Emil Lobe Suenson, Peter Nedergaard and Peter Munk Christiansen Why do you want to lash yourself to the mast? The case of the Danish “Budget Law” Abstract: The article examines the conditions that led to the adoption of the Danish 2012 “Budget Law”. The law added important new features to the institutional setup governing Danish public expenditures, the most important being budget ceilings, economic sanctions, and the requirement of structural budget balance. By testing three hypotheses drawn from different branches of public choice theory, the analysis seeks to isolate the drivers of institutional change which led to the adoption of the budget law. Each hypothesis is tested separately, and three main conclusions are reached: The Budget Law can be seen as an attempt to address two cost driving dynamics: continuous problems related to cost control especially in Danish municipalities, and asymmetrical preferences concerning public expenditures. The Budget Law can be interpreted as a credible commitment initiative established to ensure that public expenditures can be controlled even when economic conditions improve and public expenditure preferences rise. An empirical test of the median voter model reveals that Danish voters, due to the economic crisis, preferred significantly lower public expenditures in 2011 than in 2007. This shift in voter preferences most likely made it easier for the majority in the Danish Parliament to pass the Budget Law without encountering massive resistance from voters and interest groups. Overall, the sudden and radical institutional change caused by the adoption of the Budget Law is a result of the above factors coinciding. Key words: Public expenditures, Public Choice, Denmark, Budget Law. 1 Introduction In 2012, the Danish Parliament adopted probably the most seminal public spending act ever – the socalled Budget Law.1 Behind the enactment lies a complex story about the relationship between public spending growth and cost overruns, the economic crisis and resulting crisis awareness, the desire to minimize the expense policy scope, and implementation of expenditure policy management systems across both national and international levels of government. The law was adopted to ensure that public budgets are respected. Over the last 35 years, this has not been the case, and the public sector had massive cost overruns, which resulted in comparatively high public spending growth (Jørgensen and Mouritzen 2005: 19). Denmark was hit hard by the economic crisis after 2008 (Goul Andersen 2013). This gave rise to major crisis awareness among voters, interest groups and politicians, and to a political paradigm shift in which cost overruns were no longer acceptable. From December 2011, the intergovernmental agreement, the European Fiscal Compact, required signature countries to ensure public finances balance. The Budget Law represents the Danish implementation of the Fiscal Compact. Theories of public expenditures traditionally point in two important and conflicting directions: They emphasize (1) that political institutions seldom change and (2) that concerning public expenditures, politicians focus on the short term and therefore are reluctant to commit to long-term objectives (Mueller 2003: 114-127). The Budget Law is an expression of the exact opposite. Flexible, but dissolute economic management has been replaced by strict legislation limiting politicians’ current and future spending policy options and flexibility. Yet, a large majority in the Danish Parliament adopted the law. The article asks how it was possible to adopt the Budget Law. The Budget Law contains the following elements: A requirement that public expenditures must be in balance or surplus.2 1 What we term the “Budget Law” is in fact a number of new laws and changes of existing laws. 2 The annual structural deficit may not exceed 0.5 % of GDP. The balance requirement, the correction mechanism, and their design represent the implementation of the requirements of the Fiscal Compact (Budget Act § 2 and 3; Ministry of Finance 2012b: 6-7). 1 An automatic correction mechanism is triggered when public finances differ from the above balance requirements. Budget ceilings for the state, municipalities, and regions. Financial penalties to ensure compliance with the ceilings in the state, municipalities, and regions. The Economic Council3 continually assesses whether fiscal and expenditure policies comply with the above requirements. These five main elements are designed to ensure long-term balance in public finances and that elected politicians conduct fiscal policy within the requirement of structural budget balance. The Fiscal Compact imposes identical requirements on Denmark. However, the Budget Law had already been prepared when the Fiscal Compact was adopted (Ministry of Finance 2011a: 8-10). By all accounts, Denmark has introduced an economic government institution that represents a paradigm shift compared to previous expenditure management. This article asks under which conditions such a significant institutional change can take place. In general, rationalist theoretical foundation (see below) is suitable for answering why so few policy changes occur (why so much stability? – as Dennis Mueller (2003:114) asked) and rationalist theories are less suitable for explaining political paradigm shifts (Lynggaard and Nedergaard 2009). The article exposes the theoretical foundation to a hard test and proceeds as follows: theoretical foundation; method; analysis; and, finally, conclusion. 2 Theory The article is based on rationalist theories of the political system and politicians’ behaviour, which derive their assumptions about actors’ preferences from neoclassical economic theory. They assign the actors exogenously determined preferences, and their actions are seen as the consequence of the 3 The Economic Council is headed by a chairmanship consisting of four independent economists and served by a secretariat with app. 30 employees. The other 25 members of the Council are representatives of labour and business, the Danish central bank and government organizations (www.dors.dk). 2 players’ cost-benefit analyses, where the alternative with the highest net benefits is chosen (Buchanan and Tullock 1999: 17). In the following we present the asymmetry theorem and classic game theory, the idea of credible commitment, and finally the median voter model. After each theoretical section, a hypothesis is presented. 2.1 The asymmetry theorem James Buchanan uses the term “asymmetrical” in his seminal work, The Calculus of Consent (1962), to describe how the institution of majority votes pushes the tax rate to rise to a suboptimal level (Buchanan and Tullock 1999: 168). The asymmetry stems from a fundamental difference between the economic and the political system. In an economic market, a buyer shows his willingness to pay for a good or service. This implies a symmetric relation between supplier and demander. In the political system, payment and consumption are separated due to the payment of taxes; consumption is individualized, while payment is collectivized (Buchanan and Tullock 1999: 149-200). This makes the political system vulnerable to organized groups, which are able to obtain benefits that far exceed the cost of organizing. The losers are stakeholders with diffuse interests for whom it does not pay to lobby – typically taxpayers and consumers (Nedergaard 2008: 301). The asymmetry theorem predicts that interest groups might succeed in pushing government expenditure upwards. Also civil servants will benefit from a bigger budget (Kristensen 1987: 55). Likewise, several other (supply-side) theories of the public choice tradition point out that the administrative system can grow larger than optimal (e.g. Niskanen 1971; 1973; Dunleavy 1991: 181209). This analysis tests implications of the asymmetry theorem in two ways, so that expenditure growth generated by stakeholders both outside and inside the administrative system is taken into account. A general ceiling of total public expenditure (as is the case with the Budget Law) increases the political costs of increased government spending in one area, because expansion of one type of activity implies savings in other activities in order not to violate the overall expenditure ceiling. Initiatives 3 such as the Budget Law are likely to weaken the political asymmetry (Kristensen 1987: 53). Hence, it becomes relevant to examine whether this was an objective of the Budget Law. The asymmetry theorem predicts that government spending will increase, but it does not offer a theoretical explanation of why public expenditure growth is often generated by cost overruns. Below, two versions of the classic Prisoner’s Dilemma (PD) will be presented as cost overruns are typically the result of a similar suboptimal logic (Jørgensen and Mouritzen 2005: 21-23). Based on the classic budget policy literature, political and administrative actors are separated into advocates of increased expenditures and guardians of the treasury (Wildavsky 1975: 7-10). The first version of the PD assumes that all spending advocates are interested in exceeding the budget for more funding. However, they are also interested in total budgets being adhered to in order to avoid collective sanctions. This leads to a suboptimal result: The total budget is exceeded, as illustrated by the PD below. Figure 1: Individualistic Game Expense advocate 2 Do not exceed the budget Expense advocate 1 Do not exceed the budget Exceed the budget B B Exceed the budget D D A A C C (equilibrium) As shown in Figure 1, both players exceed the budget. This is because it is most profitable for each actor to do so, although it provides a suboptimal outcome at the macro level (Kuhn 2007: 1-2). For the game to be properly characterized as an individualistic PD, at least three conditions must be met, 4 however: The following condition for the pay-off holds: A>B>C>D. The players should not be able to get out of the dilemma by taking turns exploiting each other, i.e. B>(A+D)/2) (Axelrod 1990: 10, 206). Players must be concerned only with their own pay-off and not the opponent’s (Sharpf 1998: 85). The difference between the individualistic and competitive game is given by the players’ preferences (Sharpf 1998: 84). In the individualistic version, the players are concerned only with their own outcome; in the competitive version one player loses what the other wins, i.e. a zero-sum game. In both the competitive and the individualistic PD, the equilibrium is non-cooperative (Sharpf 1998: 87-88). The two games thus illustrate theoretically why public actors’ play concerning budgets can provide sub-optimal performance in both zero-sum and plus-sum situations. Figure 2: Competitive Game Player 2 Cooperate Player 1 Cooperate Do not cooperate 0 0 Do not cooperate A -A -A A 0 0 (equilibrium) The above theoretical presentation indicates that public spending will increase over time, and that games concerning budgets will often lead to suboptimal results. Based on these theoretical expectations the first hypothesis is formulated: Hypothesis 1: The Budget Law was adopted in an attempt to rein in spending driving dynamics contained in the Danish political and administrative system. 5 2.2 Credible commitment The main point in the credible commitment literature is that efficient policy outcomes require political actors to limit their ability to pursue their own short-term interests. There are many situations where the benefits of commitment far exceed the benefits of discretion (North 1993; North and Weingast 1989). The classic example of a credible commitment is the Odyssey’s account of Odysseus and the Sirens. When Odysseus let himself be bound to the mast, he obtained the (Pareto) optimal situation which allowed him to hear the Sirens’ enticing song and still make it home safely to Ithaca (Homer 1998: 144-148; Pierson 2004: 41-43). In other words, absolute freedom of decision-makers does not always lead to optimal outcomes, because with freedom comes uncertainty and inconsistency (Kydland and Prescott 1977: 473-474). There may be a need to restrict the operators of action, but this presupposes that players’ actions are credible. A commitment can basically be credible in two ways. First, it can be “motivationally credible”: An actor who is willing to be bound throughout the relevant time period has no vested interest in more freedom, and there is no need for monitoring and sanctioning. Second, a commitment can be “imperatively credible”, for instance if the actor in fear of sanctions will not act differently (Shepsle 1991: 247). Credible commitments are a classic way to overcome the problems, which in game theory are often presented as a PD (Shepsle 1991: 248). The credible commitment approach considers the formation of the political budgets as a series of PD games. According to the credible commitment literature, this series of games will lead to increasing public spending because political actors are assumed to be myopic: They have to be re-elected, and voters are more concerned with their own needs than those of future generations (Shepsle 1991: 251; Buchanan 1999: 99-100). The above-mentioned debt problems are, according to Buchanan, not only attributed to individual incentives. He is critical of Keynesian economics where a correlation between government spending and tax burden is not necessary because debt is considered unproblematic (Buchanan and Wagner 2000: 55-120). Therefore, Buchanan spent much of his life arguing for a revision of the U.S. 6 Constitution to prohibit government budget deficit (see, e.g. Buchanan and Brennan 1985; Buchanan and Wagner 2000: 187; cf. also Wildavsky 1980; 1985). Based on the above review, the Budget Law is seen as an institutional credible commitment mechanism. Hence, a second hypothesis is formulated: Hypothesis 2: The Budget Law was adopted in an attempt to tie the political actors to pursue more long-term spending. 2.3 Median voter theorem The median voter theorem predicts that the spending decisions of the political parties correspond to the median voter’s preferences. In Downs’ classic model, the political system is seen as an “economic” market where voters demand and politicians supply political decisions. Voters are assumed to be rationally informed and to have consistent preferences (Downs 1957; see also Mueller 2003: 231). When it comes to public budgets, Downs formulates the political parties’ decision rule as follows: “... expenditures are increased until the vote-gain of the marginal dollar spent equals the voteloss of the marginal dollar financed” (Downs 1957: 52). Thus, according to the model, the total expenditure is determined by the median voter. The theorem’s assumptions are often not met and the main assumptions are discussed below. First, the model is based on a two-party system where political parties can move as close to the middle as they want without losing votes to other parties (Downs 1957: 54). This is not the case in Denmark because of the proportional election system in which new fringe parties can emerge and gather votes. Second, it is assumed that all voters vote, which is never the case (Mueller 2003: 232). When the model is applied to Denmark, the problem is limited, however, because of the comparatively very high turnout (Franklin 2004). Third, the model operates with only one political dimension, presumably the left-right economic conflict line. Hence, the model is not useful to treat, for example, conflict lines concerning values (Mueller 2003: 232). Finally, it is typically assumed that voters’ preferences are static (Kurrild-Klitgaard 2011: 23). That is not the case here because we include the effect of the economic crisis on voter preferences. 7 This does not compromise the model’s basic prediction: Politicians follow the median voter. Nevertheless, the above-mentioned problems indicate that the model should be used with caution. The third and final hypothesis states: Hypothesis 3: The Budget Law was adopted because the median voter prefers tighter spending due to the economic crisis. 