A Proposal For Financing Postmarketing Drug Safety Studies By

Use r
Fe e s
A Proposal For Financing
Postmarketing Drug Safety
Studies By Augmenting FDA
User Fees
An incremental policy reform that would enable the FDA and others to
exit the current dilemma regarding drug safety and public trust.
by Daniel Carpenter
ABSTRACT: I propose to raise funds for postapproval studies of long-term drug safety by
augmenting the existing “user-fee” system. Fees would be raised by an amount deemed optimal for revenue collection, and the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA) would direct
the incremental funds to a combination of randomized controlled trials, epidemiological
studies, and postmarketing surveillance. User-fee augmentation is an achievable, incremental reform that would subsidize information that is now undersupplied in the U.S.
health care system; spread the burden of funding postmarketing safety studies among
pharmaceutical sponsors; and help restore public, scientific, and professional confidence
in the FDA and its user-fee system.
R
e c e n t e v e n ts h av e e x p o s e d several problems in U.S. pharmaceutical
regulation. Critics have pointed to insufficient regulatory attention to
safety issues, an emphasis on quick approvals over safety, an undue dependence on pharmaceutical companies by the U.S. Food and Drug Administration’s (FDA’s) drug review branch (Center for Drug Evaluation and Research, or
CDER), the role of drug user fees in promoting such dependence, the severe
undersupply of information on long-term safety, the failure of the FDA to compel
(and of pharmaceutical companies to complete) Phase IV studies, and others.
There is no consensus on the existence, nature, and severity of these problems. Yet
the trust of citizens, professionals, and health care providers in pharmaceutical
regulation has been damaged.1 The very appearance of regulatory failure is a
source of public and professional worry.
Rightly so. Perhaps the most important benefit of FDA regulation is not that it
keeps unsafe drugs from U.S. citizens, but that patients and their physicians can
enter the pharmaceutical marketplace confident that the nation’s drug supply is
Daniel Carpenter ([email protected]) is a professor and director of graduate studies in the
Department of Government, Harvard University, in Cambridge, Massachusetts.
H E A LT H A F F A I R S ~ We b E x c l u s i v e
DOI 10.1377/hlthaff.W5.469 ©2005 Project HOPE–The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc.
W5-469
D ru g
Saf e t y
safe and effective. In other words, the value of sound FDA regulation lies not just in
the fact of safety but in the beliefs it conveys. There is reason to believe that doctors, patients, and drug companies have all benefited enormously from this aggregate confidence over the past half-century, as I suggest below. In the absence of
trustworthy regulation and science-based drug development, the market for prescription drugs might look more like that for herbal supplements or the snake-oily
patent medicines that federal regulation long ago stamped out. In other words, a
healthy society; a successful health care system; and a profitable, innovative world
for pharmaceuticals all depend acutely on the actual and perceived safety of drugs.
Yet Americans’ belief in the safety and efficacy of drugs depends heavily on their
belief in the safety and efficacy of the FDA and the pharmaceutical industry.
At the moment, those beliefs have taken something of a hit. Recent polling reports by the Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation and Harris Interactive point to an
appreciable decline in public confidence in the pharmaceutical industry over the
past few years. By a three-to-one margin, Americans feel that drug companies “put
profits ahead of people,” and in terms of “favorability” ratings and reputation for
“customer care,” the industry now ranks near the bottom of the U.S. economy,
ahead only of tobacco and (slightly) of oil, and well behind airlines, banks, life insurance, and other industries. More troubling is the fact that this image battering
is a recent development. In 1997, when asked whether the pharmaceutical industry did a good job or a bad job of serving its customers, fully 79 percent of respondents reported that pharmaceutical companies had done a “good job,” with only 19
percent reporting a “bad job”; as recently as May 2002 the good/bad ratio was 59
percent to 22 percent. Yet in April 2004 the percentage of “bad job” respondents
outnumbered “good job” respondents by 48 percent to 44 percent.
The FDA’s esteem appears to have suffered less damage, yet here, too, there are
warning signs. Politicians from both major parties have worried about an erosion
of “public confidence” in the FDA, and a “lack of trust” appears to characterize the
FDA’s image in the eyes of professional associations, providers, and many other
health care stakeholders. Moreover, in a recent Gallup poll, 37 percent of respondents said that their confidence in the FDA has declined in the past few years,
while only 8 percent said that it has risen. Significantly, these declines in trust
have not affected other sectors of the health care system, such as doctors, hospitals, or even insurance companies and third-party providers.2
In this paper I propose an incremental policy reform that would enable the
FDA, citizens, doctors, health care providers, health plans and insurers, and pharmaceutical companies to exit the current dilemma. The basic idea is to increase
user fees and use the incremental monies to fund improvements in postmarketing
safety regulation. Specifically, the monies could fund epidemiological studies, randomized controlled trials (RCTs) to assess and compare the long-term safety profiles of widely used drugs for chronic conditions, and administrative and technological improvements to FDA postmarketing surveillance.
