Monotone Comparative Statics Econ 2100 Lecture 10, October 5 Outline 1 Comparative Statics Without Calculus 2 Supermodularity 3 Single Crossing 4 Topkis’and Milgrom & Shannon’s Theorems 5 Midterm Fall 2015 Comparative Statics Without Calculus Remark Using the implicit function theorem, one can show that if there are complementarities between choice variable x and parameter q, the optimum increases in q. First Order Condition: By IFT fx (x; q) = 0. xq (q) = Second Order Condition: fxx < 0. fxq (x; q) : fxx (x; q) Then xq (q) 0 if and only if fxq (x; q) 0 Here g is the derivative of g with respect to . Issues with implicit function theorem: 1 IFT needs calculus. 2 The conclusion holds only in a neighborhood of the optimum. 3 The results are dependent on the functional form used for the objective function. 1 In particular, IFT gives cardinal results that depend on the assumptions on f . Monotone Comparative Statics Objectives With monotone comparative statics, we seek results about “changes” that: do not need calculus are not necessarily only local (around the optimum). are ordinal in the sense of being robust to monotonic transformations. The objective is to get a similar result without calculus. The downside is that the results are not as strong. Main Idea: Complementarities We want to generalize the notion of complementarities between endogenous variable and parameters. With calculus, this is the assumption that fxq (x; q) 0. We would also like to account for the possibility that the optimum is not unique so that x (q) is not a function. What does it mean for a correspondence to be increasing? Strong Set Order When can we say that one set is larger? De…nition For two sets of real numbers A and B, de…ne the binary relation A sB if s as follows: for any a 2 A and b 2 B minfa; bg 2 B A s and maxfa; bg 2 A B reads “A is greater than or equal to B in the strong set order”. Generalizes the notion of greater than from numbers to sets of numbers. According to this de…nition f1; 3g is not greater than or equal to f0; 2g. This de…nition reduces to the standard de…nition when sets are singletons. Non-Decreasing Correspondences De…nition We say a correspondence g : Rm ! 2R is non-decreasing in q if and only if q0 > q implies g (q 0 ) s g (q) This says that q 0 > q implies that for any x 0 2 g (q 0 ) and x 2 g (q): minfx 0 ; xg 2 g (q) and maxfx 0 ; xg 2 g (q 0 ). Generalizes the notion of increasing function to correspondences. Exercise Prove that if g ( ) is non-decreasing and min g (q) exists for all q, then min g (q) is non-decreasing. Exercise Prove that if g ( ) is non-decreasing and max g (q) exists for all q, then max g (q) is non-decreasing. Monotone Comparative Statics: Simplest Case Set up Suppose the function f : R2 ! R is the objective function; this is not necessarily concave or di¤erentiable, and the optimizer could be set valued. Let x (q) arg max f (x; q); subject to q 2 ; x 2 S(q) Notice that for any strictly increasing g ( ), this problem is equivalent to x (q) arg max g (f (x ; q)); subject to q 2 ; x 2 S (q) but g ( ) may destroy smoothness or concavity properties of the objective function. For now, assume S( ) is independent of q and both x and q are real variables. Also, assume existence of a solution but not uniqueness. Supermodularity De…nition The function f : R2 ! R is supermodular in (x; q) if for all x 0 > x f (x 0 ; q) f (x; q) is non-decreasing in q: If f is supermodular in (x; q), then the incremental gain to a higher x is greater when q is higher. This is the idea that x and q are “complements”. Question 1, Problem Set 6. Show that supermodularity is equivalent to the property that q0 > q implies f (x; q 0 ) f (x; q) is non-decreasing in x: Di¤erentiable Version of Supermodularity When f is smooth, supermodularity has a characterization in terms of derivatives. Lemma A twice continuously di¤erentiable function f : R2 ! R is supermodular in (x; q) if and only if D12 f (x; q) 0 for all (x; q). The inequality in the de…nition of supermodularity is just the discrete version of the mixed-partial condition in the lemma. q0 > q implies f (x ; q 0 ) f (x ; q) is non-decreasing in x Topkis’Monotonicity Theorem Theorem (Easy Topkis’Monotonicity Theorem) If f is supermodular in (x; q), then x (q) arg max f (x; q) is non-decreasing. Proof. Question 2, Problem Set 6 (do not use later results). Supermodularity is su¢ cient to draw comparative statics conclusions in optimization problems without other assumptons. Topkis’Theorem follows from the IFT whenever the standard full-rank condition in the IFT holds. At a maximum, if D11 f (x ; q) 6= 0, it must be negative (by the second-order condition), hence the IFT tells you that x (q) is strictly increasing. Example Pro…t Maximiization Without Calculus A monopolist chooses output q to solve max p(q)q c(q; ). p( ) is the demand (price) function c( ) is the cost function costs depend on the existing technology, described by some parameter . Let q ( ) be the monopolist’s optimal quantity. Suppose c(q; ) is supermodular in (q; ); then the entire objective function is also supermodular in (q; ). this follows because the …rst term of the objective does not depend on . Notice that supermodularity says that for all q 0 > q, nondecreasing in . c(q 0 ; ) + c(q; ) is in other words, the marginal cost is decreasing in . Conclusion: by Topkis’theorem q is nondecreasing as long as the marginal cost of production decreases in the technological progress parameter . A Useful Trick Sometimes one can “invent” an objective function in order to apply the theorem. Compare the Optima of Di¤erent Optimization Problems Suppose one wishes to compare the solutions to two di¤erent maximization problems, max g (x) and max h(x) x 2S x 2S Apply the theorem to an arti…cial function, f ( g (x) if = 0 f (x; ) = h(x) if = 1 If h(x) g (x) is nondecreasing, f is supermodular and therefore the solution to the second problem is greater than the solution to the …rst. Single-Crossing In constrained maximization problems we have x 2 S(q), and supermodularity is not enough to establish Topkis’theorem. De…nition The function f : R2 ! R satis…es the single-crossing condition in (x; q) if for all x 0 > x, q 0 > q f (x 0 ; q) f (x; q) 0 implies f (x 0 ; q 0 ) f (x; q 0 ) 0 and f (x 0 ; q) f (x; q) > 0 implies f (x 0 ; q 0 ) f (x; q 0 ) > 0: As a function of the second argument, the marginal return can cross 0 at most once; whenever it crosses 0, as the second argument continues to increase, the marginal return is going to remain positive. Theorem If f satis…es single crossing in (x; q), then x (q) = arg maxx 2S (q) f (x; q) is nondecreasing. Moreover, if x (q) is nondecreasing in q for all constraint choice sets S, then f satis…es single-crossing in (x; q). Monotone Comparative Statics n-dimensional choice variable and m-dimensional parameter vector Before we had a function of a real number and a parameter. Next, we generalize to functions of vectors where the parameter is also a vector. De…nitions Suppose x; y 2 Rn . The join of x and y is de…ned by x _ y = (maxfx1 ; y1 g; maxfx2 ; y2 g; : : : ; maxfxn ; yn g): The meet of x and y is de…ned by x ^ y = (minfx1 ; y1 g; minfx2 ; y2 g; : : : ; minfxn ; yn g): Draw a picture. A Simple Result Lemma (i) : (ii) x _y =x ,x : x ^y =x ,x y , and y Proof. Let x; y 2 Rn . Note that x _ y = x , (maxfx1 ; y1 g; : : : ; maxfxn ; yn g) = (x1 ; : : : ; xn ) , maxfxi ; yi g = xi 8i 2 f1; : : : ; ng , xi Similarly, ,x yi 8i 2 f1; : : : ; ng y: x ^ y = x , (minfx1 ; y1 g; : : : ; maxfxn ; yn g) = (x1 ; : : : ; xn ) , minfxi ; yi g = xi 8i 2 f1; : : : ; ng , xi ,x yi 8i 2 f1; : : : ; ng y Strong Set Order De…nition (Strong set order in Rn ) The binary relation A s on subsets of Rn is de…ned as follows: for A; B sB if Rn , for any a 2 A and b 2 B a^b 2B and a _ b 2 A This is the same as the previous de…nition. We can use this to talk about non-decreasing Rn -valued correspondences. Quasi-Supermodularity De…nition Let f : Rn Rm ! R. Then f (x; q) is quasi-supermodular in x if, for all x; y 2 Rn and q 2 Rm : 1 f (x; q) 2 f (x ^ y; q) ) f (x _ y; q) f (y; q); f (x; q) > f (x ^ y; q) ) f (x _ y; q) > f (y; q): This is a generalization of the mixed second partial derivatives typically used to make statements about complementarities or substitutability. Quasi-supermodularity is an ordinal property, and for di¤erentiable functions there is a su¢ cient condition for quasi-supermodularity. Exercise 1 2 Prove that if f is quasi-supermodular in x, then h f is quasi-supermodular in x for any strictly increasing h : f (Rn Rm ) ! R. Suppose f (x; q) is twice di¤erentiable in x and with i 6= j. Then f is quasi-supermodular in x. @2 f @xi xj > 0 for all i; j = 1; : : : ; n Single-Crossing Property De…nition Let f : Rn Rm ! R. Then f (x; q) satis…es the single-crossing property if, for all x; y 2 Rn and q; r 2 Rm such that x y and q r: 1 f (x; r) 2 f (y; r) ) f (x; q) f (y; q); f (x; r) > f (y; r) ) f (x; q) > f (y; q): The “marginal return” f (x; ) f (y; ) as a function of the second argument can cross 0 at most once. The single-crossing property is an ordinal property, and for di¤erentiable functions there is a su¢ cient condition for single-crossing. Exercise 1 Prove that if f satis…es the single-crossing property, then h f satis…es the single-crossing property for any strictly increasing h : f (Rn Rm ) ! R. 2 2 @ f Suppose f (x; q) is twice di¤erentiable and @x > 0 for all i = 1; : : : ; n and i xj j = 1; : : : ; m. Then f satis…es the single-crossing property. Hint: Use induction on dimensions. Increasing Di¤erences and Supermodularity De…nition Let f : Rn Rm ! R. We say that f (x; q) satis…es the increasing di¤erences if, for all x; x0 2 Rn and q; q0 2 Rm such that x0 x and q0 q: f (x0 ; q0 ) f (x; q0 ) f (x0 ; q) f (x; q) Strict increasing di¤erences has a strict inequality. Similar to single crossing, but stronger. The “marginal return” f (x0 ; ) f (x; ) is increasing in the second argument. @2 f If f (x; q) is twice di¤erentiable and @x > 0 for all i and j, then f has i xj increasing di¤erences in (x; q). De…nition f (x; q) is supermodular in x if, for all x; y 2 Rn and q 2 Rm : f (x _ y; q) + f (x ^ y; q) f (x; q) + f (y; q); Similar to quasi-supermodularity, but stronger. @2 f If f (x; q) is twice di¤erentiable in x and @x > 0 for all i; j = 1; : : : ; n with i xj i 6= j, then f is supermodular in x. Unlike quasi-supermodularity and single-crossing, increasing di¤erences and Monotone Comparative Statics Theorem (easy Milgrom and Shannon) Let f : Rn Rm ! R. De…ne x (q) = arg maxx 2Rn f (x; q). Suppose jx (q)j = 1 for all q and f (x; q) is quasi-supermodular in x and satis…es the single-crossing property. Then q r ) x (q) x (r ): This is ‘easy’since it assume the optimum is unique (the proof does not use the ‘strict’part of the de…nitions of quasi-supermodularity and single-crossing). Proof. Suppose q ) r . Then: f (x (r ); r ) f (x (q) _ x (r ); r ) ) f (x (q) _ x (r ); q) ) ) f (x (q) ^ x (r ); r ) by de…nition of x (q) f (x (q); r ) by quasi-supermodularity in x f (x (q); q) x (q) _ x (r ) = x (q) x (q) x (r ) by Single Crossing since jx (q)j equals 1 by the earlier Lemma This result can be extended to constrained optimization problems (Question 3, Problem Set 6). Problem Set 6 (Incomplete) Due Monday, 13 October, at the beginning of class 1 Assume the function f : R2 ! R is supermodular in (x; q) and show that supermodularity is equivalent to the property that q0 > q 2 3 implies f (x; q 0 ) f (x; q) is non-decreasing in x: Without using Milgrom and Shannon’s theorem, prove that if f : R2 ! R is supermodular in (x; q), then x (q) arg max f (x; q) is non-decreasing. Consider the following extension of the monotone comparative statics results allowing for constrained optimization. Suppose f : Rn Rm ! R is quasi-supermodular in x and satis…es the single crossing property. Suppose ' : Rm ! Rn is a correspondence such that '(q 0 ) s '(q) for every q 0 > q. Set x (q) = arg max f (x; q) x 2'(q) 4 and assume jx (q)j = 1 for each q. Prove that x (q 0 ) x (q) for every q 0 > q. Suppose a …rm purchases two inputs x1 and x2 at unit costs w1 and w2 to produce a single product with production function f (x1 ; x2 ) to sell at a unit market price of p. Its pro…t is therefore: (x1 ; x2 ; p; w1 ; w2 ) = pf (x1 ; x2 ) 2 w1 x1 w2 x2 : Suppose f is C 2 and @x@ 1 fx2 > 0, i.e. x1 and x2 are complements. Assume that x (p; w1 ; w2 ) = arg max (x1 ; x2 ; p; w1 ; w2 ) is unique. Use monotone comparative statics to prove that if p 0 p, w10 w1 , and w20 w2 , then x (p 0 ; w10 ; w20 ) x (p; w1 ; w2 ). (Hint: you will have to do some change of variables.)
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz