we learned? Reflections on
globalization and peace, by Roberto Tamborini
2000.3 Metodo e valutazione in economia. Dall’apriorismo a Friedman , by
Matteo Motterlini
2000.4 Under tertiarisation and unemployment. by Maurizio Pugno
2001.1 Growth and Monetary Rules in a Model with Competitive Labor
Markets, by Luigi Bonatti.
2001.2 Profit Versus Non-Profit Firms in the Service Sector: an Analysis of
the Employment and Welfare Implications, by Luigi Bonatti, Carlo
Borzaga and Luigi Mittone.
2001.3 Statistical Economic Approach to Mixed Stock-Flows Dynamic
Models in Macroeconomics, by Bernardo Maggi and Giuseppe Espa.
2001.4 The monetary transmission mechanism in Italy: The credit channel
and a missing ring, by Riccardo Fiorentini and Roberto Tamborini.
2001.5 Vat evasion: an experimental approach, by Luigi Mittone
2001.6 Decomposability and Modularity of Economic Interactions, by Luigi
Marengo, Corrado Pasquali and Marco Valente.
2001.7 Unbalanced Growth and Women’s Homework, by Maurizio Pugno
2002.1 The Underground Economy and the Underdevelopment Trap, by
Maria Rosaria Carillo and Maurizio Pugno.
2002.2 Interregional Income Redistribution and Convergence in a Model
with Perfect Capital Mobility and Unionized Labor Markets, by Luigi
Bonatti.
2002.3 Firms’ bankruptcy and turnover in a macroeconomy, by Marco Bee,
Giuseppe Espa and Roberto Tamborini.
2002.4 One “monetary giant” with many “fiscal dwarfs”: the efficiency of
macroeconomic stabilization policies in the European Monetary Union, by
Roberto Tamborini.
2002.5 The Boom that never was? Latin American Loans in London 18221825, by Giorgio Fodor.
2002.6 L’economia senza banditore di Axel Leijonhufvud: le ‘forze oscure del
tempo e dell’ignoranza’ e la complessità del coordinamento, by Elisabetta De
Antoni.
Why is Trade between the European Union and the Transition
Economies Vertical?, by Hubert Gabrisch and Maria Luigia Segnana.
2002.7
2003.1 The service paradox and endogenous economic gorwth, by Maurizio
Pugno.
2003.2 Mappe di probabilità di sito archeologico: un passo avanti, di
Giuseppe Espa, Roberto Benedetti, Anna De Meo e Salvatore Espa.
(Probability maps of archaeological site location: one step beyond, by
Giuseppe Espa, Roberto Benedetti, Anna De Meo and Salvatore Espa).
2003.3 The Long Swings in Economic Understianding, by Axel
Leijonhufvud.
2003.4 Dinamica strutturale e occupazione nei servizi, di Giulia Felice.
2003.5 The Desirable Organizational Structure for Evolutionary Firms in
Static Landscapes, by Nicolás Garrido.
2003.6 The Financial Markets and Wealth Effects on Consumption An
Experimental Analysis, by Matteo Ploner.
2003.7 Essays on Computable Economics, Methodology and the Philosophy
of Science, by Kumaraswamy Velupillai.
2003.8 Economics and the Complexity Vision: Chimerical Partners or
Elysian Adventurers?, by Kumaraswamy Velupillai.
2003.9 Contratto d’area cooperativo contro il rischio sistemico di produzione
in agricoltura, di Luciano Pilati e Vasco Boatto.
2003.10 Il contratto della docenza universitaria. Un problema multi-tasking,
di Roberto Tamborini.
2004.1 Razionalità e motivazioni affettive: nuove idee dalla neurobiologia e
psichiatria per la teoria economica? di Maurizio Pugno.
(Rationality and affective motivations: new ideas from neurobiology and
psychiatry for economic theory? by Maurizio Pugno.