W5-470
18 October 2005
Use r
Fe e s
My proposal is simple; it would require amending the current user-fee law to
increase the annual per application user fee by a percentage to be decided by Congress. For illustration, let us say that the user fee is hiked by 25 percent. Under a
linear projection, a 25 percent increase in user fees would generate $42 million in
additional revenue for fiscal year 2005.3 Readers can imagine less money or more,
depending on their preferences. Exhibit 1 lists the different aggregate revenues
that could be raised from various percentage increases in FDA user fees.
Spending The Amounts Collected
n
Allocation. How could $42 million from a 25 percent user-fee augmentation
be allocated to improve postapproval safety regulation? I propose three ways.
Fund RCTs of widely used drugs for chronic conditions. One lesson of recent years is that
Americans know too little about the long-term safety of drugs, particularly those
for chronic conditions. This is something of a system failure and certainly a market
failure. There exists no financial incentive, and insufficient reputational incentive,
for long-term drug safety to be studied. It would appear that adequate experimental studies of long-term safety would cost $3–$7 million per trial. If perhaps half of
the increment from our 25 percent increase—that is, $21 million—were devoted
to RCTs of this sort, we could launch three to seven high-quality, long-term safety
studies (all of them randomized and fully controlled clinical trials) per year. These
studies could be conducted by the FDA or the National Institutes of Health (NIH)
or by academic medical centers (AMCs) with strong biostatistics centers, using
grants from the FDA. Ideally, such studies would be guided by well-defined and
defensible criteria for the evaluation of medical technologies.4
One question is whether so few studies could address the U.S. deficit in information about long-term drug safety. This is a reasonable concern, but I offer two
responses. First, FDA officials and health care providers probably have their
hunches about which drugs on the market present the greatest long-term safety
risks. Well before Merck withdrew Vioxx, concern was expressed about its safety
among physicians at Cleveland Clinic (Eric Topol) and FDA epidemiologists (David Graham), among others.5 So it is not hard to imagine that given proper funding,
EXHIBIT 1
Hypothetical Aggregate Funds From User-Fee Augmentation In Prescription Drug
Development
Fee increase
Amount per
application ($)
Fraction of current
development cost
10%
25%
50%
60%
67,200
168,000
336,000
403,200
0.000084
0.000210
0.000420
0.000504
Total annual revenue
augmentation ($)
16,800,000
42,000,000
84,000,000
100,800,000
SOURCE: Author’s calculations.
H E A LT H A F F A I R S ~ We b E x c l u s i v e
W5-471
D ru g
Saf e t y
“FDA epidemiologists need access to more data, including studies
comparing long-term safety profiles across drugs.”
the FDA and its advisory committees would be inclined to target funds toward
drugs presenting the greatest (subjectively perceived) risks.
Second, one lesson from the experience with Vioxx is that we should look hard
at widely used drugs for chronic conditions: those prescribed to millions of patients over many years. Among other classes, these would now include COX-2 inhibitors, selective serotonin reuptake inhibitors (SSRIs) and atypical antipsychotics, statins, prescription sleeping aids, and drugs for erectile dysfunction. The
medical and public health rationale for this targeting would be to focus on drugs
whose risks are not easily detected under current regulatory programs but whose
risks (conditional upon utilization patterns) can aggregate into high total morbidity and mortality (or, if you will, high aggregate quality-adjusted life years, or
QALYs, forfeited). When drugs have this Vioxx-like market, even small changes in
the relative risk of adverse events can add up to staggering numbers of deaths and
injuries. With utilization data from the public and private sectors, combined with
information technology (IT) advances, FDA scientists should be able to identify
drugs in need of regulatory attention.6
Fund epidemiological studies of postmarketing safety in the long run. RCTs provide a
better, more reliable take on whether a causal relationship exists between a drug
and adverse safety risks, but they are often poor at helping translate that information into what people need to know: How safe and effective are drugs when they
are prescribed in actual clinical practice and taken under nonexperimental conditions? For this reason, a nontrivial fraction of the user-fee augmentation ought to
be devoted to epidemiological studies. Although purchasing and partnership in
data sharing should be encouraged, FDA epidemiologists need access to much
more data than they have now, including studies comparing long-term safety profiles across drugs.7
Fund improvements to FDA surveillance infrastructure. Augmented user fees could also
be used to increase the FDA’s organizational capacities by hiring more epidemiologists, purchasing more data, and upgrading IT, thereby allowing its scientists to
better aggregate and analyze epidemiological and utilization data (including adverse-event reports, or AERs).8
n Institutions and criteria. Who should decide how augmented funds are allocated across studies? And what criteria should guide these choices? Prudence might
suggest separating the allocation function from the CDER’s reviewing divisions,
perhaps by involving a trustworthy FDA advisory committee. A statutory commitment that a minimum proportion of the funds be spent on clinical trials and epidemiological studies, a role for meaningful administrative discretion is preserved, an
advisory committee role—all three of these mechanisms could increase the credibil-
W5-472
18 October 2005
Use r
Fe e s
ity of the program.