3 Method The article is a single case study of the adoption of the Danish Budget Law. In order to explain single case outcomes, a number of causes, which together could lead to a given outcome, are considered. In the following analysis, the perception of causality is based on Mackie’s (1980: 62) concepts, INUS causality and INUS conditions. An INUS condition is neither necessary nor sufficient if it stands alone. Instead, it constitutes one of several conditions which combined are sufficient to achieve a given outcome; in Mackie’s (1980: 62) words: “... an insufficient but non-redundant part of an unnecessary to sufficient condition.” This approach makes it possible to identify combinations of conditions which combined are necessary for a given outcome to occur (Mahoney and Goertz 2006: 232-235). The above hypotheses are therefore neither competing nor mutually exclusive. Instead, it is investigated how the interplay between theoretical explanations may have triggered the adoption of the Budget Law. Since the hypotheses refer to a wide range of empirical phenomena, the article draws on several types of data: descriptive statistics, interviews, data from the Danish election survey as well as secondary empirical data. Eight interviews with senior officials and representatives of the two major political parties (Liberals and Social Democrats) have been conducted. The interviewees act as informants. Data from the Danish election survey is used to assess the voters’ attitudes towards the government’s expenditure policy. The survey, which has asked voters about their opinion after each general election since 1971, allows us to follow the evolution of public attitudes over the years of investigation (Stubager, Holm et al. 2013: 7) and to make it plausible if and how the voters’ possible 8 crisis awareness has affected decision-makers’ political preferences regarding expenditure policy. General elections were held in 2007 (before the crisis erupted) and in 2011 (when the crisis had lasted a couple of years). The data is cross-sectional, but changes in voter preferences are presumed to equal changes in the general population, due to the law of large numbers. 4 Analysis The analysis contains four sections. A brief presentation of events preceding the adoption of the Budget Law is followed by three sections in which each hypothesis is analysed. The conclusion discusses how the factors considered in the analysis explain the institutional change represented by the Budget Law. Several national and international events influenced the adoption of the Law. The following analysis focuses mainly on the Danish dynamics, because the informants indicated that these factors were the most important. The international factors are briefly summarized below. Both the OECD and the IMF have often recommended introduction of clearer fiscal rules, independent fiscal “watchdogs”, and a top-down budgeting system (Davidsen and Jensen 2012: 19). Danish decision-makers were probably also inspired by the Swedish Budget Law from 1996, which established an expenditure ceiling for government expenditures at state level (Ministry of Finance 2010: 238). The seemingly successful ceiling was well known among Danish decision-makers, and the Swedish model constituted a crucial inspiration, which is fully in line with the predictions of rationalistic policy learning (Meseguer 2006). It is often asserted that the Budget Law is a direct result of the Fiscal Compact. This is wrong. The Fiscal Compact was adopted in December 2011, but the Danish Ministry of Finance’s budget statement of May 2010 already referred to the Swedish Budget Law as a success story and an example to follow in Denmark (Ministry of Finance 2010: 235). By then, the Liberal government (for quite some time before the Fiscal Compact was adopted) planned to introduce a budget model that resembled the model in the current Budget Law (Ministry of Finance 2011a: 8-10). Conversely, the Fiscal Compact probably made it easier to get the Budget Law passed in the Parliament, cf. below. 9 The Budget Law was passed by a very large majority in Parliament on June 12 2012, consisting of the governing parties (the Social Liberals, the Social Democratic Party, and the Socialist People’s Party), the Liberals, and the Conservatives (Ministry of Finance 2012c). 4.1 Hypothesis 1: Asymmetry The analysis of hypothesis 1 proceeds as follows: Growth in Danish public spending is documented, and its relation to the asymmetry theorem and the Budget Law is established; the municipal and regional overspending related to the adoption of the Budget Law is uncovered; and the asymmetry theorem is tested empirically using data from the Danish election survey in 2007 and 2011. The asymmetry theorem can be examined in two ways: by considering whether the public expenditure growth can be explained as a response to asymmetric cost driving dynamics, or by examining whether the players’ preferences are instrumental self-interest maximizing as prescribed by the theory (Kristensen 1987: 56). In 1960, public spending made up approximately 25 per cent of Danish GDP, which placed Denmark well below other European countries and even below the United States. Over the next twenty years, Denmark underwent a massive growth in public spending, and in 1980 the expenditure ratio had increased to 56.9 per cent, only surpassed by Sweden. This massive growth in the expenditure ratio even took place during a period of strong GDP growth. Since the 1980s, the expenditure ratio has varied with the business cycle, and particularly the strong automatic stabilizers have made the pressure fluctuate inversely of the business cycle (Christiansen 2008: 29-30). Typically, about half of public spending consists of public consumption, and the rest is income transfers, public investments, and other expenses. Income transfers and public investment rose sharply until 2010. This was determined partly by the fact that GDP declined during the crisis, partly by fiscal priorities in advance of investments. Government consumption also grew until 2010 (Ministry of Finance 2010: 31). This is particularly relevant for the analysis because the “professional bureaucratic complex”, according to the asymmetry theorem, has a vested interest in higher consumption, while, for example, income transfers affect this group much less (Kristensen 1981: 98-99). Ceteris paribus, high growth in public spending indicates that growth is driven by asymmetry. 10 In Denmark, municipalities in general account for 50 per cent of public consumption, the state level accounts for 30 per cent, and the regions for 20 per cent (Nielsen and Rasmussen 2012: 78). Government consumption is usually measured by government spending as a share of GDP (often called “the public consumption pressure”). This number has increased from 25.7 per cent in 2001 to 29.4 per cent in 2009 with an expected consumption pressure in 2014 of 28.4 per cent (Ministry of Finance 2010: 30; 2012e: 65). Note, however, that GDP also fell during the period until 2009. Therefore real growth in public consumption must be taken into account. From 1993 to 2001 public consumption was planned to rise 1 per cent per year, but real growth was 2.5 per cent. This pattern repeated itself between 2002 and 2010, when the planned .9 per cent real growth in public consumption ended up at 1.6 per cent. On average, public consumption growth has been more than twice as high as planned between 1993 and 2010 (see Ministry of Finance 2012b: 4). All interviewees mentioned the uncontrollable spending growth from the 1990s onwards as one of the key causes of why the Budget Law was adopted. The above indicates that the growth in government spending has been driven by asymmetry, particularly because government spending has been increasing. Therefore, the adoption of the Budget Law can be interpreted as an attempt to reduce this asymmetry. The informants emphasize in particular the municipal budget overruns as decisive in this regard. Below, we conduct a game theoretical analysis of budget overruns in relation to the adoption of the Budget Law. 4.1 Hypothesis 1: Before and after the Budget Law The analysis in the remainder of this section consists of two parts. The first focuses on the dynamics that enabled the municipal budget overruns before the Budget Law. The second part examines the process that led to the Budget Law being adopted. Over the last 30 years it has been the rule rather than the exception that municipalities have exceeded their budgets (Serritzlew and Blom-Hansen 2008: 170). All informants mention municipal budget overruns as one key reason for the adoption of the Budget Law. Therefore, focus is on the municipalities, but the analysis could also be applied to the Danish regions, as they are subject to the same bargaining system. 11 Three characteristics of agreements between central and local government are of particular importance for the analysis. First, the agreements are not legally binding to municipalities and regions. Second, the agreements apply to municipalities and regions as a whole. If, for example, a municipality increases expenditure, and another municipality reduces spending by the same amount, the agreement is respected. Third, the government (with a majority in parliament) has the power to adopt collective economic sanctions against municipalities and regions if they exceed their budget. However, successive governments have refrained from doing so on numerous occasions (Serritzlew and BlomHansen 2008: 168). The Budget Law reverses the above as it introduces spending ceilings for service costs, which include approximately 70 per cent of the municipal expenditure (Budget Law § 5). Contrary to the situation before, municipalities are sanctioned individually if they exceed these spending limits. From the perspective of public choice theory, the problem is that local politicians have incentives to offer more public service, and the employees have incentive to obtain larger budgets (Howlett and Ramesh 1995: 19-20; Buchanan 1984: 133). In addition, individual municipalities have no incentives to save money due to the collective character of the annual economic agreements. Thus, the “Tragedy of the Commons” arises because municipalities maximize their own spending, resulting in a suboptimal outcome: The total budget is exceeded. “Tragedy of the Commons” is a special version of the individualistic PD, but with more players (all municipalities, i.e. n>2) (Ostrom et al. 2006: 5; Ostrom 1990: 2-5). Figure 3 illustrates the municipalities’ play against each other. As the figure shows, both municipalities exceed the budget, and the dynamic is empirically supported: Between 1980 and 2010 the budget agreements were met by the municipalities in only nine of 30 years (Serritzlew and Blom-Hansen 2008: 170; Nielsen and Rasmussen 2012: 78-79). The dynamic is reinforced by the fact that budgets are exceeded more when a local election approaches. This political business cycle is a well-known problem (Mouritzen 1989). Budget overruns are largest on issues where voters and local government employees have the strongest preferences, i.e. especially children, the elderly, and schools (Serritzlew and Blom-Hansen 2008: 152). 12 Figure 3: Individualistic game: Municipals budget exceeding Municipality 2 Do not exceed the budget Municipality 1 Do not exceed the budget Exceed the budget B B Exceed the budget D D A A C C (equilibrium) Why has the above dynamics among municipalities developed without sanctions from the incumbent government? An answer might be found in the political game between the government and the opposition. The game concerning economic sanctions can be considered as a competitive PD (Suenson, 2013: 128). It follows logically from the asymmetry theorem that the political parties of both government and opposition have no interest in sanctioning cost overruns, as this will reduce public spending and could be interpreted as unacceptable reductions in citizen-related welfare (Houlberg and Mouritzen 2011). The interviewees confirmed this: They emphasized that before the economic crisis welfare-state services were politically important, making it difficult to control costs. Therefore, successive governments did not sanction municipalities, which led to the competitive PD game shown in Figure 4. The game is a zero-sum game, since there are only 179 seats in parliament at all times. The game’s simplified logic illustrates why it has historically been difficult for the government to sanction municipalities when it has simultaneously played the eternal zero-sum game of the votes in parliament against the opposition. 13 Figure 4. Competitive game: Municipals budget exceeding – BEFORE the Budget Law Opposition Incumbent government Sanctioning No sanction 0 A Sanctioning 0 No sanction -A -A A 0 0 (equilibrium) The games above illustrate two mutually reinforcing dynamics: The municipalities have an incentive to exceed their budgets, which they have done; and the government has few incentives to sanction, which probably has caused more cost overruns. This is confirmed empirically as cost overruns became more frequent and larger towards 2009 (Holdt-Olesen and Panduro 2010: 1). The analysis illustrates why it was possible for municipalities to exceed their budgets year after year without sanctioning by the incumbent government. The next part examines how the Budget Law was probably adopted in an attempt to stop this dynamic. In 2009, the municipalities delivered the largest budget overrun ever. As pointed out by all informants, the economic crisis fundamentally changed the political agenda on public expenditure management. The Ministry of Finance played an active role in getting the Budget Law passed. By pushing for adoption of the Budget Law, the ministry’s civil servants maximized their interests: first, by subjecting the bulk of government spending to a governance system that was created and continuously adjusted by the ministry itself; second, by achieving greater control over local government spending, which the ministry had wished for a long time (Jensen 2003: 50, 300). In game theory jargon, a new equilibrium in the competitive games was created after the crisis, which means that government and some opposition parties worked together to adopt the Budget Law. 14 This could also be driven by the political parties’ self-interest, because financial accountability is rewarded by voters in times of crisis (Goul Andersen and Hansen 2013: 148), cf. Figure 5. Figure 5. Competitive game: Municipals budget exceeding – AFTER the Budget Law Opposition Cooperation Incumbent government Cooperation Noncooperation 0 0 (new equilibrium ) Noncooperation -A A A -A 0 0 According to all informants, the equilibrium of the game was changed after the economic crisis because politicians could adopt the Budget Law without being punished by the voters. In other words, preferences for public expenditure policy had changed, and this cannot be captured by public choice theory’s static preference understanding. In the following it is therefore examined whether voters’ and interest groups’ preferences changed. The asymmetry theorem claims that public spending will increase because groups with concentrated interests will push decision-makers to provide private goods to that particular group. In the election survey, voters were asked whether too little, adequate or too much money is spent on selected expenditure items. It is possible to isolate the voters who receive the benefit in question for four items: education, old age pensions, unemployment benefits, and welfare benefits. By using multiple regression analysis (robust OLS and ordered logistic regression) it can be tested whether recipients of one of these benefits prefer higher spending on the various items than non-recipients. Further, we can control for relevant background variables such as gender, age, income, and left/right 15 self-location4 and thus test whether the beneficiaries have “self-interest maximizing” preferences in 2007 and 2011 as the asymmetry theorem prescribes. The dependent variable in the regression analyses ranges from -1 (too much money) to 1 (too little money) and the intermediate category 0 (adequate).5 A