2004.2 The economic consequences of Mr. G. W. Bush’s foreign policy. Can
th US afford it? by Roberto Tamborini
2004.3 Fighting Poverty as a Worldwide Goal by Rubens Ricupero
2004.4 Commodity Prices and Debt Sustainability by Christopher L.
Gilbert and Alexandra Tabova
2004.5 A Primer on the Tools and Concepts of Computable Economics by K.
Vela Velupillai
2004.6 The Unreasonable Ineffectiveness of Mathematics in Economics by
Vela K. Velupillai
2004.7 Hicksian Visions and Vignettes on (Non-Linear) Trade Cycle
Theories by Vela K. Velupillai
2004.8 Trade, inequality and pro-poor growth: Two perspectives, one
message? By Gabriella Berloffa and Maria Luigia Segnana
2004.9 Worker involvement in entrepreneurial nonprofit organizations.
Toward a new assessment of workers? Perceived satisfaction and fairness by
Carlo Borzaga and Ermanno Tortia.
2004.10 A Social Contract Account for CSR as Extended Model of Corporate
Governance (Part I): Rational Bargaining and Justification by Lorenzo
Sacconi
2004.11 A Social Contract Account for CSR as Extended Model of Corporate
Governance (Part II): Compliance, Reputation and Reciprocity by Lorenzo
Sacconi
2004.12 A Fuzzy Logic and Default Reasoning Model of Social Norm and
Equilibrium Selection in Games under Unforeseen Contingencies by
Lorenzo Sacconi and Stefano Moretti
2004.13 The Constitution of the Not-For-Profit Organisation: Reciprocal
Conformity to Morality by Gianluca Grimalda and Lorenzo Sacconi
2005.1 The happiness paradox: a formal explanation from psycho-economics
by Maurizio Pugno
2005.2 Euro Bonds: in Search of Financial Spillovers by Stefano Schiavo
2005.3 On Maximum Likelihood
Distributions by Marco Bee
Estimation of Operational Loss
2005.4 An enclave-led model growth: the structural problem of informality
persistence in Latin America by Mario Cimoli, Annalisa Primi and
Maurizio Pugno
2005.5 A tree-based approach to forming strata in multipurpose business
surveys, Roberto Benedetti, Giuseppe Espa and Giovanni Lafratta.
2005.6 Price Discovery in the Aluminium Market by Isabel FiguerolaFerretti and Christopher L. Gilbert.
2005.7 How is Futures Trading Affected by the Move to a Computerized
Trading System? Lessons from the LIFFE FTSE 100 Contract by
Christopher L. Gilbert and Herbert A. Rijken.
2005.8 Can We Link Concessional Debt Service to Commodity Prices? By
Christopher L. Gilbert and Alexandra Tabova
2005.9 On the feasibility and desirability of GDP-indexed concessional
lending by Alexandra Tabova.
2005.10 Un modello finanziario di breve periodo per il settore statale italiano:
l’analisi relativa al contesto pre-unione monetaria by Bernardo Maggi e
Giuseppe Espa.
2005.11 Why does money matter? A structural analysis of monetary policy,
credit and aggregate supply effects in Italy, Giuliana Passamani and
Roberto Tamborini.
2005.12 Conformity and Reciprocity in the “Exclusion Game”: an
Experimental Investigation by Lorenzo Sacconi and Marco Faillo.
2005.13 The Foundations of Computable General Equilibrium Theory, by K.
Vela Velupillai.
2005.14 The Impossibility of an Effective Theory of Policy in a Complex
Economy, by K. Vela Velupillai.
2005.15 Morishima’s Nonlinear Model of the Cycle: Simplifications and
Generalizations, by K. Vela Velupillai.
2005.16 Using and Producing Ideas in Computable Endogenous
Growth, by K. Vela Velupillai.
2005.17 From Planning to Mature: on the Determinants of Open Source
Take Off by Stefano Comino, Fabio M. Manenti and Maria Laura
Parisi.
2005.18 Capabilities, the self, and well-being: a research in psychoeconomics, by Maurizio Pugno.
2005.19 Fiscal and monetary policy, unfortunate events, and the SGP
arithmetics. Evidence from a growth-gap model, by Edoardo Gaffeo,
Giuliana Passamani and Roberto Tamborini
2005.20 Semiparametric Evidence on the Long-Run Effects of Inflation on
Growth, by Andrea Vaona and Stefano Schiavo.
2006.1 On the role of public policies supporting Free/Open Source Software.
An European perspective, by Stefano Comino, Fabio M. Manenti and
Alessandro Rossi.
2006.2 Back to Wicksell? In search of the foundations of practical monetary
policy, by Roberto Tamborini
2006.3 The uses of the past, by Axel Leijonhufvud
2006.4 Worker Satisfaction and Perceived Fairness: Result of a Survey in
Public, and Non-profit Organizations, by Ermanno Tortia
2006.5 Value Chain Analysis and Market Power in Commodity Processing
with Application to the Cocoa and Coffee Sectors, by Christopher L. Gilbert
2006.6 Macroeconomic Fluctuations and the Firms’ Rate of Growth
Distribution: Evidence from UK and US Quoted Companies, by Emiliano
Santoro
2006.7 Heterogeneity and Learning in Inflation Expectation Formation: An
Empirical Assessment, by Damjan Pfajfar and Emiliano Santoro
2006.8 Good Law & Economics needs suitable microeconomic models:
the case against the application of standard agency models: the case
against the application of standard agency models to the professions,
by Lorenzo Sacconi
2006.9 Monetary policy through the “credit-cost channel”. Italy and
Germany, by Giuliana Passamani and Roberto Tamborini
2007.1 The Asymptotic Loss Distribution in a Fat-Tailed Factor Model of
Portfolio Credit Risk, by Marco Bee
2007.2 Sraffa?s Mathematical Economics – A Constructive Interpretation,
by Kumaraswamy Velupillai
2007.3 Variations on the Theme of Conning in Mathematical Economics, by
Kumaraswamy Velupillai
2007.4 Norm Compliance: the Contribution of Behavioral Economics Models,
by Marco Faillo and Lorenzo Sacconi
2007.5 A class of spatial econometric methods in the empirical analysis of
clusters of firms in the space, by Giuseppe Arbia, Giuseppe Espa e
Danny Quah.
2007.6 Rescuing the LM (and the money market) in a modern Macro course,
by Roberto Tamborini.
2007.7 Family, Partnerships, and Network: Reflections on the Strategies of
the Salvadori Firm of Trento, by Cinzia Lorandini.
2007.8 I Verleger serici trentino-tirolesi nei rapporti tra Nord e Sud: un
approccio prosopografico, by Cinzia Lorandini.
2007.9 A Framework for Cut-off Sampling in Business Survey Design, by
Marco Bee, Roberto Benedetti e Giuseppe Espa
2007.10 Spatial Models for Flood Risk Assessment, by Marco Bee, Roberto
Benedetti e Giuseppe Espa
2007.11 Inequality across cohorts of households:evidence from Italy, by
Gabriella Berloffa and Paola Villa
2007.12 Cultural Relativism and Ideological Policy Makers in a Dynamic
Model with Endogenous Preferences, by Luigi Bonatti
2007.13 Optimal Public Policy and Endogenous Preferences: an Application
to an Economy with For-Profit and Non-Profit, by Luigi Bonatti
2007.14 Breaking the Stability Pact: Was it Predictable?, by Luigi Bonatti
and Annalisa Cristini.
2007.15 Home Production, Labor Taxation and Trade Account, by Luigi
Bonatti.
2007.16 The Interaction Between the Central Bank and a Monopoly Union
Revisited: Does Greater Uncertainty about Monetary Policy Reduce Average
Inflation?, by Luigi Bonatti.
2007.17 Complementary Research Strategies, First-Mover Advantage and
the Inefficiency of Patents, by Luigi Bonatti.
2007.18 DualLicensing in Open Source Markets, by Stefano Comino and
Fabio M. Manenti.
2007.19 Evolution of Preferences and Cross-Country Differences in Time
Devoted to Market Work, by Luigi Bonatti.
2007.20 Aggregation of Regional Economic Time Series with Different
Spatial Correlation Structures, by Giuseppe Arbia, Marco Bee and
Giuseppe Espa.
2007.21 The Sustainable Enterprise. The multi-fiduciary perspective to the
EU Sustainability Strategy, by Giuseppe Danese.
2007.22 Taming the Incomputable, Reconstructing the Nonconstructive and
Deciding the Undecidable in Mathematical Economics, by K. Vela
Velupillai.
2007.23 A Computable Economist’s Perspective on Computational
Complexity, by K. Vela Velupillai.
2007.24 Models for Non-Exclusive Multinomial Choice, with Application to
Indonesian Rural Households, by Christopher L. Gilbert and Francesca
Modena.
2007.25 Have we been Mugged? Market Power in the World Coffee
Industry, by Christopher L. Gilbert.
2007.26 A Stochastic Complexity Perspective of Induction in Economics and
Inference in Dynamics, by K. Vela Velupillai.
2007.27 Local Credit ad Territorial Development: General Aspects and the
Italian Experience, by Silvio Goglio.
2007.28 Importance Sampling for Sums of Lognormal Distributions, with
Applications to Operational Risk, by Marco Bee.
2007.29 Re-reading Jevons’s Principles of Science. Induction Redux, by K.
Vela Velupillai.
2007.30 Taking stock: global imbalances. Where do we stand and where are
we aiming to? by Andrea Fracasso.
2007.31 Rediscovering Fiscal Policy Through Minskyan Eyes, by Philip
Arestis and Elisabetta De Antoni.
2008.1 A Monte Carlo EM Algorithm for the Estimation of a Logistic Autologistic Model with Missing Data, by Marco Bee and Giuseppe Espa.
2008.2 Adaptive microfoundations for emergent macroeconomics, Edoardo
Gaffeo, Domenico Delli Gatti, Saul Desiderio, Mauro Gallegati.
2008.3 A look at the relationship between industrial dynamics and aggregate
fluctuations, Domenico Delli Gatti, Edoardo Gaffeo, Mauro Gallegati.
2008.4 Demand Distribution Dynamics in Creative Industries: the Market
for Books in Italy, Edoardo Gaffeo, Antonello E. Scorcu, Laura Vici.
2008.5 On the mean/variance relationship of the firm size distribution:
evidence and some theory, Edoardo Gaffeo, Corrado di Guilmi, Mauro
Gallegati, Alberto Russo.
2008.6 Uncomputability and Undecidability in Economic Theory, K. Vela
Velupillai.
2008.7 The Mathematization of Macroeconomics: A Recursive Revolution,
K. Vela Velupillai.
2008.8 Natural disturbances and natural hazards in mountain forests: a
framework for the economic valuation, Sandra Notaro, Alessandro Paletto
2008.9 Does forest damage have an economic impact? A case study from the
Italian Alps, Sandra Notaro, Alessandro Paletto, Roberta Raffaelli.
2008.10 Compliance by believing: an experimental exploration on social
norms and impartial agreements, Marco Faillo, Stefania Ottone, Lorenzo
Sacconi.
2008.11 You Won the Battle. What about the War? A Model of Competition
between Proprietary and Open Source Software, Riccardo Leoncini,
Francesco Rentocchini, Giuseppe Vittucci Marzetti.
2008.12 Minsky’s Upward Instability: the Not-Too-Keynesian Optimism of
a Financial Cassandra, Elisabetta De Antoni.
2008.13 A theoretical analysis of the relationship between social capital and
corporate social responsibility: concepts and definitions, Lorenzo Sacconi,
Giacomo Degli Antoni.
2008.14 Conformity, Reciprocity and the Sense of Justice. How Social
Contract-based Preferences and Beliefs Explain Norm Compliance: the
Experimental Evidence, Lorenzo Sacconi, Marco Faillo.
2008.15 The macroeconomics of imperfect capital markets. Whither savinginvestment imbalances? Roberto Tamborini
2008.16 Financial Constraints and Firm Export Behavior, Flora Bellone,
Patrick Musso, Lionel Nesta and Stefano Schiavo
2008.17 Why do frms invest abroad? An analysis of the motives underlying
Foreign Direct Investments Financial Constraints and Firm Export
Behavior, Chiara Franco, Francesco Rentocchini and Giuseppe Vittucci
Marzetti
2008.18 CSR as Contractarian Model of Multi-Stakeholder Corporate
Governance and the Game-Theory of its Implementation, Lorenzo Sacconi
2008.19 Managing Agricultural Price Risk in Developing Countries, Julie
Dana and Christopher L. Gilbert
2008.20 Commodity Speculation and Commodity Investment, Christopher
L. Gilbert
2008.21 Inspection games with long-run inspectors, Luciano Andreozzi
PUBBLICAZIONE REGISTRATA PRESSO IL TRIBUNALE DI TRENTO