As for criteria, consider the recent recommendations of Jerry Avorn and the
FDA’s own Robert Temple. Avorn’s mixed strategy of “generating new information” as well as “digging out the [existing] data on risk” focuses most heavily on
comparative safety data, how one drug’s safety profile compares to those of other
treatments for the targeted condition, or even with other treatments in the drug’s
class.9 So some minimum proportion (perhaps 20 percent) of the funds should be
devoted to comparative RCTs and case-control epidemiological studies of this
sort. Temple has proposed a general conceptual scheme for what kinds of postmarketing studies are needed, under what circumstances. His rule of thumb is to
begin by using existing surveillance (including AERs) to establish the existence of
safety issues and to generate hypotheses. Where the hypothesized increase in risk
is modest, and where utilization is broad, reliance on RCTs is called for. Where
hypothesized or suspected increase in risk is manyfold (>2), then epidemiological
studies using case-control methods are more appropriate. The data discussed here
could supplement AER data, which should not be abandoned but used in conjunction with RCTs and epidemiological studies.10
n The value of bandwagoning. One way of investigating safety rigorously yet
more cheaply is to use ongoing trials for supplemental new drug applications. Upon
approval of a new molecular entity (NME), many companies continue studying the
compound for potential use for other medical conditions. Much as the NIH and
medical researchers do, the FDA can “jump aboard” these existing clinical studies
for supplemental efficacy submissions and create trial arms for safety studies.11
Advantages
n
Restoring confidence. Perhaps the most important benefit of a user-fee augmentation policy is the greater credibility and legitimacy it would lend to current
and future drug regulation. With improved postmarketing safety regulation, the
public’s confidence in the FDA could increase appreciably, and hence the public’s
(and doctors’) confidence in the nation’s supply of pharmaceuticals could increase as
well. Once the user-fee system is understood to support postmarketing safety studies as well as premarketing review, many physicians’ doubts about the perverse incentives and effects of the current user-fee system will be addressed and perhaps
answered. And once the pharmaceutical industry is seen as making direct contributions to the funding of postmarketing safety studies as well as speedier premarketing review, its own public legitimacy would likely benefit.
Neither in science, nor in medicine, nor in government, nor in business do we
rely heavily on markets to tell us how good drugs are. We rely instead upon largescale statistical studies conducted prior to market entry.12 Given learning difficulties, physicians and patients face something of a lottery when they enter an unregulated pharmaceutical market—they can only guess at how good the products
are. This can lead risk-averse consumers and physicians to forgo use of pharma-
H E A LT H A F F A I R S ~ We b E x c l u s i v e
W5-473
D ru g
Saf e t y
ceuticals altogether. Yet if patients and doctors are persuaded that the worst
drugs—bad both in efficacy and in safety—will not enter the market or be very
unlikely to do so, greater confidence will result, to the benefit of all in the health
care marketplace.13 Conversely, if confidence in the FDA’s ability to screen out the
worst drugs dwindles, then doctors and patients might well avoid treatments that
would otherwise benefit them.
Politicians, journalists, and policy analysts have spoken vaguely about this
“confidence mechanism,” but they seem to recognize its potential. Although no
empirical studies of these phenomena exist, there is suggestive evidence from the
decades before and after the 1962 Kefauver-Harris Drug Amendments. Those
amendments coincided with a decline in the introduction of NMEs to the marketplace, as the FDA began to sift good from bad products and as the costs of pharmaceutical research and development (R&D) increased. Yet other patterns also followed the amendments: The volatility of prescription patterns and their prices
declined, per drug sales rose, and drug prices declined.14 It is plausible, then, that
U.S. pharmaceutical markets were characterized by greater stability and certainty
following stronger regulation.