positive beta estimate/coefficient in the regression analysis indicates that the beneficiaries prefer higher spending on these items, a negative the opposite. As we will not comment on other control variables, they do not appear below. Overall, the 2007 regression models confirm the assumptions of the asymmetry theorem about the actors’ preferences. The beneficiaries of education, unemployment benefits, and welfare benefits all prefer significantly higher spending on their “own” welfare benefits than the general population. Only the 2007 models regarding old age pensions are insignificant. Furthermore, it appears from the models’ R2 that none of the models can explain more than 16.2 per cent of the variation in the dependent variable, indicating that voters’ expense policy preferences are more complex than the asymmetry theorem prescribes. The figures show that it is plausible that the recipients’ preferences constituted an upward pressure on spending levels in 2007, and as shown above especially public consumption rose massively until the crisis erupted. The Budget Law can be seen as an attempt to weaken this pressure. As the Budget Law is introduced, it becomes harder to fulfil everyone’s spending preferences, as it will most certainly lead to an overrun of budget ceilings (Kristensen 1987: 53-54). The adoption of the Budget Law can be seen as an attempt to reduce the fragmentation of decision-making and thus the asymmetry in order to stop growth in public spending. 4 It is not possible to control for education because of differences in the survey questions in 2007 and 2011. Age is not used as control variable in the regression models regarding old age pensions since eligibility is dependent on age. 5 The dependent variable only has three categories and is therefore not interval scaled. Still, robust OLS results are reported because they are easily interpretable (robust OLS models are used since the dependent variable with three categories results in heteroscedasticity). The results are basically the same when the regression analysis is performed as ordered logistic regressions. N is larger in 2007 than in 2011, which all else equal makes the 2007 models more significant than the 2011 models. However n is over 770 in every model, so this anti-conservative effect is considered relatively unproblematic. 16 Table 1. Users’/beneficiaries’ estimation of actual consumption of the selected items of expenditures, 2007 and 2011 Results Constant Education 2007 .886 (.076)*** Beta estimates (robust OLS regression) R2 .083 Education 2011 .835 (.101)*** .231 (,057)*** .060 (,069) Old age pensions 2007 .956 (.052)*** -.025 (.029) .063 Old age pensions 2011 .460 (.071)*** .258 (.053)*** .030 .456 (.067)*** .292 (.104)*** .118 .318 (.091)*** .117 (.101) .108 Welfare benefits 2007 .483 (.074)*** .426 (.270)* .162 Welfare benefits 2011 .250 (.102)*** .176 (.188) .143 s Unemployment benefits 2007 Unemployment benefits 2011 .059 Ordered logistic regression Coefficient 1.181 (.341)*** .336 (.339) N -.120 (.119) .575 (.198)*** 2362 1.303 (.484)*** .439 (.479) 2347 1.639 (1.031)* .507 (.772) 2338 2374 834 820 818 770 Note: Standard errors in brackets, *significant at 0.1 level, **significant at 0.05 level, ***significant at 0.01 level. All models showed weaknesses in terms of normally distributed errors and homoscedasticity. Table 1 also shows the corresponding preferences measured in 2011 after the voters had experienced a severe economic crisis over the past three years. The 2011 figures do not support the asymmetry theorem’s assumptions about the actors’ preferences since the correlations of education, unemployment, and social welfare are insignificant. Only recipients of old age pensions prefer significantly more spending in this area. The assumptions of the asymmetry theorem can therefore not be found in three of four models. This is interesting for three reasons. First, this matches previous research which shows that self-interest maximizing preferences decrease in times of crisis (Goul Andersen and Hansen 2013). In particular, the economic crisis of the 1980s clearly affected public attitudes (Christiansen 1990: 443). Second, it is theoretically interesting that preferences vary. The regression models do not explain why recipients no longer prefer higher spending. One explanation could be that the crisis invokes more sociotropic attitudes among voters and recipients (Goul Andersen 1993: 173; Stubager, Botterill et al. 2013). Third, it was probably easier 17 to adopt the Budget Law because of this change in preference. The political problems associated with implementing budgetary ceilings are invariably smaller when the pressure from users and interest groups decreases. In conclusion, the Budget Law was probably adopted to weaken the political asymmetry, which makes public expenditure management more difficult. It was easier to adopt the law because of the shift in preferences of involved citizens. Overall, hypothesis 1 therefore finds support. 4.2 Hypothesis 2: Credible commitment This section analyses the motives behind the Budget Law on the basis of the credible commitment literature. It examines whether the Budget Law was passed in an attempt to tie public expenditures; it analyses whether the Law was adopted at a time when the expenditure objectives were met; and it looks at the Law as a balancing of discretion and commitment. Most informants mention the Budget Law as an initiative to deprive politicians of fiscal discretion. All informants further notice that existing fiscal priorities have not been consistent enough. The Budget Law is seen as an attempt to create a credible binding of expenditure policy to ensure that the development of public expenditure remains within the planned framework when the business cycle turns around and crisis awareness withers. The Budget Law can be seen as the politicians’ attempt to lash themselves to the mast before the (asymmetric) siren song starts again and the growth in public spending again becomes difficult to control. The consumption objectives and economic agreements between the government and Local Government Denmark were actually met after 2010 (Ministry of Economic Affairs and the Interior 2012). In the credible commitment terminology, public expenditure advocates’ “promise” to respect the budgets is seen as “motivationally credible”, probably because crisis awareness has affected many expenditure advocates. At first glance, it is surprising that the Budget Law was introduced at a time when the expenditure policy objectives were respected and when the pressure on spending was limited. For example, 2011 was the first year since 1990 that government spending dropped, and we have to go back to 1984 to find a larger decrease in government spending (Ministry of Finance 2012d: 48). 18 The Budget Law adopted in spring 2012 can be seen as the consequence of the government and the opposition being tired of playing the ongoing competitive PD. As budget overruns grew until 2009, and because municipalities also exceeded their budgets in 2010, the Budget Law commencing in 2011 is seen as the result of the parties’ desire to stop overruns. With the Budget Law, penalties are no longer adopted by discretion in Parliament. Instead, sanctioning mechanisms and budget ceilings are automatized, which makes it much easier to adopt and adhere to strict budgetary ceilings. The Budget Law can also be seen as an institutional blame avoidance mechanism that in particular the major political parties in Parliament can refer to when the spending cut debate rages (Jensen et al. 2008: 117). Overall, the Budget Law can be seen as a classic credible commitment initiative. The Law removes fiscal discretion from political actors and thereby stops the competitive PD in Parliament. The analysis has shown that budgetary ceilings and sanction mechanisms in the Budget Law were enacted to bind political actors. Evidence also suggests that the adoption of the Budget Law was the result of a desire to ensure a balanced budget in the long term. The Ministry of Finance (2012a) states the desire to avoid the problems created by a large, interest-bearing debt. Thus, for two reasons, the balance requirements of the Budget Law can be seen as projecting from the idea of credible commitment. First, the Budget Law is in compliance with Buchanan’s recommendation to enrol directly in the U.S. Constitution that government budget deficit is not allowed (Buchanan and Wagner 2000: 187). Second, the credible commitment literature underlines that actions are influenced by expectations about the future. If investors fear that the public debt will increase, they require a higher yield on Danish government bonds (see Breen and McMenamin 2013). The balance requirement of both the Fiscal Compact and Budget Law may be interpreted as a signal to financial markets. The credibility of this signal is significantly strengthened because the Budget Law was passed by a large majority in Parliament, which reduces the likelihood that the Budget Law is abolished after a general election. All credible commitment initiatives include a trade-off between discretion and commitment. Several informants expressed that the Budget Law’s binding also involves political costs. For 19 example, the four-year budget ceilings make it harder to both ease and tighten fiscal policy in the next few years. Several informants see this binding of the fiscal policy as problematic. The balance between discretion and binding is further addressed by not allowing the most cyclical spending to be subject to budgetary ceilings. Thus, the cost of unemployment benefits, social welfare, and the cost of employment activities are excluded from the budget ceiling. In this way, the Budget Law has sought to achieve the positive gains by tying expenditure policy, while at the same time avoiding the negative consequences by allowing automatic stabilizers to operate freely (Ministry of Finance 2012b: 2). Overall, hypothesis 2 finds support: The informants see the Budget Law as an attempt to limit politicians’ room for fiscal manoeuvre, and the Budget Law is used to bind political actors into the future when the economy turns. 4.3 Hypothesis 3: Median voter theorem In this section, the median voter theorem is tested empirically using data from the Danish election survey. The same data is then used to determine whether voters’ expense policy preferences have changed between 2007 and 2011. The adoption of the Budget Law is in this section seen as a consequence of the fact that voters have moved on the political continuum, which is the inverse dynamics of what the median voter theorem normally prescribes, namely that the political parties move. Before the median voter theorem can be used in an analysis of the adoption of the Budget Law, we have to test whether expenditure policies follow the median voter’s preferences. If this is not the case, it weakens the applicability of the median voter theorem. Kristensen (1982: 40) uses a simple and logically consistent test of the median voter theorem which is based on voter preferences. The premise is that if the policy is similar to the median voter’s preferences, exactly the same number of voters believe that the government is spending “too much” 20 and “too little”. This is possible to test with data from the Danish election survey, which asked voters whether they believed that the money spent on 14 different items was too little, adequate or too much.6 The response category “too much money” is assigned the value -1, the response category “appropriate” is assigned the value 0, and the response category “too little money” is assigned the value 1. The three categories can be combined into an overall measure of voters’ expenditure preference on each item, called PDI values (percentage difference index), which are obtained by subtracting the share of respondents who answered “too much money” from those who answered “too little money” (i.e. calculating the average around zero). The index can take values from -1 to 1; -1 indicates that all respondents believe that too much money is spent on that item, and 1 indicates that too little money is spent on the item. PDI values are shown in Table 2 for each item of expenditure in 2007 and 2011. The median voter theorem is rejected in both 2007 and 2011, as most PDI values are much higher or lower than 0. Only five of the 28 PDI values are closer to 0 than +/-0.1 (corresponding to a variation of 0 to 10 per cent, as the range of distribution is 2). PDI values fall too far from 0, and only 8 of the 28 PDI values are negative. Thus, the deviations from 0 are probably not attributable to random errors in variation. 6 The response categories refer to actual public expenditure on different items at the time the election survey is undertaken. Since costs may change between elections, it is uncertain whether altered response submissions are due to amended expenditure preferences or spending changes. It is assumed that voters are not aware of variations in costs between elections, and changes in response submissions are interpreted as signs of changing preferences. 21 Table 2: PDI values for the expenditure items Expenditure item and year yearearUdgiftspost og år Defence PDI 2007 PDI 2011 Diff. Sig. N 2007 N 2011 -.373 (.010) -.492 (.019) -.119 (.000)*** 3913 985 .735 (.007) .562 (.018) -.173 (.000)*** 3994 1003 Education .570 (.008) .650 (.016) .080 (.000)*** 3957 1000 Old age pensions .474 (.008) .340 (.017) -.134 (.000)*** 3935 980 Environment .501 (.009) .405 (.020) -.096 (.000)*** 3918 974 Culture -.174 (.010) -.333 (.020) -.159 (.000)*** 3920 976 Kindergartens and nurseries .517 (.009) .603 (.017) .086 (.000)*** 3927 982 Unemployment benefits .087 (.008) .132 (.018) .044 (.016)** 3888 972 benefitshedsunderstøttelse til den Welfare benefits .084 (.009) .040 (.022) -.044 (.046)** 3852 911 enkelte Foreign aid -.019 (.012) -.189 (.022) -.170 (.000)*** 3927 967 Refugees and immigrants .037 (.012) -.127 (.022) -.163 (.000)*** 3917 940 Home care .701 (.008) .682 (.016) -.020 (.257) 3962 971 Motorways and bridges .122 (.011) -.101 (.020) -.222 (.000)*** 3927 974 Police .614 (.009) .369 (.019) -.245 (.000)*** 3931 973 Note: Standard errors in brackets, *significant at 0.1 level, **significant at 0.05 level, ***significant at 0.01 level. Healthcare According to the median voter theorem, political parties could therefore reap more votes by increasing government spending and approaching the median voter. The theorem can thus help explain the growth in public spending until the crisis. The Budget Law however cannot be seen as a direct consequence of the predictions of the median voter theorem, as it is evident from the above that government spending does not follow the median voter’s preferences (Jørgensen and Mouritzen 2005: 73). That said, the formulation of the questions could lead to bias because the questions do not force voters to take into account the tax consequences of higher government spending – the so-called fiscal illusion (Courant et al. 1980; Kristensen 1987: 154). Furthermore, voters often have inconsistent preferences for spending increases and at the same time lower taxes (Winter and Mouritzen 2001). Nevertheless, the results are relevant for an analysis of the adoption of the Budget Law because some of the PDI values decreased from 2007 to 2011, indicating that voters prefer lower public spending after the crisis. Based on the results above, it is possible to examine how voters’ preferences change. First, PDI values from 2007 and 2011 are compared. Analytically it is assumed that the Budget Law – all else being equal – will result in tighter public spending. Because tighter spending often attracts negative attention from (media and) voters, we will examine whether voters prefer lower public spending in 22 2011 than in 2007. If this is the case, it can be seen as a facilitating cause of the adoption of the Budget Law because the political parties’ costs of adopting the law were lower in 2011 than in 2007. If voters prefer lower public expenditure, the PDI values from 2011 will be lower than those from 2007. Table 2 shows, for each expenditure item, the difference between the PDI values and a test of significance that indicates whether the PDI values for the two years differ significantly. On 10 of the 14 items, voters prefer significantly lower spending in 2011 than in 2007.7 Only for three items (Unemployment benefits, Education, and Kindergartens and nurseries) do voters prefer significantly higher costs. In conclusion, voters’ preferences have changed significantly in 13 of the 14 expenditure categories. We cannot conclude unequivocally, based on the above, that voters prefer lower public spending, as some responses may reflect attitudes on values rather than on expenditure policy. A factor analysis is therefore conducted in order to assess whether there is an underlying value political dimension. The factor analysis can be viewed online as an annex to this article (http://www.xxxxxx.dk). The conclusion in the appendix is that the above result holds even when the value political change in voter preferences is taken into account. 5 Conclusion The analyses show that institutional change in this case was driven by a number of factors coinciding. More than one institutional logic of change was at work. Nevertheless, the institutional approach can help explain why the Budget Law was adopted. The Budget Law’s adoption should be seen as a consequence of both endogenous and exogenous factors in relation to the institution itself. The old public expenditure governance model led to increasingly larger budget overruns, especially in the municipalities, and since possible sanctions had to be adopted discretionarily, they often did not materialize. This signalled to the municipalities that cost overruns would not be sanctioned. Hence, the institutional outcome created a need for automatic and individual sanctions. In addition, the economic crisis after 2008 resulted in an exogenous shock. The crisis affected the two 7 Voters may also prefer lower spending on home care, but this result is insignificant. 23 main stakeholders: Groups of recipients of payments developed more sociotropic preferences, and voters preferred significantly lower public expenditures at the time the Budget Law was adopted than when the economic crisis started. The Budget Law’s provisions establish a new and radically different framework for public financial management, but it retains the traditional institutional features consisting of agreements with local and regional authorities, the ministries’ possibility of being awarded additional funds, etc. The Budget Law’s adoption may thus be characterized as a new layer on top of existing institutional elements (i.e. radical layering). Hypotheses 1 and 2 are supported, as the relevant INUS conditions were present. First, public spending was increasing towards the adoption of the Budget Law and the objectives for growth in public consumption were exceeded. This is consistent with the asymmetry theorem, and not least public employees have their own interest in higher public consumption. Second, and importantly, the municipalities had significant cost overruns. Supplementing the collective nature of economy agreements with individual financial penalties on municipalities and regions ended the collective action dilemma. Hence, the Budget Law can be seen as an attempt to prevent both expenditure growth driven by asymmetry and cost overruns. This was further confirmed since the quantitative tests of the asymmetry theorem showed that interest groups had individual utility-maximizing preferences in 2007. However, the asymmetry theorem’s assumptions about the actor’s preferences could not be confirmed unequivocally in 2011 when the preferences were less expenditure expansive due to the crisis. In a better future economic situation, crisis awareness is expected to slow down, and the preferences are expected to return to a more self-interest maximizing stage. Therefore, the Budget Law was adopted – in line with hypothesis 2 – as a credible commitment initiative to prevent future spending collapses. Overall, hypothesis 2 finds support because the Budget Law restricts both politicians’ current and future fiscal manoeuvre. Hypothesis 3 only received partial support, as two of the median voter theorem’s assumptions could not be found empirically. More significantly, the analysis clarified that the voters’ expenditure policy preferences changed towards significantly lower public spending in 2011 than in 2007, even 24 when value political changes in voter preferences are taken into account. The voters’ shift in preferences probably made the fiscal tightening by the Budget Law possible. In recent years, Denmark has implemented reforms in areas that previously would have been very difficult to reform, e.g., the early retirement scheme, unemployment benefits, social welfare, regulation of public benefits, and economic support for education. The economic crisis has made otherwise very difficult reforms possible and has opened the way for reforms elsewhere in Europe; many of them far more radical than the Danish reforms and several provoking pronounced political unrest. If nothing else, these experiences show that it is possible to intervene radically in the otherwise hard-to-change political and economic institutions. Time will reveal the long-term effects. It is too early to tell whether crisis awareness or the Budget Law ultimately ensures budget compliance, since we have not yet had one without the other. 25 References Axelrod, R. (1990). The evolution of co-operation. London: Penguin books. Breen, M., & Menamin, I. (2013). Political institutions, credible commitment, and sovereign debt in advanced economies. International Studies Quarterly. Forthcoming. Buchanan, J. M. (1999). Public finance in democratic process: fiscal institutions and individual choice. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund Inc. Buchanan, J.M. (1984). Politics Without Romance: A Sketch of Positive Public Choice Theory and Its Normative Implications. I J.M. Buchanan & R.D. Tollison (eds.): The Theory of Public Choice II. Michigan: The University of Michigan Press. Buchanan, J. M., & Brennan, G. (1985). The reason of rules: constitutional political economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1999). The calculus of consent – logical foundations of constitutional political economy. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund Inc. Buchanan, J. M., & Wagner, R. E. (2000). Democracy in deficit – the political legacy of Lord Keynes. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund Inc. Christiansen, P. M. (1990). Udgiftspolitikken i 1980’erne: fra asymmetri til asymmetrisk tilpasning? Politica, 22, 442-455. Christiansen, P. M. (2008). De politiske budgetter. In P. M. Christiansen (Ed.), Budgetlægning og offentlige udgifter. Aarhus: Academia. Courant, P. N., Gramlich, E. M., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (1980). Why voters support tax limitation amendments: the Michigan case. National Tax Journal, 33, 1-20. Davidsen, S., & Jensen, L. (2012). The global financial crisis in Denmark and Sweden: A case of “crisis management lite”. Unpublished. Located 4 May 2013 at: http://www.irspm.net/publications/viewcategory/89-42-the-impact-of-fiscal-crisis-on-publicmanagementand-governance.html Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row. Dunleavy, P. (1991). Democracy, bureaucracy and public choice: economic explanations in political science. London: Longman. 26 Franklin, M. N. (2004). Voter turnout and the dynamics of electoral competition in established democracies since 1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Goul Andersen, J. (1993). Samfundssind og egennytte. Politica, 25, 163-186. Goul Andersen, J. (2013). Krisens navn. Bekæmper regeringen den forkerte økonomiske krise? Copenhagen: Frydenlund Academic. Goul Andersen, J., & Hansen, K. M. (2013). Vælgernes krisebevidsthed. In R. Stubager, K. M. Hansen, & J. Goul Andersen (Eds.), Krisevalg. Økonomien og folketingsvalget 2011. Copenhagen: DJØF Publishers. Holdt-Olesen, P., & Panduro, B. (2010). Kommunernes økonomiske styring 1995-2009. Aarhus: KREVI. Located 23 March 2013 at: http://krevi.dk/files/Kommunernes_okonomiske_styring_95-09_endelig.pdf Homer, translated by Samuel Butler (1998). The odyssey. New York: Orange Street Press. Houlberg, K., & Mouritzen, P. E. (2011). Kommunerne skal levere velfærd – men sidder i statens jerngreb. Copenhagen: AKF. Located 7 February 2013 at: http://www.akf.dk/udgivelser/container/2011/udgivelse_1101/ Howlett, M., & Ramesh, M. (1995). Studying public policy: policy cycles and policy subsystems. Oxford: Oxford University Press. http://www.fm.dk/Nyheder/RSS/~/media/Files/Nyheder/Pressemeddelelser/2012/03/Budgetlov/budget lov_handouts.ashx Jensen, L. (2003). Den store koordinator – Finansministeriet som moderne styringsaktør. Copenhagen: DJØF Publishers. Jensen, L., Andersen, T. S., & Henneberg, S. (2008). Statens budget – processer, rammer og aktører. I P. M. Christiansen (Ed.), Budgetlægning og offentlige udgifter. Aarhus: Academia. Jørgensen, T. B., & Mouritzen, P. E. (2005). Udgiftspolitik og budgetlægning. Aarhus: Systime Academic. Kristensen, O. P. (1981). Den politisk-bureaukratiske beslutningsproces som medvirkende årsag til væksten i den offentlige sektor. Nordisk Administrativt Tidsskrift, 4, 80-102. 27 Kristensen, O. P. (1982). Voter attitudes and public spending: Is there a relationship? European Journal of Political Research, 10, 35-52. Kristensen, O. P. (1984). On the futility of the demand approach to public sector growth. European Journal of Political Research, 12, 309-324. Kristensen, O. P. (1987). Væksten i den offentlige sektor. Institutioner og politik. Copenhagen: DJØF Publishers. Kuhn, S. (2007). Prisoner’s Dilemma. Stanford: Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. Located 7 February 2013 at: http://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2009/entries/prisoner-dilemma/ Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2011). Kontraktpolitik, kulturkamp og ideologi 2001-2011. MPRA Paper nr. 43052. Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 473-491. Lynggaard, K., & Nedergaard, P. (2009). The logic of policy development: lessons learned from reform and routine within the CAP 1980-2003. Journal of European Integration, 31, 291-309. Mackie, J. L. (1980). The cement of the universe: a study of causation. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Mahoney, J., & Goertz, G. (2006). A tale of two cultures: Contrasting quantitative and qualitative research. Annual Review of Political Science, 9, 455-476. Meseguer, C. (2006). Rational learning and bounded learning in the diffusion of policy innovations. Rationality and Society, 18, 35-66. Ministry of Economic Affairs and the Interior (2012). Økonomisk Redegørelse, december 2012. Copenhagen: Ministry of Economic Affairs and the Interior. Located 7 May 2013 at: http://oim.dk/media/371804/web__konomisk_redeg_relse_samlet_dec.2012.pdf Ministry of Finance (2010). Budgetredegørelse 2010. Copenhagen: Ministry of Finance. Located 7 February 2013: http://www.fm.dk/Publikationer/2010/~/media/Publikationer/Imported/2010/2113Budgetredegoerelse%202010/978-87-7856-941-7.pdf.ashx 28 Ministry of Finance (2011a). Reformpakken 2020 – Kontant sikring af Danmarks velfærd. Copenhagen: Ministry of Finance. Located 16 June 2013 at: http://www.fm.dk/publikationer/2011/reformpakken-2020-_-kontant-sikring-afdanmarksvelfaerd/download/~/media/Publikationer/Imported/2011/Reformpakken%202020%2 0publikation/reformpakken_2020_web.pdf.ashx Ministry of Finance (2012a). Aftale om Budgetlov. Copenhagen: Ministry of Finance. Located 7 February 2013 at: http://www.fm.dk/Nyheder/RSS/~/media/Files/Nyheder/Pressemeddelelser/2012/03/Budgetlov/ aftale%20om%20budgetlov.ashx Ministry of Finance (2012b). Budgetlov. Copenhagen: Ministry of Finance. Located 7 February 2013 at: Ministry of Finance (2012c). Regeringen indgår aftale om en ny budgetlov. Copenhagen: Ministry of Finance. Located 9 March 2013 at: http://www.fm.dk/nyheder/pressemeddelelser/2012/03/regeringen-indgaar-aftale-om-nybudgetlov/ Ministry of Finance (2012d). Budgetoversigt 1. maj 2012. Copenhagen: Ministry of Finance. Located 12 June 2013 at: http://www.fm.dk/publikationer/2012/budgetoversigt-1maj2012/~/media/Publikationer/Imported/2012/BO1%20maj%2012/budgetoversigt%201_maj% 202012_web.ashx Ministry of Finance (2012e). Budgetoversigt 3. december 2012. Copenhagen: Ministry of Finance. Loacted 12 May 2013 at: http://www.fm.dk/publikationer/2012/budgetoversigt-3december2012/~/media/Publikationer/Imported/2012/BO3%20dec%2012/budgetoversigt%203 %20december%202012_web.pdf Mouritzen, P. E. (1989). The local political business cycle. Scandinavian Political Studies, 12, 37-54. Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Nedergaard, P. (2008). The political economy of European integration and business: How to explain policy developments. In P. Nedergaard, & J. L. Campbell (Eds.), Institutions and Politics. Copenhagen: DJØF Publishers. 29 Nielsen, P. B., & Rasmussen, M. H. (2012). Styring af de offentlige udgifter i Danmark. Kvartalsoversigt, 2. kvartal 2012 – Del 1. Copenhagen: Nationalbanken. Lokaliseret den 7. februar 2013 på: http://www.nationalbanken.dk/C1256BE2005737D3/side/Kvartalsoversigt_2012_2_kvartal_Del _1/$file/kvo_2kvt_2012_del1_web.pdf Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company. Niskanen, W. A. (1973). Bureaucracy: servant or master? Wolver Hampton: William Gibbon and Sons Ltd. North, D. C. (1993). Institutions and credible commitment. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 149, 11-23. North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of Economic History, 49, 803-832. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons – the evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University press. Ostrom, E., Gardner, R., & Walker, J. (2006). Rules, games, and common-pool resources. Michigan: The University of Michigan Press. Pierson, P. (2004). Politics in time. History, institutions and social analysis. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Rodeheffer, C. D, Hill, S. E., & Lord, C. G. (2012). Does this recession make me look black? The effect of resource scarcity on the categorization of biracial faces. Psychological Science, 23, 1476. Scharpf, F. (1998). Games real actors play – actor-centered institutionalism in policy research. Boulder: Westview Press. Serritzlew, S., & Blom-Hansen, J. (2008). Budgetlægning i kommuner og regioner. In P. M. Christiansen (Ed.), Budgetlægning og offentlige udgifter. Aarhus: Academia. 30 Shepsle, K. A. (1991). Discretion, institutions and the problem of government commitment. In P. Bourdieu, & J. Coleman (Eds.), Social theory for a changing society. Boulder: Westview Press. Stubager, R., Botterill, N. W., Lewis-Beck, M. S., & Nadeau, R. (2013). Scope conditions of economic voting: the Danish exception? Electoral Studies (in press). Stubager, R., Holm, J., Smidstrup, M., & Kramb, K. (2013). Danske vælgere 1971-2011: en oversigt over udviklingen i vælgernes holdninger og adfærd. Copenhagen: Valgprojektet. Located 21 April 2013 at: http://www.valgprojektet.dk/files/Danske%20vælgere%201971-2011%20%20Februar%202013.pdf Suenson, E. L. (2013). Budgetlovens fødsel – overforbruget, krisen og rationaliteten. In K. KosiaraPedersen, G. Nedergaard, & E.L. Suenson (Eds.), Statskundskab i praksis. Copenhagen: Karnov Group. The Budget Law (2012). Budget Law. Copenhagen: Retsinformation. Located 7 February 2013 at: https://www.retsinformation.dk/Forms/R0710.aspx?id=142466andexp=1 Wildavsky, A. (1975). Budgeting, a comparative theory of the budgetary process. Boston: Little Brown and Company. Wildavsky, A. (1980). How to limit government spending. Berkeley: University of California Press. Wildavsky, A. (1985). Equality, spending limits, and the growth of government. Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science, 35, 59-71. Winter, S., & Mouritzen, P. E. (2001). Why people want something for nothing: the role of asymmetrical illusions. European Journal of Political Research, 39, 109-143. 31
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz