REMEDIES IN COORDINATED BEHAVIOUR CASES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS MARKET: TYPES AND THEIR EFFECTIVENESS Master’s Thesis LL.M International Business Law Tilburg Law School Tilburg Law and Economics Center (TILEC) Anastasia Kryuchkova ANR: 280455 Thesis Supervisor: Prof. Pierre Larouche June 2014 Table of Contents Page Introduction 2 Chapter 1. Tacit collusion and coordinated behaviour 4 Chapter 2. EU enforcement practice - Airtours conditions 7 Chapter 3. Remedies under ECMR 12 Chapter 4. Coordinated behaviour cases in telecommunications market 20 Before Airtours 22 After Airtours 25 Conclusion 31 Bibliography 33 1 Introduction It is usually thought that the main problems of the competition law are cartels and monopolies. Trying to reach the ideal competition market, competition authorities all over the world chase the firms willing to gain maximized profits through either acquiring full control over the market or coordinating its common behaviour through agreements. However, there is another existing problem – oligopolies. This is a situation when there is more than one player on the market; but their number is not enough to constitute an ideal competition. Oligopolies are not illegal per se, because they could successfully exist and operate without causing any harm to the customer welfare. Unfortunately, this does not happen very often in the reality. In the oligopolistic market, the firms might choose one of the two behavioural directions: to not cooperate and simply coexist without bringing any innovation and progress, while just caring about getting a minimum profit; or coordinate their behaviour in an implicit way, therefore still coexisting, but being able to increase their profits. The second situation is often referred to as “tacit collusion”. In tacitly colluding markets firms would coordinate and resemble each other’s commercial policies, without entering in an actual agreement. Therefore, their behaviour does not fall under the prohibition of anti-competitive agreements. In the European Union (EU) there is an understanding in theory and practice that such firms might be enjoying a “collective dominant position”. Coordinated behaviour is not a characteristic of any oligopolistic market – there are certain conditions to be fulfilled. Still, even knowing these conditions, tacit collusion is often hard to chase. The problem stands in the number and list of these conditions, the effectiveness of current prosecution procedures and remedies applied. In over twenty years, the European Commission (Commission) has developed an approach where tacit collusion will only be chased ex ante, leaving ex post prosecution of the abuse of collective dominance through Article 102 of the Treaty on the functioning of the EU 1(TFEU) open. This way the preferred mechanism will be applying EU Merger control regulation (ECMR)2 in order to prevent the appearance or facilitation of coordinated behaviour. Even though the General Court expressed the position that Article 102 TFEU could be applied to tacit collusion,3 there have not yet been any decision by the Commission 1 Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) as amended by the Treaty of Lisbon (2007) Council regulation (EC) No. 139/2004 of 20 January on the Control of concentrations between Undertakings, (2004) OJ L24/1. 3 Piau v. Commission , (Case T-193/02), 6/01/2005, [2005] ECR II-209 2 2 in this regard. The problem might be laying in the field of proof: to define the existing coordinated behaviour in the absence of real agreement one has to use economic analysis of the market and present additional evidence of existing tacit collusion, which could be quite arguable. In its Guidance on enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to abusive exclusionary conduct (Guidance paper)4 the Commission has stated that it only applies to single dominance cases, therefore leaving collective dominance out of its scope: “Article 82 applies to undertakings which hold a dominant position on one or more relevant markets. Such a position may be held by one undertaking (single dominance) or by two or more undertakings (collective dominance). This document only relates to abuses committed by an undertaking holding a single dominant position”.5 The current situation regarding tacit collusion in EU may be seen as following: Commission de facto only addresses the problem of coordinated behaviour when examining proposed concentrations under ECMR, therefore leaving the question of correction of existing tacit collusion open. This approach does not always find support,6 but this is a reality we are coping with. The European Commission, as well as EU member states competition authorities (CA) fight coordinated behaviour through preventive measures, by analysing the risk of tacit collusion facilitation through mergers and either banning them or applying remedies to the companies in question. In this research paper, I would like to study the types of remedies and effectiveness of their application in coordinated behaviour cases. To narrow down the research, only telecommunications market will be analysed, studying both Commission and national CA decisions. Telecommunications market is often seen as the one giving a lot of opportunities in facilitating oligopolies, and, going further, tacit collusion. Given the limited number of firms operating on each of member state’s market and the nature of the business itself (for example, high barriers to entry), together with the recent changes of regulation,7 this area is an interesting one to analyse. Guidance on the Commission’s enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to abusive exclusionary conduct by dominant undertakings, December 2008, OJ C 45, 2009 5 ibid, note 241, para. 4 6 See, for example: N. Petit, D. Henry, “Why the EU Merger Regulation should not enjoy a monopoly over tacit collusion. A close look at five common misconceptions” (2010) 7 2009 Telecoms package; European Commission - MEMO/09/568 18/12/2009; Digital Agenda for Europe 2020, based on the Digital Priorities, available at http://ec.europa.eu/digital-agenda/en/news/digital-do-list-new-digitalpriorities-2013-2014 4 3 Chapter 1. Tacit collusion and coordinated behaviour Firms could collude in two different ways – explicitly, thus constituting cartels, and tacitly, avoiding the severe consequences of anticompetitive cartel behaviour and enjoying extra profits. Oligopolists might want to coordinate their prices or another variable without entering into any arrangement – be it contract, joint venture, trade association etc. The effect on the market will be the same as in explicit collusion, but formally, there will be none. The problem of tacit collusion was in the scope of research of lawyers and economists for many decades. Already in the late 20s, economist E.H. Chamberlin has described the classic model of tacit collusion. There, oligopolists compete for market share in a transparent market. Every time a player exercises a price cut he expects his rivals to do the same. It leads to the decision to not cut prices at all, because it would not make any sense. On the contrary, rivals would try to follow each other’s pricing policy through so called “tit for tat” interactions, thus steadily increasing prices. To make every player cooperate and prevent deviation from the common behaviour, there must be a possibility for punishment from other oligopolists.8 Back in 1960s, the economists of Harvard school trying to find the conditions triggering tacit collusion came to the analysis of market structure itself. According to them, there is a strong link between the number of players on the market and the supra-competitive pricing. Therefore, oligopolistic markets create conditions for tacit collusion as they are, just because of the small number of firms operating. This enables the transparency and “unreasonable” degree of market power for each of the players.9 The findings of Harvard school researchers were later criticised by Chicago school experts, bringing the efficiency of oligopolists’ conduct to the first place.10 The scholars of game theory entered in the new stage of studies over tacit collusion. They have proven that in an oligopolistic market, where firms meet regularly and infinitely, they would prefer to collude rather than compete.11 The oligopolists could tacitly communicate by sending each other various signals, and, the more they interact, the more united they become – the longterm profits would supersede the possible short-term profits from competing with each other. Whilst conducting further research on factors facilitating the origination of tacit collusion, game theory scholars have come to the four cumulative conditions to be fulfilled. Firstly, there must be a common understanding amongst oligopolists on the level the price should be raised (condition 1, C1). Secondly, a credible threat of retaliation should exist in order to depress any willingness to deviate from the common behaviour (C2). Then, there should be an ability for E. H. Chamberlin, “Duopoly: value where sellers are few” (1929), 44 Quarterly journal of economics. C. Kaysen, D.F. Turner, “Antitrust policy” (1959), Harvard University press, Cambridge 10 N. Petit, “Oligopoly problem in EU competition law” (2012), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1999829 11 J.W. Friedman, “A non-cooperative equilibrium for supergames” (1971), 38 Review of economic studies 8 9 4 oligopolists to monitor each other’s behaviour to notice any cheating (C3). Finally, the colluding players must have an ability to put barriers to entry for other firms (C4).12 Based on the game theory, economic analysts have also determined other key factors (besides the aforementioned ones), which could facilitate or block the sustainability of tacit collusion. However, these are not the necessary ones to establish a situation of coordinated behaviour, they could only have an effect on it. These include product homogeneity, market concentration, rate of innovation, frequency of interaction, low level of uncertainty and others.13 Based on their presence and intensity, these market features could be ascribed as “plus-factors” or “minus-factors”. Nonhomogeneous products compete not as strong as similar ones – this factor decreases the gains from cooperation. Besides, market players can deviate by increasing the quality of product. As opposed, the agreement on price or quantity is easier to reach while talking about homogeneous products. Market interaction is important as it facilitates fast responses to deviation and, subsequently, punishments. A high degree of uncertainty serves as an incentive for oligopolists to cooperate less, trying to reach one-time goals by deviating, thus making tacit collusion unsustainable. Where the market variables are certain, detecting cheating is easier and punishing strategies are more effective. To make market more transparent, firms would implement various facilitating practices, mainly some forms of exchange of information: they could publicly announce the prices, exchange information within professional associations etc. Such practices are developed to make tacit collusion easier: with their help, the benefits of deviation could be decreased, and the possibility of detection will be increased. That, consequently, reduces the costs of punishment. In a reality, that means that to facilitate collusion, firms need to do some work, as it would not arise by itself, just because of the certain market structure. As for today, the conditions, which increase the likelihood of tacit collusion, include, among others: transparent prices, frequent interaction, entry barriers, absence of countervailing buyer power, low number of competitors and symmetry of market shares.14 However, even the presence of those conditions does not necessarily mean that oligopolists will definitely coordinate their behaviour. The market players should solve at least two problems. First, they need to find a way to agree on the terms of the collusion – if no real agreement is to take place, this might be quite difficult. Secondly, even after there is a tacit agreement to “fix and abide”, there is still an existing possibility that one (or more) of the oligopolists will have an incentive to deviate.15 If a firm cuts N. Petit, “Oligopoly problem in EU competition law” (2012), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1999829 S. Ardiyok, “Comparative analysis of collective dominance” (2006), 3 Journal of Yeditepe University – Faculty of Law 14 Ivaldi et al, “The economics of tacit collusion. Report for DG Comp” (2003), European Commission. 