It is quite likely that the proposed user-fee augmentation will improve public
confidence in regulation. A large number of recent complaints about drug regulation are aimed at a perceived “imbalance” at the FDA. Prominent observers have
lamented that the user-fee system is tilted too much toward the approval of new
medicines and not enough toward their safety.15 If an augmentation proposal does
nothing else, it will specifically, formally, and publicly commit tens of millions of
dollars per year to safety-related studies and surveillance. And as the funded studies make their way into academic, public, and regulatory discussions, the public
will increasingly recognize the contribution of augmented and safety-directed
user fees.
n Funding scientific studies of long-term safety. A user-fee augmentation
would also help correct the rather severe deficiency we face in knowledge about
drugs’ long-term safety. By financing three to seven large-scale, long-term clinical
trials per year, just half of the augmented user fee could address a critical failure of
the current pharmaceutical market and regulatory system. Large epidemiological
data sets—of the sort that have assisted detection of associations between estrogen
and endometrial cancer, between SSRIs and teenage/adolescent suicide, and between Vioxx and heart attacks—will also be required.
Our current policy of relying on Phase IV studies and postmarketing surveillance falls far short of addressing the public’s need for greater safety information,
for several reasons. First, the completion rate and quality of data for Phase IV
studies are quite poor. Recent data suggest that of the 1,191 Phase IV postmarketing commitments that had been made as of 30 September 2004, 68 percent had yet
to be commenced, compared with the 30 percent that were either ongoing or already submitted. Drug companies lack incentives to complete these studies, and
W 5 - 4 74
18 October 2005
Use r
Fe e s
the FDA lacks the legal authority and the political incentive to compel them once a
drug is approved. In addition, the set of available punishments is brute. Faced
with a firm that refuses to honor its Phase IV commitments, the FDA cannot issue
fines, restrict advertising, or administer any administrative penalty save that of
withdrawing approval of the company’s NDA. The political incentives weighing
against withdrawal—as well as the punishment this delivers to patients and physicians—render Phase IV commitments essentially unenforceable.16
Second, many Phase IV studies are insufficiently powered or not designed to
address long-term safety, which is the very issue raised by the Vioxx and SSRI debates. Finally, some critics believe that the FDA often requests Phase IV studies in
the final days of a drug review, which leaves little time for sponsors to work with
the agency in shaping trials that are feasible and informative. As an unfortunate
result of this pattern, many Phase IV studies are poorly designed or conceived and
are doomed to fail from their outset.17
Political And Legal Obstacles To Reform
There are real and nontrivial obstacles standing in the way of this policy proposal. Generally, one can imagine a proposal such as this “taking hits from both
sides” (from the industry and consumer-safety advocates).
n Pharmaceutical industry. As with the passage of the Prescription Drug User
Fee Act (PDUFA) in 1992 and revisions in 1997 and 2002, industry assent will be required to change the user-fee law in Congress. For at least three reasons, the industry might be reluctant to embrace user-fee augmentation. First, it might dislike the
additional tax imposed upon pharmaceutical submissions. Second, it might dislike
the diversion of user-fee revenues to any purpose other than quicker approvals (in
other words, it might fear that if funds are diverted, progress in accelerating approval times will decline). Third, pharmaceutical firms and their political representatives might view federal funding of more safety studies with suspicion, preferring
instead to conduct such studies on their own, independent of government promotion or oversight.
These obstacles are real but not insurmountable. Consider the following three
points.
(1) Precedent in existing law and proposals, and plausible support from industry. PDUFA III,
enacted in 2002, contains provisions for postmarketing surveillance. So industry
has already agreed to postmarketing surveillance funding from user fees; the real
question is whether the proposed hikes in these fees will be unpalatable. On this
point, the benefits of the proposal and, most important, the specter of uncertain
PDUFA reauthorization could induce industry to see an augmentation program as
a good deal. Conservative commentators and industry supporters have all embraced the idea of more funding for the agency’s postmarketing safety program.18
(2) A political mechanism: establish user-fee augmentation and user fee–funded safety studies
as the political price for PDUFA reauthorization. Although industry assent might be re-
H E A LT H A F F A I R S ~ We b E x c l u s i v e
W5-475
D ru g
Saf e t y
“If the user-fee monies are seen as simply whitewashing drug-safety
issues, then the money will have done only harm.”
quired for user-fee augmentation, industry enthusiasm might not be. PDUFA itself cannot live on past 2007 without congressional reauthorization, and that program has come under increasing attack. The industry’s assent is needed politically
for PDUFA reauthorization, but so is the assent of Congress. In light of recent
events, it would hardly be surprising if user-fee reauthorization in 2007 were the
target of a broader backlash: scrutiny from members of both parties, obstruction
from well-placed committee chairs in both chambers, or even a filibuster.
PDUFA’s supporters, including many in industry, will soon realize this prospect, if
indeed they do not fear it already.
The possible political conflict and uncertainty over the user-fee reauthorization might allow policymakers to extract some policy concessions from the pharmaceutical industry and (separately) from the FDA. The industry presumably
wants the user-fee act to continue. Suppose, then, that a user-fee hike, combined
with safety-related expenditures from user-fee revenues, were presented to the industry as the political price of PDUFA reauthorization. Indeed, thinking prospectively, pivotally positioned legislators might be in the best position to deliver such
a message. In light of the specter of uncertain reauthorization of the entire user-fee
program, an augmentation plan begins to look like a good deal for industry.
(3) Reputational and informational benefits of the proposal. In the aggregate, I think that
it is possible to persuade drug companies that they would benefit from more and
higher-quality information on safety—information that could be better distributed using improvements from the user-fee augmentation. Using an argument
such as that advanced by Avorn, one could make the case that collective action
problems prevent pharmaceutical firms from investing in data-gathering mechanisms that are in their interest.19 The industry’s public reputation, now quite
weak, would also stand to benefit.
n Consumer-safety advocates and patient groups. Fears of the conflict of interest created by user fees have led many observers to propose scrapping the system
altogether; voices for a consumer-safety focus at the FDA might not readily agree to a
hike in the fees that would perpetuate the system.20
These concerns are understandable and real. The key concern to address is the
credibility of safety-related studies and analyses undertaken with monies from the
user-fee augmentation. If the user-fee monies are seen as simply whitewashing the
drug-safety issues in U.S. health care, then the money will have done only harm.
Here the partial independence of the allocation authority is crucial; the user-fee
monies should be allocated by decisionmakers from both within and outside of
the FDA, whose responsibility and interest is not the approval of drugs, but their
postmarketing regulation. Moreover, studies funded by the user-fee augmentation
W5-476
18 October 2005
Use r
Fe e s
should be fully revealed to the public, and any such disclosure commitment
should be made before a study commences.
With the proper institutional protections, safety advocates will see an augmented user fee as a costly and real commitment by industry and the FDA to bolster the study and regulation of drugs after they have entered the marketplace.
With these protections in mind, it warrants remark that there was genuine support in some quarters of the medical profession as little as five years ago for using
user-fee monies in much the way I have proposed here.21
n Problems with other proposals. Other proposals advanced to solve the problem have more daunting problems. Per prescription taxes are politically unpalatable
and would require a costly new administrative apparatus to collect. FDA mandates
for Phase IV studies are widely ignored now, and few if any of these studies are observational or directly compare therapies. As with any discretionary component of
general revenues, FDA appropriations can always be cut in any fiscal crisis, which
means that they are less stable on an annual basis.22
Answers To Questions And Concerns
n
Isn’t this a tax on pharmaceutical companies? Will it discourage innovation? Prescription drug user fees are a per application tax on pharmaceutical producers. No analysis of the problem should sidestep that fact. Yet the benefits of a
stronger user-fee system and a credible program for drug-safety analysis would outweigh the relatively small costs of a user-fee hike. If user-fee augmentation made it
less likely that insurers and providers would remove approved products from their
formularies for safety reasons (as recently occurred with COX-2 inhibitors), or that
doctors and patients would shy away from new FDA-approved products, is it then
not easily conceivable that these benefits would aggregate at least to tens of millions
of dollars annually for the industry?
One might be concerned, still, that a user-fee hike would slow innovation. For
most companies, this is arguably not an issue. Other determinants of development
cost dwarf user fees by multiples of hundreds or thousands. From 1991 to 2003 the
Tufts Center for the Study of Drug Development estimate of drug development
cost rose from $291 million to $802 million. From 1994 to 2004, the nominal value
of the per drug user fee rose from $208,000 to $672,000, or less than a half-million
dollars. In other words, the increase in user fees can account at most for 0.12 percent of the increase in development costs over the past decade, and this calculation assumes that the user-fee system brings no offsetting benefits with it. Even if
development costs are a nonlinear (convex) function of nominal user fees, the
overwhelming share of the increase in drug development costs must be attributable to other factors. Another consideration comes from a second glance at Exhibit
1: For a 25 percent increase in the product user fee by itself to render drug development unprofitable, the present-value margin of the product at the date of regulatory submission must be at or below $168,000. This seems exceedingly unlikely for
H E A LT H A F F A I R S ~ We b E x c l u s i v e
W5-477
D ru g
Saf e t y
any drug now under development.
n Didn’t PDUFA III (2002) already devote user-fee revenues to drug safety?
Not for the kind of information that everyone agrees is needed. PDUFA III allocates
several million dollars per year to the collection and analysis of AERs.23 AER data are
useful, and along with the FDA’s Temple, I envision them as allowing hypothesis
generation and complementing observational and experimental studies. Yet AER
data are far from sufficient for rigorous analysis of drug safety, and if the monies were
used for surveillance only, the user-fee augmentation will have been a wasted policy
opportunity.
n Couldn’t these studies be used against pharmaceutical manufacturers
in court? We already have Phase IV trials and ongoing epidemiological studies that
present this risk. Clearly, then, tort risk cannot be a prohibitive consideration here;
otherwise, even the modest level of Phase IV clinical trials and epidemiological studies that we observe today would not be carried out. It is possible, though, that to expand postmarketing safety studies, some restrictions on the evidentiary use of federally funded studies in tort cases might be considered.
n Why rely on taxation rather than enforcement of existing policies? The
FDA really has no enforcement authority. It cannot issue fines, cannot compel Phase
IV studies, and cannot enforce Phase IV commitments. So the agency’s weaknesses
leave it with a brutal trade-off: Let companies off the hook, or withdraw NDA
approval altogether (a political disaster that hurts patients). Moreover, increased
enforcement and the present proposal are not exclusive options. The funds from
user-fee augmentation can be used to bolster enforcement and (just as important) to
supplement the data gained from enforcement. The user-fee augmentation policy
proposed here offers much more incremental, more achievable mechanisms for postmarketing analysis and regulation of drug safety.
A
s av o r n h a s r e c e n t ly w r i t t e n, “The initial FDA approval of a drug
should be seen as the beginning of an intensive period of assessment, not
the end.” For a decade, user fees have been used with great effect to accelerate “initial approval.”24 Let us now harness them for improving drug-safety activities as well, not just by increasing postmarketing surveillance but by funding scientifically sound studies (experimental and observational) of the drugs used most
widely and durably in our health care system. User-fee augmentation might not
solve all of the problems facing the FDA, the U.S. health care system, and the pharmaceutical industry. Yet an augmentation proposal would cost little, fund the revelation of health information that is now undersupplied, and offer a means for increasing public confidence in the current health care system, which seems perhaps
the first place for policy reforms to start.
W5-478
18 October 2005
Use r
Fe e s
Daniel Carpenter acknowledges a Robert Wood Johnson Investigator Award in Health Policy Research, a Robert
Wood Johnson Scholar in Health Policy fellowship, the National Science Foundation (SES-0076452 and SES0351048), and Harvard University (the Center for American Political Studies and Institute for Quantitative
Social Science) for support. The author neither seeks nor accepts research funding or any other form of
compensation from the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA), from private entities that sponsor product
applications to the FDA, from patient advocacy groups, or from public interest research groups (PIRGs). Sanford
Gordon, three anonymous reviewers, the editors, and Alan Cohen offered helpful commentary and criticism. All
errors, omissions, and interpretations are the author’s alone.
NOTES
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
J. Avorn, Powerful Medicines: The Benefits, Risks, and Costs of Prescription Drugs (New York: Knopf, 2004); P.B.
Fontanarosa, D. Rennie, and C.D. De Angelis, “Postmarketing Surveillance—Lack of Vigilance, Lack of
Trust,” Journal of the American Medical Association 292, no. 21 (2004): 2647–2650; and S. Frantz, “How to Avoid
Another ‘Vioxx’,” Nature Reviews—Drug Discovery 4, no. 1 (2004): 5–7.
Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, “Views on Prescription Drugs and the Pharmaceutical Industry,”
Health Poll Report, January/February 2005 Featured Topic, www.kff.org/healthpollreport/feb_2005/
upload/full_report.pdf (19 September 2005); and J. Appleby, “Poll: Confidence in FDA Still Strong Despite
Blunders,” USA Today, 23 November 2004.
The current law is Title 5 of the Public Health Security and Bioterrorism Preparedness and Response Act
of 2002, also known as PDUFA III. User-fee figures are from Notices, Federal Register 69, no. 147 (2004):
46165–46168. For supplementary material, see D. Carpenter, “The FDA Project,” people.hmdc.harvard
.edu/~dcarpent/fdaproject.html (28 September 2005).
T.J. Moore, Prescription for Disaster (New York: Dell, 1999). On clinical trial costs, for which estimates are
very hard to come by, see the remarks by Richard Platt, Harvard Medical School, in G. Harris, “FDA to
Create Advisory Board on Drug Safety,” New York Times, 16 February 2005. See also the Cenetec Corporation’s 2001 estimate of $1.5–$2.5 million per trial; Cenentec, “Cenetec LLC Announces Marcon, Pioneer in
Web-mased Clinical Trials, as First Client at Gainesville Technology Accelerator,” Press Release, 7 May
2001, www.cenetec.com/NV_news_PR_05072001.htm (19 September 2005). For a discussion of technology decision criteria, see A. Cohen and R.S. Hanft, Technology in American Health Care (Ann Arbor: University
of Michigan Press, 2004), 30–71; R. Temple, “Meta-Analysis and Epidemiologic Studies in Drug Development and Postmarketing Surveillance,” Journal of the American Medical Association 281, no. 9 (1999): 841–844;
and Institute of Medicine, Setting Priorities for Health Technology Assessment (Washington: National Academies
Press, 1992).
D. Mukherjee, S.E. Nissen, and E.J. Topol, “Risk of Cardiovascular Events associated with Selective COX-2
Inhibitors,” Journal of the American Medical Association 286, no. 8 (2001): 954–959.
Avorn, Powerful Medicines, makes a similar argument. See also S. Gottlieb, “Opening Pandora’s Pillbox: Using
Modern Information Tools to Improve Drug Safety,” Health Affairs 24, no. 4 (2005): 938–948; and D.J.
Malenka et al., “Postmarketing Surveillance of Medical Devices using Medicare Claims,” Health Affairs 24,
no. 4 (2005): 928–937.
Avorn, Powerful Medicines, chap. 21.
Gottlieb, “Opening Pandora’s Pillbox”; and Malenka et al., “Postmarketing Surveillance.”
See A.J. Wood, C.M. Stein, and R. Woosley, “Making Medicines Safer: The Need for an Independent Drug
Safety Board,” New England Journal of Medicine 339, no. 25 (1998): 1851–1854; Temple, “Meta-Analysis and
Epidemiologic Studies”; and Avorn, Powerful Medicines, 370–371, who also suggests gathering comparative
efficacy data.
I thank an anonymous reviewer for many of the considerations in this section.
I thank an anonymous reviewer for this suggestion.
For accessible discussions of credence goods, see M. Law, “The Origins of State Pure Food Regulation,”
Journal of Economic History 63, no. 4 (2003): 1103–1130; and M.T. Law, “History of Food and Drug Regulation
in the United States,” EH.Net Encyclopedia, ed. R. Whaples, 12 October 2004, eh.net/encyclopedia/article/
Law.Food.and.Drug.Regulation (19 September 2005). The classic hypothesis of reduced consumption under uncertainty appears in G. Akerlof, “The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market
Mechanism,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, no. 3 (1970): 488–500. For mathematical formalization of this
argument, applied to health settings, see D. Carpenter, “A General Model of Placebo Learning: How More
H E A LT H A F F A I R S ~ We b E x c l u s i v e
W5-479
D ru g
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
Saf e t y
Patient Options Can Increase Bias and Reduce Welfare” (Unpublished manuscript, Department of Government, Harvard University, 2005); also J. Das, “Do Patients Learn about Doctor Quality? Theory and an
Application to India” (Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Economics, Harvard University, 2001). On how
randomized controlled trials supplant market mechanisms, see H. Marks, The Progress of Experiment (New
York: Cambridge University Press, 1997) and Temple, “Meta-Analysis and Epidemiologic Studies.”
Note, for instance, the recent decision of Kaiser Permanente to remove Bextra from its formulary, even
though the FDA has allowed the drug to remain on the market.
P. Hilts, Protecting America’s Health (New York: Knopf, 2003), 193–194, 214. When Health and Human Services (HHS) Secretary Michael Leavitt announced recent changes at the FDA, he stated that “the FDA is
an icon of trust, a certifier of safety, an enabler of innovation, and a repository of information.” Whether
the decline in new molecular entities in the 1960s is traceable to the 1962 Amendments is not clear; see
Law, “History of Food and Drug Regulation.” For evidence on increasing per drug sales after the amendments, see M.B. Balter, “Coping with Illness: Choices, Alternatives, and Consequences,” in Drug Development and Marketing, ed. R.B. Helms (Washington: AEI Press, 1975), 37–43; and D. Schwartzmann, “Pharmaceutical R&D Expenditures and Rates of Return,” in ibid., 68–69. Per drug data on prescription patterns
are unavailable, but the variance of prescription drug prices dropped heavily after the 1962 regulations. In
the twelve years before the 1962 amendments, the variance of the pharmaceutical CPI was 18.7 CPI points,
whereas the variance in the twelve years following the amendments was 6.1 points—less than one-third of
its pre-1962 value. The level of the prescription drug CPI also fell continuously during the 1960s, from 51.4
in 1961 to 46.9 in 1970, and reached its pre-regulation peak only in 1976. All data are from Consumer Price
Indices as calculated by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor.
S. Frantz, “Vioxx Fears Prompt Call for User Fee Evaluation,” Nature Reviews—Drug Discovery 4, no. 3
(2005): 179.
Moore, Prescription for Disaster; T. Moore, B.M. Psaty, and C.D. Furberg, “Time to Act on Drug Safety,” Journal
of the American Medical Association 279, no. 19 (1998): 1571–1573; B.M. Psaty et al., “Potential for Conflict of Interest in the Evaluation of Suspected Adverse Drug Reactions: Use of Cerivastatin and Risk of Rhabdomyolysis,” Journal of the American Medical Association 292, no. 21 (2004): 2622–2631; E.J. Topol, “Failing the
Public Health—Rofecoxib, Merck, and the FDA,” New England Journal of Medicine 351, no. 17 (2004): 1707–
1709; and Fontanarosa et al., “Postmarketing Surveillance,” 2647. For data on Phase IV completion, see Federal Register 70, no. 33 (2005): 8030. See Comments of Consumers Union before the FDA Science Board, 15
April 2005, www.fda.gov/ohrms/dockets/ac/05/slides/2005-4136OPH_02_01_Consumer’s%20Union.pdf
(8 September 2005).
I thank an anonymous reviewer for this suggestion and the language in which it was expressed.
On support for increased FDA funding, see Gottlieb, “Opening Pandora’s Pillbox”; and R. Woosley, “Ensuring Drug Safety: Where Do We Go from Here?” Testimony before the Senate Health, Education, Labor,
and Pensions Committee, 3 March 2005.
Avorn, Powerful Medicines, 374–375, 378–379.
Ibid., 374–375; and R. Horton, “Lotronex and the FDA: A Fatal Erosion of Integrity,” Lancet 357, no. 9268
(2001): 1544–1545. Whether or not PDUFA has resulted in regulatory capture of the FDA remains an open
question; evidence that seems to point to capture might be consistent with neutral decision making. See
D.P. Carpenter, “Protection without Capture: Product Approval by a Politically Responsive, Learning
Regulator,” American Political Science Review 98, no. 4 (2004): 613–631; and D.P. Carpenter et al., “Approval
Times for New Drugs: Does the Source of Funding for FDA Staff Matter?” Health Affairs, 17 December 2003,
content.healthaffairs.org/cgi/content/abstract/hlthaff.w3.618 (19 September 2005).
See Moore et al., “Time to Act on Drug Safety”; and Wood et al., ”Making Medicines Safer.”
S. Wolfe, B. Peck, and F. Clemente, “Public Citizen and Congress Watch Comments on the Prescription
Drug User Fee Act (PDUFA),” Docket no. 01N-0450, 25 January 2002, www.citizen.org/publications/
release.cfm?ID=7145 (19 September 2005); and Avorn, Powerful Medicines, 374–375.
U.S. Food and Drug Administration, Prescription Drug User Fee Act III, Five Year Plan, July 2003, www
.fda.gov/oc/pdufa3/2003plan/default.htm (19 September 2005).
Avorn, Powerful Medicines, 383; M.K. Olson, “Managing Delegation in the FDA: Reducing Delay in NewDrug Review,” Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 29, no. 3 (2004): 397–430; and Carpenter et al., “Approval Times for New Drugs.”
W5-480
18 October 2005