15 George Stigler, “A theory of oligopoly” (1964), 72 Journal of political economy 12 13 5 its prices slightly, while they still remain above marginal costs, it will gain additional profit – and this is a strong motivation in many cases. A need for detection and punishment mechanism arises from there – all these portraying C2 and C3 conditions. With the presence of various research on factors facilitating tacit collusion, such as market characteristics, empirical analysis and behavioural economics analysis, there is still no overall, “one-size-fits-all” theory as in what is necessary for coordinated behaviour to appear and exist. Critics of tacit collusion theory often question whether it is a problem itself. Representatives of Chicago school16 state, for example, that there is always a possibility for one player to cut prices and gain extra profit, and no fear of punishment would stop him from doing so – the overall profit would still be worth it. Besides, other players might not apply any punishment at all, after estimating price war costs. The critics also mention that the market model on which theory is based is very far from the reality, it is too idealistic and does not take into consideration such factors, as different cost levels, various range of goods that firms have to offer, different market shares, buyer characteristics etc. It is however could be argued that these aspects do not diminish tacit collusion completely, but could act as “plus” or “minus” factors. Finally, the critique also exists in that the theory does not explain the differences of intensity of tacit collusion in different markets. Firms may even collude in price levels, but still compete on the product quality level, loyalty programs and advertising, thus decreasing the effectiveness of coordinated behaviour. It is clear, that product features, market differences, behavioural deviations and other factors make it impossible to develop one theory of tacit collusion that would fit any situation. Therefore, while examining the possible or already existing coordinated behaviour, it is important to count in four conditions for the appearance of tacit collusion, while still paying close attention to “plus factors” and “minus factors” which could affect it. Every situation is unique and arises from a handful of factors, and so should be remedies applied by competition authorities for each tacit collusion case. When talking about ex ante prosecution, there is no universal solution to the problem of tacit collusion prevention. However, before addressing the question of tacit collusion remedies, the question of investigation and prosecution shall be answered. The European Commission together with the Court of First Instance and General Court have established an approach for examining tacit collusion cases. This approach was a result of the developments in both case law and respective legislation. 16 For example, Bork, “The Antitrust Paradox” (Free Press, 1993) 6 Chapter 2. EU enforcement practice - Airtours conditions Although the economic studies on tacit collusion are very various and often thorough, it does not mean that all of them should and would be applied in practice. Moreover, enforcement policies sometimes could vary considerably from the scholars’ theories. As was mentioned before, nowadays in its enforcement against coordinated behaviour European Commission prefers the ex ante approach, therefore most often investigating the probability of tacit collusion when assessing proposed merger cases under ECMR. However, it has not always been this way. In the 1990s, it was not always clear from the Commission’s decisions whether the collective dominance and tacit collusion are different stand-alone theories or whether one is a part of the other. For example, it was addressing the problem of creating collective dominant position in both merger and Article 102 cases, without mentioning the tacit collusion or coordinated behaviour issues. By the end of the 1990s, it was clarified that the concept of collective dominance includes tacit collusion. In France v. Commission 17 the Court has indicated that a collective dominance position is possible between firms “because of correlative factors which exist between them”. This was not yet the clear definition, but already a step. Further, in Gencor Ltd. v. Commission, the General Court has explicitly described the tacit collusion situation by stating that: “there is no reason whatsoever in legal or economic terms to exclude from the notion of economic links the relationship of interdependence existing between the parties to a tight oligopoly within which, in a market with the appropriate characteristics, in particular in terms of market concentration, transparency and product homogeneity, those parties are in a position to anticipate one another's behaviour and are therefore strongly encouraged to align their conduct in the market, in particular in such a way as to maximise their joint profits by restricting production with a view to increasing prices”.18 The key decision, which changed the approach of both European Commission and national CA’s regarding tacit collusion, was Airtours.19 There the court has directly addressed the question of tacit collusion and clarified the conditions required to prove collective dominance.20 In this case, the Commission was revising the proposed takeover of First Choice by Airtours, both being in the top of four biggest UK package holidays companies. As was found by the Commission, the market presented a vertically integrated structure, where these firms were integrated with airlines upstream and retail distribution downstream. The merger would have led to the reduction of République française et Société commerciale des potasses et de l'azote (SCPA) et entreprise minière et chimique (EMC) v. Commission, CJEU, Case C-68/94, , ECR [1998] I-1375 18 Gencor Ltd. v. Commission, GC, T-102/96, 25 March 1999, ECR [1999] II-753, §276 19 Airtours/First Choice, (Case No IV/M.1524); GC, T-342/99, Airtours plc. v.Commission, 6 June 2002, ECR [2002] II-2585 20 N. Petit, “Oligopoly problem in EU competition law” (2012), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1999829 17 7 production costs, and would have had no major impact on the sustainability of their connections with partners, as, for example, they were using same travel agency chains. On the contrary, there was no countervailing buyer power from the smaller sized firms, as they needed to use big firms’ distribution channels. As for the level of demand, the Commission has established that there were homogeneous goods at place, as package holidays are normally chosen based on the price and the demand was not very price-sensitive. It has also found that the demand volatility could have an impact on collusion, making firms increase its capacity during selling season and cut it during the low season.21 Besides, according to the decision, four biggest travel companies, including the ones willing to merge, were significantly symmetrical and transparent in both planning and selling periods. Therefore, subject to the specific functioning of that market (planning and further selling seasons), the firms were able to collude on price levels during the planning season and further enjoy their maximized profits during selling period with no need to then coordinate their behaviour. The Commission also found that the market was sustainable to outside pressures and there existed an actual barrier to entry through control on two main factors of distribution – access to airlines and travel agencies. By acquiring First Choice, Airtours would not have reached the market share to the level necessary for single dominance; however, the collective share of the then three biggest firms would have raised and constituted 83%. The merger was prohibited by the Commission based on the high possibility of the creation of the collective dominance position. The decision states: “It is sufficient that the merger makes it rational for the oligopolists, in adapting themselves to market conditions, to act, individually, in ways which will substantially reduce competition between them, and as a result of which they may act, to an appreciable extent, independently of competitors, customers and consumers”.22 Addressing the question of the absence of mechanism for detecting deviations and low-cost punishments, it has noticed, that there are certain features of market structure and operation, which facilitate anti-competitive outcomes and in particular collective dominance. However, not all of them should be present in the case – and it did not count the retaliation mechanism as a necessary one for the collective dominance in the present case.23 In some authors’ opinion, the Commission has presented an unusual definition of collective dominance in this case. It has presumed that this situation would exist post merger, and was finding the justification for that in the current market conditions. Thus, it was moving in a deductive, not inductive way– where it would have analysed the market. This approach was not common for the Airtours/ First choice, (Case IV/M.1524), OJ, 2000, L-93/1-33, §§ 93-97 ibid, para. 54 23 ibid, para. 55 21 22 8 Commission and it has faced criticism onwards. For example, in the opinion of M. Filippelli, “this description of collective dominance is quite anomalous, especially if compared to the previous case law on this point, and even the methodological approach is different”.24 The author mentions that it was uncommon for the authority to hold that differences between products and volatility of the demand were not enough to serve as a deterrent to the collusion. This was meaning de facto a departure from the game theory and its core conditions. It was also argued that the Commission has put too big emphasis on the incentive of individual firms to avoid competition – that way, there was a notion of parallel conduct coming from an individual decision, rather than collective one (which is a detriment for tacit collusion and collective dominance).25 The outcome of the decision was not only the wide discussion, but also its appeal by Airtours in the Court of first instance (CFI).26 Its main grounds were the market definition, the inference of collective dominance and the evidence about the likelihood of post-merger coordination. The clarification of collective dominance definition is of the biggest interest for us. The court has defined three main conditions necessary to support the inference of post-merger coordination. Firstly, as tacit collusion needs reciprocal observation, transparency of the market plays an important role in facilitating and retaining collusion. The Court stated: “Each member of the dominant oligopoly must have the ability to know how the other members are behaving in order to monitor whether or not they are adopting the common policy. As the Commission specifically acknowledges, it is not enough for each member of the dominant oligopoly to be aware that interdependent market conduct is profitable for all of them, but each member must also have a means of knowing whether they are maintaining it. There must, therefore, be sufficient market transparency for all members of the dominant oligopoly to be aware, sufficiently, precisely and quickly, of the way in which the other members’ market conduct is evolving”.27 The main idea of this statement is the importance of transparency on the market for both creating and further maintaining of the collusion. The second condition defined by CFI was sustainability of the tacit collusion over time. The firms should have “an incentive not to depart from the common policy on the market”, so to say, they should all benefit from such parallel behaviour. CFI also underlines the importance of the retaliation mechanism, which is able to stop individual firm from deviation: “In this instance, the parties concur that, for a situation of collective dominance to be viable, there must be adequate deterrents to ensure that there is a long-term incentive in not departing from the common policy, M. Filippelli, “Collective Dominance in Competition Law” (2008), IMT Institute for Advanced Studies, Lucca, 88 J. Langer, “The Airtours judgement: a welcome lecture on oligopolies, economics and joint dominance” (2003) 26 Airtours plc v. Commission, (case T-342/99, 6 June 2002), ECR 2002, II-2585 27 ibid, para. 62 24 25 9 which means that each member of the dominant oligopoly must be aware that highly competitive action on its part designed to increase its market share would provoke identical action by the others, so that it would derive no benefit from its initiative”.28 Finally, it is important for the tacit collusion to be resistant to external factors: “the Commission must also establish that the foreseeable reaction of current and future competitors, as well as of consumers, would not jeopardise the results expected from the common policy”.29 While analysing the aforementioned conditions, it is safe to say that CFI has summarised the previous case law as well as economic doctrine. The Airtours conditions align with those of the game theory (C1-C4): common understanding (C1) and ability to monitor (C3) could be found in the transparency condition; a threat of retaliation (C2) was fully carried over to the internal stability condition; lastly, the ability to put barriers to entry (C4) could be found in the external sustainability condition. The Court has also analysed the Commission’s decision in its most contradictive points. It has ruled that demand volatility, which Commission saw as an incentive to collude, was actually a detrimental for firms to compete by enhancing the volume of their production during the selling season (§88-89). As to the existing vertical integration, the Court stated that this was not crucial for establishing tacit collusion, because it was, on the contrary, the source of possible efficiency gains (§105-106). The Court has argued the previous statement that the market was transparent enough to establish collusion. In its opinion, such factors as the complexity of market functioning, the demand volatility and different composition of holiday packages (product heterogeneity) were acting as an obstacle to the firms to be able to control their rival’s behaviour. In the analysis of the importance of retaliation mechanism, the Court has recognised its role, however stating that the incentive to maintain collusion is of the bigger importance here. In the CFI’s opinion, the Commission “must not necessarily prove that there is a specific retaliation mechanism involving a degree of severity, but it must none the less establish that deterrents exist, which are such that it is not worth the while of any member of the dominant oligopoly to depart from the common course of conduct to the detriment of the other oligopolists”.30 As the Court has established, the Commission has underestimated the countervailing buyer power of smaller firms and overestimated the high barriers to entry. As a result, it was stated that the external sustainability of the possible collusion was not present in the case. 28 ibid ibid 30 ibid, para. 195 29 10 Lacking all three conditions of tacit collusion, the Court has decided to overrule the Commission’s decision. It has also increased the standard of proof in such cases: “where the Commission takes the view that a merger should be prohibited because it will create a situation of collective dominance, it is incumbent upon it to produce convincing evidence thereof”. 31 The importance of the Airtours judgement could hardly be overestimated. The minimal conditions required to establish collective dominance (together with tacit collusion) were indicated for the first time. These conditions are based on the economic theory of tacit collusion, which excludes any notion of unilateral effects to it – which puts a border between unilateral effects and coordinated effects cases. Moreover, this decision served as a starting point to the following reform of European merger control system. The impact of Airtours could be found in the Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers,32 as well as Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers.33 Both these documents define various situations when the merger could significantly impede the competition. One of these situations is the creation of the collective dominance position or the coordinated effects on the market. The merger in question could change the competition on the relevant market if the firms are more likely to coordinate their behaviour or the existing coordination becomes “easier, more stable or more effective for firms”. 34 In assessing the probability of coordinated effects, the Commission will examine the following: whether the firms could reach the terms of coordination; monitor each other’s deviations; have deterrent mechanisms to prevent such deviations and be sustainable to any outsider influence. These conditions are consistent with those presented by the academics of game theory and later applied in Airtours case. After assessing the possibility of appearance or intensification of coordinated behaviour on the market, the Commission will take the required action. Because of the reform, the Commission has gone away from the checklist system to the more economic approach in analysing proposed mergers, which includes detecting one or more coordinated effects scenarios and further testing according to the theory of harm. According to such approach, the market features will be examined – including four cumulative conditions enabling tacit collusion. 31 ibid, para. 63 Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (2004/C 31/03) (“Horizontal merger guidelines”), Official Journal of European Union, C 31/5 33 Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (2008/C 265/07) (“Vertical merger guidelines”), Official Journal of European Union, C 265/6 34 Horizontal merger guidelines, 22 (b). 32 11 Chapter 3. Remedies under ECMR In the EU all mergers having Community dimension should be notified to the Commission in prior. The determining fact for the Community dimension is the turnover of the parties to the merger. Generally, if the transaction does not fall under certain threshold, it should be examined by the national competition authority. Once notified to the Commission, the proposed merger will be investigated during phase I with the possible outcome of: unconditional clearance, conditional clearance with remedies application or prohibition. The authority could choose to proceed to phase II investigation in order to study the case more in depth. The options for the outcome of the second phase of the investigation are generally the same as for the phase I.35 In about 5% of all merger cases in history of the European Commission, the deal was authorised upon the offer of sufficient commitments by the parties. As to the coordinated effects cases, the question of remedies has not been specifically addressed by the Commission in any of its documents. Both Horizontal guidelines36 and Remedies Notice37 do not clarify the way remedies should be in coherence with the theory of harm. It is especially important as the Commission might proceed to phase II investigation if it deems the proposed remedies insufficient – however, there is no clear guidance for the firms on what kind of remedies would suffice. The general approach of the Commission when accepting or rejecting the proposed remedies is their proportionality to the competition problem and ability to entirely eliminate it.38 It is possible to propose commitments in both phase I and phase II stages. The role of commitments seems to be important – due to their existence, there are so little cases where the merger was prohibited.39 When assessing the proposed remedies, the Commission would like them to completely address existing concerns in respect of the transaction, as well as they must be effectively implemented within a short period of time.40 Whilst the commitments introduced during phase I must rule out serious doubts regarding concentration’s competitive effects, those proposed in R. Whish, D. Bailey, “Competition law” (2012), 829 Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings, OJ C 31, 5.2.2004 37 Commission Notice on remedies acceptable under the Council Regulation 139/2004 and under Commission Regulation 802/2004 (Remedies Notice), OJ C 267, 22.10.2008 38 ECMR, Recital 30 39 C. Koenig et al, EC competition and telecommunications law (2009), 331 40 Remedies Notice, para. 9 35 36 12 phase II should be more precise and address certain competitive concerns already raised by the Commission. In both phases, the authority would appraise the remedies using legal and market analysis and stakeholders (such as customers, suppliers and competitors) would be given a chance to speak up as well. This way the Commission is getting the “genuine market perspective”.41 Each case is analysed individually, taking into account all relevant facts and circumstances. The Remedies Notice states in paragraph 12, that “in assessing whether the proposed commitments are sufficiently workable and lasting to ensure that the commitments will likely eliminate the competition concerns identified, the Commission will consider all relevant factors relating to the proposed remedy itself, including, inter alia, the type, scale and scope of the remedy proposed, judged by the reference to the structure and particular characteristics of the market in which the competition concerns arise, including the position of the parties and other players on the market”. Talking about the types of remedies, the Commission distinguishes two major forms of them – structural remedies and behaviour-related remedies. In the structural commitments, the special role is given to divestitures, as they are “the best way to eliminate competition concerns resulting from horizontal overlaps, and may also be the best means of resolving problems resulting from vertical or conglomerate concerns”.42 However, there exists a slightly different academic approach in generating the types of remedies. Based on the analysis of all coordinated effects cases under European merger control regulation (both Regulations 4064/89 and 139/2004) where remedies have been applied, three types of them could be distinguished.43 First type of remedies include those aiming to create or restore “competitive forces” outside of the oligopoly (type 1 remedies). These could for example include actions such as establishing new entrant / facilitating such entrance or strengthening of a current competitor. For this purpose, the parties could execute a divestiture of the company or its assets or make quasi-structural commitments – to transfer technology, to supply on non-exclusive terms etc.44 Type 2 remedies include those addressing the existing structural links within the oligopoly. This type of remedies will try to separate the existing firms from one another by cutting any existing connections between them. Such links could most often be found in existing joint ventures, cross-shareholdings, commercial links or membership in the professional associations. 41 ibid, para. 80 ibid, para. 17 43 N. Petit, “Remedies for coordinated effects under the European Union Merger regulation” (2010), Competition Law International, 6(2) 44 ibid 42 13 Thirdly, the remedies, which the Commission could apply (type 3), include those aiming to abolish behaviour easing tacit collusion – so called “facilitating practices”. These could include conduct making the market more transparent – for example, publishing of prices through trade associations. This was the case in Nestle/Perrier, where the firms made information about their sales volumes available to the association members. As could be seen from this classification, it follows the general path of the Commission’s typology when distinguishing structural and behavioural remedies. In the academic classification the emphasis is put on the structural remedies, where two main types are present – affecting the market structure from outside and from inside, same as the Commission’s typology lays the stress on divestitures, which is one of the structural remedies. The divestitures as a type of commitments is believed to be one of the most popular and preferred by the Commission. The divestiture would be the sale of the part of the business, a branch or a subsidiary, to a competitor. The reason behind the preference is that this type of remedy does not require monitoring after it was applied, as opposed to some behavioural remedies. 45 The divested unit must be able to act competitively, therefore it should include not only assets, but also personnel and customers. For example, in WorldCom/MCI, the initial commitment to divest some tangible assets was refused by the Commission, which stated that only the full divestiture including staff and customer base would suffice.46 The Commission underlined the importance of the competitiveness of the divested unit in Telia/Telenor, where the parties’ Norwegian and Swedish cable television businesses were sold. It stated that not only the units should be sold as a whole, including contracts, licenses and personnel, but also “each divestiture will be made to a viable existing or prospective competitor, unconnected to and independent of Telia and Telenor, and possessing the financial resources and proven expertise enabling them to develop the divested business into an active competitive force on the market. Each divestiture will be subject to the Commission’s express approval”.47 However, in coordinated effects cases type 1 remedies including divestiture are not the most popular ones. According to the study conducted by Nicolas Petit, in phase I investigations type 2 remedies were prevailing over type 1. However, in phase II proceedings type 1 remedies were used more often. This allows making a conclusion, that in cases “involving serious competition P. Papandropoulos, A. Tajana, “The merger remedies study – in divestiture we trust?” (2006), European competition law review, 445 46 WorldCom/MCI (II), (Case IV/M.1069), paras 145-163 47 Telia/Telenor, (Case COMP/M.1439), para. 383. 45 14 concerns”, the Commission regards type 1 remedies as a safer measure,48 whereas the possibility in applying type 2 remedies is not abolished either. Moreover, according to the DG Competition’s ex-post assessment of merger remedies, which were applied in cases between 1996 and 2000 (“The Remedies Study”),49 divestiture does not guarantee the effective competition on the market after its adoption. This type of remedies was only effective in 56 percent of the cases where it has been applied; it was partially effective in 25 percent of the cases.50 The effectiveness was measured based on the divested unit being able to effectively compete in three to five years following the divestiture. In collective dominance cases the picture did not differ: the divestiture remedy in one of the two cases “clearly failed”. 51 The study presented a number of issues relating to the application of divestiture remedies. In many cases, the commitment turned out to be insufficient or it was inadequate, for example, when the assets necessary for the successful functioning of the divested unit were not included or the scope of the divested business being identified wrongly. As a result, the divested entity was often not viable – this was especially the case in “mix and match” carve-out of assets (as opposed to the divestiture of stand-alone businesses).52 Another problem relating to the divestiture lays in the figure of the purchaser. In 11 cases, the choice of an insufficient purchaser led to the lack of effectiveness of the proposed remedy. For example, small companies are often incapable of competing efficiently after acquiring a new business. Besides, the divesting party could have narrowed down the list of potential buyers too much or provided them with insufficient information about the entity to be sold. 53 According to the study, there have been cases where the assets due to divest were not preserved in a proper way, which lead to the degradation of their value and viability. The parties were, for instance, retaining the key know-how or adopting pricing promotions prior to the divestiture of the business and using other jeopardizing practices in the process. The Commission saw the reason, amongst others, in the “interest for the parties…to limit the future competition by the purchaser in cases where they retained a business in the same relevant market”.54 N. Petit, “Remedies for coordinated effects under the European Union Merger regulation” (2010), Competition Law International, 6(2) 49 Merger remedies study, DG Competition, October 2005 (http://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/legislation/remedies_study.pdf) 50 ibid, page 134 51 ibid, page 39 52 ibid, page 73 53 ibid, page 69 54 ibid, page 70 48 15 Other type 1 commitments include access remedies, which could be quite effective when implemented in telecommunications market. As stated by the Commission, such remedies foster competition by “granting of access to key infrastructure, networks, key technology, including patents, know-how or other intellectual property rights, and essential inputs”.55 They can address one of the conditions for coordinated behaviour - an ability to put barriers to entry for other firms (C4). By granting access to its assets, being network in telecommunications, the barriers for new entrants are lowered, as well as the party is prevented from retaining its position on the market pre-merger.56 This type of remedies was first applied in wireless network markets in Vodafone AirTouch/Mannesman, where the competitors were enabled to make use of Vodafone’s panEuropean network.57 Another way to grant access was shown in B Sky B/Kirch Pay TV case in the pay-tv market, where Kirch committed to offer to all third parties its technical services “enabling the interested third parties’ digitally transmitted services…,where supported by Kirch’s technical platform, to be received by viewers authorised by means of digital decoders administered by Kirch”.58 However, another remedy in that case – to enter into “simulcrypt” agreements with all interested digital access providers – did not work at all, as no such agreements were concluded due to the absence of competent licensing authority in Germany.59 The access remedies must be working on a non-discrimination basis – so that any interested party may gain access to the facility (such commitments were given in Telia/Telenor,60 Telia/Sonera61 and other cases). When the access is connected with intellectual property rights, the Commission requires “the introduction of a compulsory conditional access license and an arbitration procedure for settling disputes concerning conditions, in particular the level of license fees, may indeed go some way to ensuring that third parties are not subject to discrimination where licensing is concerned”. 62 Alongside with necessary licensing, there could be cases when stand-alone access to the network would not suffice, as the parties are using different interface in such systems. When the interoperability is required, the Commission would approve the proposed remedy including such condition, as it did in MSG Media Service: “The introduction of a common interface appears from a competition point of view to be a solution to the problem of conditional access that would have 55 Remedies Notice, para. 62 C. Koenig et al, EC competition and telecommunications law (2009), 335 57 Vodafone AirTouch/Mannesman, (Case IV/M.1430), para. 58 58 B Sky B/Kirch Pay TV, (Case COMP/JV.37), Annex I, para. 1 59 C. Koenig et al, EC competition and telecommunications law (2009), 335 60 Telia/Telenor, (Case COMP/M.1439), para. 381 61 Telia/Sonera, (Case COMP/M/2803), para. 138-142 62 Deutsche Telecom/BetaResearch, (Case IV/M.1027), para. 64 56 16 a positive effect on the development of free and unfettered competition”.63 In this particular case, however, MSG has later stated that the common interface was not secure enough which has resulted in a commitment being “merely a declaration of intent”. To sum up, even though the various type 1 remedies, especially divestitures, seem to be the preferred ones by the Commission, they do not always guarantee the successful elimination of anti-competitive concerns in certain cases. Their effectiveness is often jeopardized by the market conditions or the incentive of the committing party to avoid the creation of a new strong competitor. There could be other obstacles when applying type 1 remedies. Some academics believe that the implementation of remedies of this type might lead to adverse economic effects. First, in remedies aiming to create a new player on the market (such as divestiture or giving access to network) they could result in cooperation of the parties concerned, thus giving rise to collusion or enhancing it.64 When negotiating over a prospective divestiture or when granting access to the facility, undertakings get a chance to exchange information. 65 In case it is in both notifying party and third party’s interest to avoid creating a competitive situation, they might end up in coordinating their behaviour post Commission’s clearance or a buyer might replace one of the merged entities in a duopoly.66 Secondly, the type 1 remedies (especially divestiture) could enhance symmetry on the already collusive market.67 Whilst reducing the merging parties’ market share, it simultaneously increases the share of the buyer – this leads to the more symmetric shares overall and remaining position of coordinated behaviour. This was the reason why the Commission rejected the proposed commitments in Alcan/Pechiney, where the divestiture of a capacity would have created “two players with symmetrical market positions”.68 Could different types of remedies be applied cumulatively? As for the application of type 1 and 2 remedies together, it remains a rare case. In most proceedings, the Commission would choose either one type or another, each of them addressing a certain anti-competitive concern. Opposite to that, type 3 remedies would always serve as an ancillary, being applied together with type 1 or type 2 remedies. In coordinated effects cases type 3 remedies are almost never used as a basis commitment. The reason probably lays in the Commission’s ability to address facilitating 63 MSG Media Service, (Case IV/M.469), para. 94 P. Papandropoulos, A. Tajana, “The merger remedies study – in divestiture we trust?” (2006), European competition law review, 449 65 M. Motta, M. Polo and H. Vasconcelos, “Merger remedies in the EU: an overview” (2003), Merger remedies in American and European Union competition law, 106 66 This was mentioned by the Commission in its Merger Remedies Study, page 103 67 M. Motta, M. Polo and H. Vasconcelos, “Merger remedies in the EU: an overview” (2003), Merger remedies in American and European Union competition law, 106 68 Commission press release, IP/00/258, http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-00-258_en.htm 64 17 practices through Articles 101 and 102 TFEU. 69 In addition, as previously mentioned, type 3 remedies require ex post control, and consequently additional working capacities from the Commission. It states in Remedies Notice, that “commitments relating to the future behaviour of the merged entity may be acceptable only exceptionally in very specific circumstances. (…) those types of remedies can only exceptionally be accepted if their workability is fully ensured by effective implementation and monitoring in line with the considerations set out in paragraphs 1314, 66, 69, and if they do not risk leading to distorting effects on competition”.70 It might be concluded that in merger control cases, anti-competitive concerns could be better solved through first two types of commitments, affecting the structure of the market, although this statement is sometimes argued by academics. They state that behavioural remedies are not always hard to implement, and often they are easy to monitor afterwards (for example, when there are already sufficient authority in place). 71 Moreover, this type of remedies seem appropriate in nonhorizontal mergers, as the concerns mostly arise not in regard to the market structure, but in the field of possible foreclosure – which could be avoided by applying behavioural commitments. Approval of the proposed remedy by the Commission is not the final stage of the merger control procedure. The implementation of the commitment could be done in three different ways, as Remedies notice and respective practice proposes. Firstly, the Commission may require the merging parties to implement the remedies before the final decision is made. 72 The second option is for the obligations to be conditional for the proposed merger. In RCA/MAV Cargo, the authority stated: “The two remaining commitments have to be fulfilled prior to the closing of the MAV Cargo transaction”. 73 The last way is to implement remedies following clearance – this is the most common situation.74 During the implementation, the parties have certain duties, such as preservation of the viability of assets which are about to be divested or appointing a special manager to keep these assets aside from the ones that firms are going to retain. The Commission has the right to approve the purchaser of the divested unit and appoint monitoring trustees to observe the compliance of the merging firms with the given conditions. In case the parties were not successful in a search for the buyer, a divestiture trustee will have a duty to find one. The Remedies notice points out the importance of divestiture trustees, saying that they “will be given an irrevocable and exclusive mandate to dispose N. Petit, “Remedies for coordinated effects under the European Union Merger regulation” (2010), Competition Law International, 6(2) 70 Remedies Notice, para. 17 71 P. Rey, “Economic analysis and the choice of remedies” (2003), Merger Remedies in American and European Union Competition Law 72 Remedies Notice, para. 5 73 RCA-MAV Cargo, (Case COMP/M.5096), para. 112 74 Remedies Notice, para. 5 69 18 of the business, under the supervision of the Commission, within a specific deadline at no minimum price to a suitable purchaser. The commitments shall allow the divestiture trustee to include in the sale and purchase agreement such terms and conditions as it considers appropriate for an expedient sale, in particular customary representations, warranties and indemnities”.75 Under the ECMR, the enforcement of remedial commitments is guaranteed with certain instruments. In case the parties fail to implement the approved remedies, the merger would not be authorised. If the concentration was already implemented, “it should be treated in the same way as a non-notified concentration implemented without authorization”.76 Moreover, the Commission has the authority to dissolve the already conducted merger in order to restore the initial situation on the market and impose fines on the breaching parties. 77 The Commission may face difficulties when enforcing type 2 remedies, as they often depend on the third parties. In cases when the firm has to withdraw from the joint venture it sometimes needs to get the approval of the contracting party first. When such remedies are not in favour of the players on the market and they are not interested in retaining a competitive situation, certain obstacles could be met. This problem was described in the Commission’s Remedies study, where it pointed out that third parties could “prevent or impede the implementation of remedies that affect them” through extended negotiations or unreasonable requests, initiated litigation etc.78 To sum up, the following could be stated regarding the remedies in coordinated effects cases. In general, the Commission has three types of remedies at its disposal: creating or restoring “outside” competitive forces after the merger; those severing structural links between competitors, which could facilitate coordination; and purely behavioural remedies aiming to cease the conduct facilitating tacit collusion. Of all these opportunities, the competition authority tends to choose between first and second type, leaving type 3 commitments as a substitute to the first two. However, their effectiveness is not always guaranteed: this is confirmed by the merger study carried out by the Commission. The problems may lie in the wrong choice of the commitments, their scope issues and enforcement procedures. 75 ibid, para. 121 ECMR, Recital 31 77 ECMR, Article 14 78 Remedies Study, paras. 46-47 76 19 Chapter 4. Coordinated behaviour cases in telecommunications market Telecommunications market is one of the most fast-growing and developing areas, which is characterised by constant innovation and is nowadays very consumer-oriented. However, historically, it was first a national states’ monopolised sector. With the input of the Commission, the liberalisation reform started in the 90s and it is still ongoing, aiming at granting access to the equipment, breaking up monopolies and ensuring consumer rights protection. One of the main goals of the liberalization process was boosting competition on the market and consequently lowering prices for end-users. First addressed at voice communications only, the regulation has widened to the broadband access in the early 2000s. The 2002 reform79 has covered all types of electronic communication: fixed-line voice telephony, mobile and broadband communications and cable and satellite television. The national regulatory authorities (NRA) were given obligations to promote competition in the sector. These included: ensuring maximum benefits for users in choice, price and quality; introducing general authorization procedure for network operators; encouraging efficient use of spectrum;80 establishing of trans-European networks and interoperability of pan-European services;81 internal cooperation of the authorities; ensuring the access to universal services82 and protection of personal data and privacy. 83 Besides, the overall transparency in both NRA activity and interoperators relations is to be guaranteed. One of the most important rights given to Member states in terms of promoting competition was an ability to impose the sharing of facilities or property on an undertaking operating an electronic communications network. In cases when the access to networks is limited due to environmental, health or public safety reasons or reproducing of infrastructure is not possible, the firm could be obliged to give access to its infrastructure. In the mobile industry, where Mobile virtual network operators (MVNO) already existed in some countries (for example, Virgin Mobile UK in the United Kingdom), this new regulation served as a booster for the growth in their number, and the growth of the number of competitors on the market accordingly. 79 Directive 2002/21/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on a common regulatory framework for electronic communications networks and services (Framework Directive) 80 Directive 2002/20/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on the authorisation of electronic communications networks and services (Authorisation Directive). 81 Directive 2002/19/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on access to, and interconnection of, electronic communications networks and associated facilities (Access Directive) 82 Directive 2002/22/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on universal service and users' rights relating to electronic communications networks and services (Universal Service Directive) 83 Directive 2002/58/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 12 July 2002 concerning the processing of personal data and the protection of privacy in the electronic communications sector (Directive on privacy and electronic communications) 20 The Regulatory framework package was amended in 2009 by Better regulation directive 2009/140/EC84 and Citizens’ Rights Directive 2009/136/EC,85 granting more rights to the end users and ensuring better transparency and interoperability on the market. The Single market for telecommunication services was supported by regulated rates on mobile calls and data transfer, as well as the recent positive vote of European Parliament on the ban of roaming costs within European Union.86 Overall, telecommunications area is nowadays regulated by both sector-specific regulatory authorities and competition authorities. Some see that sometimes competition regulators intervene in the sector more than they are required to, and “the Commission behaves more like an industrial regulator than a mere antitrust authority”.87 This sometimes raises concerns of the market players and academics, arguing that “competition law has been stretched beyond its reasonable limits and the institutional and legitimacy settings of antitrust do not justify its quasi-regulatory role”.88 The reasons for such exceeding of the authority might be seen in the recent behaviour of the players in the sector. Starting the 2000s, the consolidation trend of the industry has taken place. Once the prices were capped and the infrastructure monopoly was limited, the parties started seeking ways to compensate “the losses”. One of such ways is to merge and therefore cut production costs when often become able to offer a wider range of services.89 The role of the national competition authorities and the Commission is to control this process and not let the monopolization or creation of dominance position happen on relevant markets. Alongside with these two problems, the tacit collusion is also under the control of the Commission when assessing proposed mergers. 84 Directive 2009/140/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 25 November 2009 amending Directives 2002/21/EC on a common regulatory framework for electronic communications networks and services, 2002/19/EC on access to, and interconnection of, electronic communications networks and associated facilities, and 2002/20/EC on the authorisation of electronic communications networks and services, Official Journal L 337 of 18.12.2009 85 Directive 2009/136/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 25 November 2009 amending Directive 2002/22/EC on universal service and users’ rights relating to electronic communications networks and services, Directive 2002/58/EC concerning the processing of personal data and the protection of privacy in the electronic communications sector and Regulation (EC) No 2006/2004 on cooperation between national authorities responsible for the enforcement of consumer protection laws 86 “MEP heard loud and clear on telecoms laws”, April 3 2014, http://www.eubusiness.com/Members/BEUC/telecoms-laws/ 87 A. De Streel, The Relationship between Competition Law and Sector Specific Regulation: The Case of Electronic Communications (September 16, 2008). Reflets & Perpectives de la vie économique, XLVII, 2008/1, 55-72 88 ibid 89 ibid 21 Since the adoption of the first EU merger control regulation in 1989,90 the Commission has reviewed 286 merger notifications in telecommunications sector with Community dimension. 91 These include wired, wireless, satellite and other telecommunications activities. 127 of these cases were examined after the new merger control regulation (ECMR) came in force in 2004, followed by the Horizontal guidelines and Vertical guidelines, where the problem of coordinated behaviour was thoroughly addressed. Of all these cases, 6 were cleared with the proposed commitments, and only in 2 of them the Commission has mentioned the problem of tacit collusion. It seems reasonable to study cases both before and after 2004, in regard to the commitments proposed, as well as see how the Commission and national regulatory authorities were examining Airtours conditions relating to the coordinated conduct in proposed merger cases. Before Airtours There were two cases reviewed by the Commission before 2004, where the concerned were raised regarding tacit collusion, although this terminology was not explicitly used there. In Vodafone/AirTouch the authority has examined the proposed merger between two major wireless telecommunications providers. 92 Back in 1999, Vodafone was operating itself and through subsidiaries and associated companies in UK and 13 more countries worldwide, including EU states - France, Germany, Greece, the Netherlands and Sweden. AirTouch was mainly active in the United States, although it had ownership interests in cellular operators in 12 other countries, including European ones. The relevant markets in the investigation were defined as ones for mobile telecommunication services, with the geographical markets being national. The merger in question would have resulted in companies having market overlaps in two European countries: Germany and Sweden. No concerns arose in regard to the Swedish area, however German market turned out to be more problematic. Both parties were carrying interest and were able to exercise decisive influence over two of four Germany’s biggest mobile services providers – AirTouch had 34.8% in Mannesman Mobilfunk and Vodafone had 17,2% in E-Plus. According to the Commission’s study, newly combined entity would have decisive influence and joint control over two of the main three players (the fourth provider carrying a market share less than 5%), whose combined share is 50-60% of the market. Regarding the possible coordination of their behaviour, the authority stated, that “by creating a structural link between two of the three main market operators in Germany would create a duopolistic market situation, accounting for 90 Council Regulation (EEC) No 4064/89 of 21 December 1989 on the control of concentrations between undertakings, OJ L 257/90 P 13 91 Data from the advanced case search available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/index_en.html (last accessed 30.05.2014) 92 Vodafone/AirTouch, (Case No IV/M.1430) 22 almost 100% of the market”.93 It has added that the market was characterized by “considerable barriers to entry” and in which “information is readily available to customers and competitors who wish to make pricing comparisons”. We can see the Commission already pointing out the possibility of duopoly and mentioning two of tacit collusion conditions – barriers to entry and transparency. It has therefore ruled that there is a possibility of the future anticompetitive parallel behaviour. The Commission has cleared the transaction with the commitments proposed by the parties. To remove the competition concerns, the structural (type 1) remedy was offered by Vodafone: it has undertaken to divest its interest in German provider E-Plus. According to the decision, “the divestment would have the effect of removing any competition concerns which might otherwise have resulted from the overlap on the German market between the activities of E-Plus and D2”.94 The Commission found the remedies “sufficient” and declared the notified transaction compatible with the common market and with the EEA Agreement. The year after the Vodafone/AirTouch, another proposed merger came under the Commission’s examination. France Telecom, one of the biggest mobile and fixed line operators in France was intending to merge with Orange plc, a UK mobile telecommunication operator.95 Both parties, apart from being active in their home countries, also had interests in various joint ventures and thus were represented in other European countries, such as Belgium, The Netherlands, Spain and others. After examining the proposed concentration, The Commission found out that there were several product markets relevant to the case: mobile telecommunication services, the provision of pan-European services to internationally mobile customers and mobile handsets and mobile telephony network equipment. The concerns arose in one of these markets, namely the Belgian market for mobile telecommunication services, where both parties were present. According to the Commission, the proposed merger would have resulted in France telecom having joint control over two of three Belgian mobile operators – Mobistar SA and KPN Orange Belgium SA. This will subsequently reduce the number of firms from three to two. The authority has pointed out the available barriers to entry on the market due to the limited amount of available spectrum frequencies for new licensees. Besides, the historical perspective of the Belgian mobile telecommunication market was important. Before Orange (jointly with KPN) started operating, there were two players present – Mobistar and Proximus. They were keeping high tariffs at the 93 ibid, para. 28 ibid, para. 35 95 France Télécom/Orange, (Case No COMP/M. 2016) 94 23 similar level. According to the decision, “as Proximus and Mobistar were the only players on the Belgian market for mobile telecommunication and as they had a similar and transparent pricing, Proximus and Mobistar were in a position to exercise joint dominance and will not have any incentive to deviate from the collusive prices”.96 Therefore there existed a tacit collusion on the market. The newcomer, Orange, has broken that tendency and the prices has dropped down significantly, which was “an indicator of increased degree of competition”. Knowing that prehistory of existing price coordination, the elimination of Orange who broke “the duopolistic behaviour of both Proximus and Mobistar”, would have raised serious doubts of the Commission as to compatibility of the proposed merger with the common market. The concerns raised by the concentration were removed by the offered commitments. The parties has undertaken to divest Orange’s 50% stake in KPN Orange Belgium in order to eliminate the competitive overlap in Belgian market. Such divestiture meant that three players would remain on the market and the existing level of competition would be kept. To ensure that the remedies procedure goes in accordance with the decision and no confidential information is passed from Orange to France Telecom, a independent Trustee was appointed to “monitor the viability and saleability of the divestment” and “represent France Telecom in all bodies of KPN Orange Belgium”.97 The proposed structural (type 1) remedy has eliminated all Commission’s concerns regarding the possible coordinated behaviour on the Belgian mobile telecommunications market postmerger. Whilst the aforementioned cases were portraying the possibility of horizontal collusion, in NC/Canal+/CDPQ/BankAmerica the Commission has found the opportunity for the parties to coordinate their behaviour in vertical relations.98 The firms notified the proposed concentration in the form of joint venture on the French market of cable television services. The Commission has found no concerns regarding that market. However, it was found that the parties to agreement hold controlling interests in Spanish pay-tv market operators: BankAmerica together with CDPQ control Cableuropa, whereas Cable+ holds interest in Sogecable. At the same time, Cableuropa was a buyer of pay-tv rights from Sogecable. In its decision, the authority has ruled out the possibility of horizontal coordination of the parties on the Spanish market, because “Cableuropa is a new entrant in the pay-tv market and it needs to get as many subscribers as possible in the start-up phase, thus rendering a horizontal coordination with Sogecable on prices, quite unlikely”. 99 As opposed to that, it was found that 96 ibid, para. 26 ibid, para. 47 98 NC/Canal+/CDPQ/BankAmerica, (Case No IV/M.1327) 99 ibid, para. 32 97 24 “there are strong indicators that the notified operation could have led to the coordination of the competitive behaviour of Sogecable and Cableuropa in the Spanish market, in their vertical relation, i.e. with regard to access to the content rights needed to operate in the pay-tv market”. Besides, the Commission had concerns that it would lead to the “discrimination policy vis-a-vis other market players”. 100 All these concerns were addressed in the proposed remedies. Canal+ has undertaken that any future negotiations between Sogecable and Spanish cable operators with respect to the content over which the party has distribution rights, will be conducted “in a fair and non-discriminatory manner consistent with applicable European Union and Spanish competition laws”. 101 This was an example of behavioral (type 3) commitment, which has removed any competition concerns of the Commission in the given case and led to the clearance of the merger. The reason that standing alone type 3 remedy was sufficient to the Commission may be found in the nature of the concentration and the effect it was able to bring, which was vertical, not horizontal. After Airtours As previously said, the Airtours decision has indicated a milestone in the Commission’s and national competition authorities’ approach to the examining the existence of tacit collusion. It was later applied not only in respect to merger cases, but also in prosecuting collective dominance on the market with no regard to possible concentration, as it happened in Ireland. The conditions set up by the Court were used by Irish Commission for Communications Regulation (ComReg) in its analysis of the telecommunication market and were further approved by the Irish competition authority. The remedies proposed by ComReg in respect to the market for access and call origination on mobile telephone networks were later notified to the Commission and found no objection therein. 102 After the new EU communications framework directive103 came into force in 2003, the Irish communications authority conducted an examination of the telecommunications market. Its particular interest was lying in the wholesale market for access and call origination on public mobile telephone networks, as defined by the Commission Recommendation dated 11 February 2003 (market 15 in the document).104 According to this Recommendation, the presence of the certain market on the list was giving national authorities a possibility to apply ex ante regulation. 100 ibid, para. 38 ibid, para. 40 102 Registered notification for the case IE/2004/0121 103 Directive 2002/21/EC (Framework directive) 104 Commission Recommendation of 11 February 2003 on relevant product and service markets within the electronic communications sector susceptible to ex ante regulation in accordance with Directive 2002/21/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council on a common regulatory framework for electronic communication networks and services, OJ L 114/45 101 25 It was noted that such regulation would be warranted in the absence of effective competition on the market. ComReg has analysed the aforementioned market in accordance with the obligation set up in Article 16 of the Framework directive. In its study, the Irish authority has referred to both European legislation, among others, the Framework directive and SMP Guidelines, 105 as well as case law, such as CFI decision in Airtours.106 In the view of ComReg, two of the four Irish mobile network operators, Vodafone and O2, were enjoying a collective dominant position and coordinating their behaviour. The finding was based on the following analysis. While examining the market structure, ComReg was answering the question whether it was “such that O2 and Vodafone, in becoming aware of a range of common economic interests, could consider it possible, economically rational, and hence preferable, to adopt on a lasting basis a common policy on the market aimed at selling at above competitive prices, without having to enter into an agreement or resort to a concerted practice and without any actual or potential competitors, let alone customers or consumers, being able to react effectively”.107 In its review, the authority has examined the following market structure elements: (a) the degree of market concentration; (b) the incentive to coordinate; (c) the ability to coordinate; (d) the ability to detect cheating; (e) enforceability of compliance; (d) and actual and/or potential market constraints. As could be seen, the (c)-(d) elements portray the classic tacit collusion conditions, implemented from Airtours. After the assessment, ComReg has concluded that the market is characterized by the high degree of concentration, having only four players, two of which (Vodafone and O2) have a combine share of 94% of subscribers. It has also stated that it is unlikely that in the nearest future the two other firms will be able to influence the competition situation significantly. The incentives of the firms to collude were found to be stable due to the oligopolistic situation on the market and relatively symmetric (40% and 54%) market shares of two undertakings. The competitors “frequently interact with one another through their common participation in various practices common to a networked industry”. 108 The demand on the relevant market was “expected to remain at current levels or grow”, therefore enhancing the incentives to collude. Altogether, ComReg has decided that there were sufficient incentives for firms to coordinate their behaviour. 105 Commission guidelines on market analysis and the assessment of significant market power under the Community regulatory framework for electronic communications networks and services (2002/C 165/03), OJ C 165/6 106 See document: “Response to Consultation and Notification to European Commission. Market analysis – wholesale mobile access and call origination” by Commission for Communications Regulation, Ireland, dated December 9, 2004. http://www.comreg.ie/_fileupload/publications/ComReg04118.pdf 107 ibid, para. 4.26 108 ibid, para. 4.47 26 The analysis of the market has shown that it has sufficient level of transparency to enable Vodafone and O2 to collude, in terms of both price and denying access of independent entities to upstream elements. The ability of customers to exercise countervailing buyer power was found to be insufficient due to the absence of independent service providers on the wholesale level. After studying the data on the growth of the subscriber number in years 2001-2004, ComReg has concluded that it was similar for Vodafone and O2. Therefore, it believed that “due to transparency in the retail market, it would be readily identifiable as it would lead to a reduction in demand at the firm not deviating and be associated with an increase in demand with the firm deviating”. 109 This has supported the view on the ability of firms to detect cheating of the rival. It also was the view of ComReg that the absence of deviation in prices over these years was due to the existence of the retaliation mechanism – for example, by “lowering retail prices or by offering wholesale airtime on terms that enable independent service providers to offer lower retail prices”.110 While discussing the actual and potential market constraints, the authority has addressed fringe competitors’ activity and the emergence of potential competitors. The existing competitor Meteor has not made a major impact on the rivals’ prices and, according to the view of ComReg, would be unable to exert sufficient competitive pressure in the wholesale market over the expected lifetime of the market review.111 The potential competitors in the form of MVNO were unlikely to appear as Irish providers “seem unlikely to conclude [wholesale access] deals”.112 All these structural characteristics of the wholesale market led to the conclusion that there was a high possibility for the firms to collude. Besides, there was a behavioural evidence that tacit collusion between Vodafone and O2 already existed – in terms of price levels, profitability measures and denial of access to wholesale airtime. With regard to the finding of two firms holding a position of joint dominance, ComReg also concluded that they were having significant market power jointly with each other. As a draft measures, the Irish communication authority proposed to impose several obligations on Vodafone and O2.113 These included both structural and behavioural remedies: obligation to provide network access following a reasonable request by an access seeker; non-discrimination obligation; obligation of price control to be implemented by way of cost orientation; Obligation to 109 ibid, para. 4.82 ibid, para. 4.93 111 Access and call origination on public mobile telephone networks in Ireland, (Case IE/2004/0121) 112 ibid, para. II.2 113 Response to Consultation and Notification to European Commission. Market analysis – wholesale mobile access and call origination, Article 6. 110 27 prepare separated accounts; Obligation to implement appropriate cost accounting systems. The last three obligations referred to the founding of the ComReg of existence of supracompetitive pricing on the market, and were to be implemented only in the case of first two being unsuccessful. After the analysis and proposed measures were notified to the Commission, the latter has issued its comments on the document, which were not, however, in any major opposition to the ComReg’s findings. Interestingly, the decision was later appealed to the Electronic Communications Appeal Panel (ECAP) by Vodafone, O2 and Meteor. Following the appeal, the telecommunications authority agreed to annul its decision. The reasoning behind it is still arguable, as some believe that ComReg’s initial decision was “inconsistent with the facts in several respects”,114 such as symmetry if Vodafone and O2’s market shares, their excessive charges, and competitiveness of the remaining players on the market. However, this does not change the fact that Irish communications authority has conducted the full analysis of the possibility and existence of tacit collusion on the relevant market in accordance with the EU legislation and case law. The new approach for the assessment of coordinated behaviour was implied in the Commission’s merger cases practice as well. In Telefonica UK/Vodafone UK/Everything Everywhere, the authority has examined the possibility of the tacit collusion post proposed creation of a joint venture between the parties on mobile wallet market.115 The question posed was whether the firms had an incentive to engage in a collective foreclosure strategy against rival mobile wallet operators. After an analysis, the Commission ruled out the emergence of such strategy “based on tacit and on-going coordination between the Notifying Parties” as it is “unlikely that all of the conditions laid down in the Airtours judgment would be met in the case of commercial foreclosure”. 116 The reasons for this finding were as follows: the coordination in question was hard to implement; once established, it might not be internally stable, because the threat of punishment did not outweigh possible gains from deviation; the rival third party providers had a possibility to deploy counterstrategies as well; the barriers to entry on the market were not high. Given all these arguments, the Commission concluded the low chance of the parties engaging in a coordinated foreclosure strategy. Another case where the Commission has applied the new approach in assessment of coordinated behaviour was Syniverse/BSG.117 The proposed merger would have decreased the number of players on the GSM roaming data clearing services market from three to two. However, the authority, despite its common practice, did not find any grounds to the possible emergence of 114 P. Massey, M. McDowell, Joint Dominance and Tacit Collusion: An Analysis of the Irish Vodafone/O2 Case and the Implications for Competition and Regulatory Policy, (2008) UCD Centre for economic research, WP08/05 115 Telefónica UK/Vodafone UK/ Everything Everywhere/ JV, (Case No COMP/M.6314) 116 ibid, para. 441 117 Syniverse/BSG, (Case No COMP/M. 4662) 28 duopoly. The reasoning behind this decision was that the rival company, Mach, was an acknowledged market leader 118 and strong competitor. After the proposed merger, it would remain the leader with overall market share of 50-60% against Syniverse/BSG combined share of 30-40%. The Commission has assessed the four conditions necessary to analyse the possibility of coordination on the market and found out that it “does not seem likely that the proposed merger would lead to coordinated effects”.119 It is hard to establish a common understanding on the market as it has a dynamic structure and bidding nature. Due to the low transparency, it will be hard to detect deviation, as well as apply a credible retaliation mechanism. The collusion was also unlikely because of the strong possibility of outsiders jeopardizing the results of coordination. The new players are likely to enter the market, as well as the market itself is characterized as innovative and therefore unstable for the purpose of collusion. 120 As a result, the Commission has cleared the concentration with no additional commitments. As previously mentioned, there were two cases after the implementation of the new system of assessment of tacit collusion where the authority has agreed with the proposed commitments. These were Hutchison/Orange and T-Mobile Austria/tele.ring, both affecting the Austrian telecommunications market. In Hutchison/Orange, the Commission studied the likeliness of the parties coordinating their behaviour post-merger.121 It named the conditions to be checked and “found that some characteristics of the Austrian mobile telecommunications market may be conducive to coordination and some past parallel behaviour of the Austrian MNOs could point to coordination”. However, despite this finding, the authority has decided that “the indications did not meet the requisite standard of proof the Commission has to meet according to the case law, namely a significant impediment to effective competition leading to coordinated effects”. 122 Nevertheless, lacking the thorough examination of Airtours conditions, the proposed remedies were still assumed sufficient as they “aim to facilitate market entry and thus also address possible coordinated effects”.123 The parties offered to provide wholesale assess to Hutchison’s network for up to 16 MVNOs in the coming 10 years. Together with that, the acquisition would not be finished before Hutchison enters in such agreement with one MVNO. Besides, the party has committed to divest a certain radio spectrum together with additional rights to a new entrant on the Austrian market.124 After assessment of the remedies, the Commission has decided that “the 118 ibid, para. 38 ibid, para. 106 120 ibid, para. 109 121 Hutchison 3g Austria / Orange Austria, (Case No M.6497) 122 ibid, para. 448 123 ibid, para. 449 124 ibid, para. 526 119 29 Final Commitments are appropriate to eliminate the non-coordinated effects identified and, moreover, the possible coordinated effects”.125 As a result, the concentration was cleared subject to fulfillment of the structural remedies offered by the parties. The competition concerns were raised by the Commission in T-Mobile Austria/tele.ring.126 According to the case, Austrian mobile operator T-Mobile had an intention to acquire tele.ring, which would have led to the removal of so called “maverick” on the market. The market analysis has shown that “not only that tele.ring has played an active role on the market in the last three years but also that it has been the only company to play such an active role, in terms of increased market share”.127 Besides, it was indicated that “tele.ring exerts the strongest competitive pressure on Mobilkom and T-Mobile in particular”128 and “plays a crucial role in restricting their freedom on pricing”.129 Therefore, the elimination of such a player would result in the reduction of capacity and “the merger would have a considerable impact on competition”.130 In the assessment of possible coordinated effects, the Commission came to the conclusion that such possibility could not be ruled out. It has pointed out to the proposed merger leading to the shares of the competitors becoming more symmetric, as well as removing of a maverick making the price coordination easier. However, the full analysis was not conducted because “the commitments proposed by the notifying party rule out the possibility that the transaction will lead to coordinated effects on the Austrian end-customer market for mobile telephony services”. 131 The parties to the merger proposed to sell a part of tele.ring’s UMTS frequencies and mobile communication sites on the basis of framework agreement, which was further concluded with mobile operator H3G.132 Therefore, such commitments constituted an example of type 1 (divestiture) remedies. According to the decision, they were “capable of eliminating the risk that the merger in its original form would significantly impede effective competition”,133 and resulted in the clearance of the concentration. 125 ibid, para. 538 T-Mobile Austria/tele.ring, (Case No COMP/M.3916) 127 ibid, para. 43 128 ibid, para. 51 129 ibid, para. 72 130 ibid, para. 100 131 ibid, para. 129 132 ibid, para. 130 133 ibid, para. 154 126 30 Conclusion The problem of tacit collusion has been addressed by academics, legislators and enforcement authorities for many decades. In a search for factors facilitating coordinated behaviour of firms on the market, many theories and approaches were presented. In the EU, the CFI was the first to define the conditions necessary to establish and maintain tacit collusion, whose findings were later implemented in the legislation. These conditions, sometimes named “Airtours” conditions, refer to both market structure and behaviour of the players there. According to CFI, the firms are most likely to coordinate their conduct if they are able to reach the consensus on their agreement, further monitor and punish any deviations of the rival and have enough power to sustain the outsiders’ influence. In the telecommunications sector, the problem of tacit collusion exists as well as in other economic areas. It was examined by the European Commission mostly while assessing proposed merger cases, but also while studying the notification of national regulation authority. According to the research conducted in this master thesis paper, it could be said that the number of tacit collusion cases as opposed to overall number of merger cases The Commission examines in telecommunications market, is relatively small. However, once the possibility of the coordinated behaviour is found, the decision would always accept remedies addressing, among others, this issue. Based on the data analysed, the most common type of commitment was structural, with the prevalence of divestiture (type 1) over other alternatives, such as granting access to the network (type 1), being the second most popular. The Commission has also approved the implementation of behavioural remedies, namely obligation of non-discrimination, where it was a complementary in one case and the main undertaking in another case. As previously notices, the possibility of behavioural remedies to be the primary commitment was almost fully ruled out by Remedies Notice, however the decision in question was issued by the Commission before the aforementioned document came into force. Besides, this was the only case of possible vertical coordination, so this might also be the reason why type 3 remedy was found more sufficient. None of the represented cases has shown an example of the Commission applying type 2 remedies – those aiming to severe structural links between competitors. The reasoning behind it possibly lays in the absence of any such connections in given cases or, where they presumably existed (see France Telecom/Orange), the authority found it more effective to implement type 1 commitments, also addressing the structure of the market. 31 It is not unusual to apply multiple remedies – it happened in Hutchison/Orange and in Irish market analysis. In both cases, the authorities were dealing with not only possible future coordination, but also existing one (in Ireland) or past (in Austria). This might explain the desire to use more than one type of commitment, as these cases could be called more “complicated”. Interestingly, in France Telecom/Orange, where the Commission was also dealing with the signs of past coordination, divestiture alone turned out to be enough. Therefore, it is not possible to establish the strong correlation between “complexity” of the case and the number of remedies applied. In analysis of the most often applied remedies – divestiture and access to network – it could be concluded that they are used due to the features of the telecommunications market. Its main facility is network, which is restricted due to the technical characteristics (radio spectrum). Therefore, once in possession of such asset, the firm could try to exercise anti-competitive behaviour, be it unilateral or joint. In order to overcome such situation, the number of players should be increased. This could be accomplished by either selling them such facility or granting access to it. Even though such remedies could not guarantee the absence of the collusion (and this could also be seen in the results of the Commission’s remedies study), they would at least ensure that there would be enough firms to prevent possible market concentration, and subsequently, coordination. Regarding overall implementation practice of the European Commission in respect to coordinated behaviour, it could be said that it might be further developed. Once the problem would be addressed not only while examining merger cases, but also when finding of concerted practices facilitating any or all of the tacit collusion conditions, the situation on the market will improve. For example, when all but one conditions already exist, the parties might want to facilitate the last one, as it happened in the Netherlands134 when the firms decided to discuss the prices, which has enabled future price parallelism. Such practices should be tackled more often, using economic approach and trying to avoid formalism. After such enforcement trend is established, there will be hope that the market players will be coordinating their behaviour less and the problem of tacit collusion will be addressed not only through preventive measures, but also against existing forms. 134 CJEU, T-Mobile Netherlands BV and Others v Raad van bestuur van de Nederlandse Mededingingsautoriteit, (Case C-8/08) 32 Bibliography EU legislation Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) as amended by the Treaty of Lisbon (2007) Council Regulation (EEC) No 4064/89 of 21 December 1989 on the control of concentrations between undertakings, OJ L 257/90 P 13 Directive 2002/21/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on a common regulatory framework for electronic communications networks and services, OJ L 114/45 Directive 2002/20/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on the authorisation of electronic communications networks and services (Authorisation Directive). Directive 2002/19/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on access to, and interconnection of, electronic communications networks and associated facilities (Access Directive) Directive 2002/22/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on universal service and users' rights relating to electronic communications networks and services (Universal Service Directive) Directive 2002/58/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 12 July 2002 concerning the processing of personal data and the protection of privacy in the electronic communications sector (Directive on privacy and electronic communications) Council regulation (EC) No. 139/2004 of 20 January on the Control of concentrations between Undertakings, (2004) OJ L24/1. Directive 2009/140/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 25 November 2009 amending Directives 2002/21/EC on a common regulatory framework for electronic communications networks and services, 2002/19/EC on access to, and interconnection of, electronic communications networks and associated facilities, and 2002/20/EC on the authorisation of electronic communications networks and services, Official Journal L 337 of 18.12.2009 Directive 2009/136/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 25 November 2009 amending Directive 2002/22/EC on universal service and users’ rights relating to electronic communications networks and services, Directive 2002/58/EC concerning the processing of personal data and the protection of privacy in the electronic communications sector and Regulation (EC) No 2006/2004 on cooperation between national authorities responsible for the enforcement of consumer protection laws Commission Notice on remedies acceptable under the Council Regulation 139/2004 and under Commission Regulation 802/2004 (Remedies Notice), OJ C 267, 22.10.2008 33 Commission Recommendation of 11 February 2003 on relevant product and service markets within the electronic communications sector susceptible to ex ante regulation in accordance with Commission guidelines on market analysis and the assessment of significant market power under the Community regulatory framework for electronic communications networks and services (2002/C 165/03), OJ C 165/6 Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (2004/C 31/03) (“Horizontal merger guidelines”), Official Journal of European Union, C 31/5 Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (2008/C 265/07) (“Vertical merger guidelines”), Official Journal of European Union, C 265/6 Guidance on the Commission’s enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to abusive exclusionary conduct by dominant undertakings, December 2008, OJ C 45, 2009 EU Cases Access and call origination on public mobile telephone networks in Ireland, (Case IE/2004/0121) Airtours/ First choice, (Case IV/M.1524), OJ, 2000, L-93/1-33, §§ 93-97 B Sky B/Kirch Pay TV, (Case COMP/JV.37) Deutsche Telecom/BetaResearch, (Case IV/M.1027) France Télécom/Orange, (Case No COMP/M. 2016) Hutchison 3g Austria / Orange Austria, (Case No M.6497) MSG Media Service, (Case IV/M.469) NC/Canal+/CDPQ/BankAmerica, (Case No IV/M.1327) RCA-MAV Cargo, (Case COMP/M.5096) Syniverse/BSG, (Case No COMP/M. 4662) Telefónica UK/Vodafone UK/ Everything Everywhere/ JV, (Case No COMP/M.6314) Telia/Sonera, (Case COMP/M/2803) Telia/Telenor, (Case COMP/M.1439) T-Mobile Austria/tele.ring, (Case No COMP/M.3916) 34 Vodafone AirTouch/Mannesman, (Case IV/M.1430) Vodafone/AirTouch, (Case No IV/M.1430) WorldCom/MCI (II), (Case IV/M.1069) CJEU République française et Société commerciale des potasses et de l'azote (SCPA) et entreprise minière et chimique (EMC) v. Commission, (Case C-68/94), ECR [1998] I-1375 T-Mobile Netherlands BV and Others v Raad van bestuur van de Nederlandse Mededingingsautoriteit, (Case C-8/08) CFI Gencor Ltd. v. Commission, (case T-102/96, 25 March 1999), ECR [1999] II-753, §276 Airtours plc v. Commission, (case T-342/99, 6 June 2002), ECR 2002, II-2585 Piau v. Commission , (Case T-193/02, 6 January 2005), [2005] ECR II-209 EU Member States authorities “Response to Consultation and Notification to European Commission. Market analysis – wholesale mobile access and call origination” (9.12.2004) by Commission for Communications Regulation, Ireland. http://www.comreg.ie/_fileupload/publications/ComReg04118.pdf Registered notification for the case IE/2004/0121 Books Bork, “The Antitrust Paradox” (Free Press, 1993) Koenig C. et al, EC competition and telecommunications law (2009) Whish R, Bailey D, “Competition law” (2012) Journal articles Ardiyok S, “Comparative analysis of collective dominance” (2006), 3 Journal of Yeditepe University – Faculty of Law Chamberlin E.H, “Duopoly: value where sellers are few” (1929), 44 Quarterly journal of economics. 35 De Streel A, The Relationship between Competition Law and Sector Specific Regulation: The Case of Electronic Communications (September 16, 2008). Reflets & Perpectives de la vie économique, XLVII, 2008/1, 55-72 Filippelli M, “Collective Dominance in Competition Law” (2008), IMT Institute for Advanced Studies, Lucca, 88 Friedman J.W, “A non-cooperative equilibrium for supergames” (1971), 38 Review of economic studies Ivaldi et al, “The economics of tacit collusion. Report for DG Comp” (2003), European Commission. Kaysen C, Turner D.F, “Antitrust policy” (1959), Harvard University press, Cambridge Langer J, “The Airtours judgement: a welcome lecture on oligopolies, economics and joint dominance” (2003) Massey P, McDowell M, Joint Dominance and Tacit Collusion: An Analysis of the Irish Vodafone/O2 Case and the Implications for Competition and Regulatory Policy, (2008) UCD Centre for economic research, WP08/05 Motta M, Polo M and Vasconcelos H, “Merger remedies in the EU: an overview” (2003), Merger remedies in American and European Union competition law, 106 Papandropoulos P, Tajana A, “The merger remedies study – in divestiture we trust?” (2006), European competition law review, 445 Petit N, “Oligopoly problem http://ssrn.com/abstract=1999829 in EU competition law” (2012), available at Petit N, “Remedies for coordinated effects under the European Union Merger regulation” (2010), Competition Law International, 6(2) Petit N, Henry D, “Why the EU Merger Regulation should not enjoy a monopoly over tacit collusion. A close look at five common misconceptions” (2010) Rey P, “Economic analysis and the choice of remedies” (2003), Merger Remedies in American and European Union Competition Law Stigler G, “A theory of oligopoly” (1964), 72 Journal of political economy Electronic resources http://ec.europa.eu/competition/index_en.html 36 “MEP heard loud and clear on telecoms http://www.eubusiness.com/Members/BEUC/telecoms-laws/ laws”, April 3 2014, Commission press release, IP/00/258, http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-00-258_en.htm Merger remedies study, DG Competition, (http://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/legislation/remedies_study.pdf) October 2005 Digital Agenda for Europe 2020, based on the Digital Priorities, available at http://ec.europa.eu/digitalagenda/en/news/digital-do-list-new-digital-priorities-2013-2014 37
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz