March, 2017 Journal of Resources and Ecology Vol. 8 No.2 J. Resour. Ecol. 2017 8(2) 129-140 DOI: 10.5814/j.issn.1674-764x.2017.02.003 www.jorae.cn Progress in the Research on Benefit-sharing and Ecological Compensation Mechanisms for Transboundary Rivers HAN Ze1,2, SONG Wei1,*, DENG Xiangzheng1,3 1. Key Laboratory of Land Surface Pattern and Simulation, Institute of Geographic Sciences and Natural Resources Research, Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100101, China; 2. School of Information Engineering, China University of Geosciences, Beijing 100083, China; 3. Center for Chinese Agricultural Policy, Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100101, China Abstract: Transboundary rivers have important geopolitical and geo-economic connotations, but riparian states of transboundary rivers are often driven by their own rapid population growth and economic development to become involved in regional conflicts about the development and use of water resources. Therefore, finding a balance between the need for fair and reasonable development of water resources and the effective protection of environment from an ecological perspective has become a major problem faced by the international community. This paper begins with consideration of international water laws related to transboundary rivers and then reviews advances in the research on benefit-sharing, ecological compensation mechanisms, and adaptive management systems. We believe that existing international water laws form a complete legal system and that more attention needs to be paid to transboundary cooperation and sustainable water resource use. With respect to how transboundary water conflicts are resolved, there is a trend to move away from single water resource allocation (a zero-sum game) to benefit-sharing in order to achieve a win-win situation for riparian states, but there are still some difficulties in transboundary ecological compensation. In China, the central government has paid attention to horizontal ecological compensation between upstream and downstream, offering guidance to promote establishment of inter-province ecological compensation. Based on existing practice, horizontal ecological compensations are still in their infancy, small in scale, supported by a weak legal system, lacking market mechanisms to encourage their use and relying on fiscal transfers as the method of payment. In the future, China will need to intensify its research on legal system development, international cooperation, and benefit-sharing as these impact transboundary water resources. Because government can be seen as a management department with multiple identities (enabler, regulator and buyer), to improve adaptive transboundary ecological compensation mechanisms, government must develop as soon as possible data sharing platforms, standards of water consumption behaviors and intergovernmental policies (or ordinances). Key words: transboundary rivers; water resources; ecological compensation; benefit sharing 1 Introduction Water is the source of all life and the core of the sustainable development of resources. Explosive population growth, rapid economic development, and urbanization (Song and Deng, 2015; Song et al., 2015a; Song et al., 2015b; Tan et al., 2008) have led to a number of environmental problems such as water pollution, water shortages, and groundwater recession. These problems not only threaten the sustainable development of water resources (Deng et al., 2016; Deng and Zhao, 2015; Du and Lu, 2012; Fang et al., 2016; Wang Received: 2016-11-02 Accepted: 2107-01-22 Foundation: The Projects of National Natural Science Foundation of China (71561137002, 41671177 and 41501192), National Key Basic Research and Development Plan of China (2015CB452702) and National Key Research and Development Plan of China (2016YFA0602402). *Corresponding author: SONG Wei, E-mail: [email protected] Citation: HAN Ze, SONG Wei, DENG Xiangzheng. 2017. Progress in the Research on Benefit-sharing and Ecological Compensation Mechanisms for Transboundary Rivers. Journal of Resources and Ecology. 8(2): 129–140. 130 et al., 2016; Yang et al., 2014; Liu et al., 2012), but also the survival of mankind (Kong, 2014; Wu et al., 2016). According to estimates in the United Nations World Water Resources Development Report (2015), the number of people living in regions and countries with extreme water scarcity will reach 1.8 billion by 2025, and in some arid and semi-arid regions, water shortages will compel 24 to 700 million people to leave their homes. It is therefore obvious that water shortages have become a global challenge and require the development of effective countermeasures. Transboundary rivers flow through or form the boundaries between two or more countries. From a legal point of view, riparian countries through which an international river flows do not have the authority to manage the river throughout its length (Kliot et al., 2001). Hence, people are often concerned about whether the water resources can be shared fairly (Sneddon and Fox, 2006) to avoid conflicts. However, special geopolitical and economic connotations of transboundary rivers imply challenges in terms of management (Sun and He, 2011). First, transboundary rivers have many stakeholders with different management scopes, and subject to different policy regimes, development levels and economic standards. Second, to ensure that management mechanisms are practical, the management of transboundary rivers should also consider resource sovereignty, international relations, border management, and development and stability of transboundary ethnic communities. In addition, transboundary rivers usually provide a wide range of ecological services and functions, such as the supply of irrigation and drinking water, fishing areas and shipping channels, hydroelectric power generation potential, landscape aesthetic, and opportunities to develop tourism (Jagerskog et al., 2007; Jo et al., 1997). However, it is usually difficult to consider the variety of ecological services and functions when setting management goals. Many international rivers on the Asian continent have their sources in China; the country shares about 40 transboundary rivers with 14 adjacent countries. The development, use, and protection of transboundary water resources accounts for the welfare of more than 3 billion people, as well as creating opportunities for both economic development and problems for the environment and health (Arjoon et al., 2016; He et al., 2014). In recent years, China, as an upstream country, has been using water resources in cooperation with downstream countries, such as Vietnam, Laos and Burma etc. (Chen et al., 2013; Lee, 2015; Wouters, 2014; Wouters and Chen, 2013) and has signed a number of water use agreements for many international rivers (Li, 2014). These agreements include the Cooperation Agreement on the Use and Protection of Transboundary Rivers and the Water Quality Protection Agreement on Transboundary Rivers signed by China and Kazakhstan, the Agreement on the Protection and Utilization of Transboundary Waters signed by China and Mongolia, and the Journal of Resources and Ecology Vol. 8 No. 2, 2017 Agreement on the Rational Utilization and Protection of Transboundary Waters signed by China and Russia. However, the development level and political and economic strengths of different countries are not balanced, thus making transboundary management more complex than that within the same administrative system and jurisdiction. Besides, there is still considerable competition for the use of resources and this aggravates conflicts between neighboring countries. Therefore, using the “natural link”, that is, the rivers themselves, to solve the “unfair” profit and loss of transboundary ecology is a necessary way to realize interregional ecological security and alleviate water resource conflicts. Ecosystem services will be at the core of benefit-sharing in the future for the riparian countries of transboundary rivers. On the one hand, ecosystem services are the foundation of cooperation and benefit-sharing between riparian countries (Jagerskog et al., 2007). In order to meet the growing demand for water, the United Nations Water Channel (UNWC) conference clearly pointed out that riparian states of transboundary rivers shall have the obligation of ecological protection in the process of developing and using water resources (McIntyre, 2015). On the other hand, the environmental benefits resulting from cooperation and benefit-sharing may promote regional sustainable development. Therefore, solving the imbalance between the fair and reasonable development of water resources and the effective protection of ecological environment have become major problems facing the international community. Currently, China has accumulated a certain amount of ecological compensation cases concerning the protection of river ecosystems. However, in terms of study areas, these cases are mainly focused on longitudinal ecological compensation and lack relevant research on benefit-sharing of horizontal transboundary rivers and adaptive ecological compensation mechanisms. In this paper, after taking into consideration international water laws related to transboundary rivers, we review the advances in benefit-sharing, ecological compensation mechanisms, and adaptive management systems for transboundary rivers, with the aim to provide a reference for ecological compensation mechanisms for transboundary rivers. 2 Related international laws for transboundary rivers As an awareness of the relationship between humans and the environment has increased, the development and use of rivers have gone through three successive stages. These are the primary use of living/non-living resources, the development of water resources, and development with restrictions imposed to protect the environment. International laws, rules, regulations, and institutions can help to coordinate the relationships of various countries with respect to the development, use, and protection of international water bodies HAN Ze, et al.: Progress in the Research on Benefit-sharing and Ecological Compensation Mechanisms for Transboundary Rivers (Gao, 2008). A study of the historical record shows that, since the 19th century, 286 international conventions on transboundary water resources use have been established and most of these are concentrated in Europe and North America (Kliot et al., 2001). Among these, the Helsinki Rules, drafted by the International Law Association in 1996 (ILA, 1966), and the Convention on the Law of the NonNavigational Uses of International Watercourses, approved by the United Nations in 1997 (McCaffrey, 1998), are two important examples (Kliot, 2001). From the early 19th century to the middle of the 20th century, international water laws were based mainly on the freedom of navigation principle and the harmless use law (Gao, 2008). For example, in 1815, the Final Act of the Congress of Vienna specified a freedom of navigation regime for the Rhine River from the navigable starting point to the estuary. Since then, the Freedom of Navigation Principles in 1887, the International Convention and Statute Concerning the Regime of Navigable Waterways of International Concern in 1921, the Regulation Governing Navigation on International Rivers in 1934, and the Convention Regarding the Regime of Navigation on the Danube in 1948 all have clauses concerning the freedom of navigation. In terms of environmental protection, rapid industrialization after the Second World War has resulted in a set of problems such as water pollution and inter-basin water diversion (Gao, 2008). As a consequence, some conventions have begun to pay close attention to problems related to water resource use of international rivers as well as ecological profit and loss, with additional clauses about harmless use. In 1966, the International Law Association issued the Helsinki Rules, which set the first comprehensive international standard to regulate the use of transboundary rivers and their underground aquifers (Cooley et al., 2009; Salman, 2007). The Helsinki Rules not only include relevant clauses about freedom of navigation and harmless use, but also add some new clauses concerning fair and reasonable use and general cooperation obligations. These rules have helped to set global guidelines and have been very influential; however, since they are not legally binding, there are no specific enforcement mechanisms. The appearance of the Helsinki Rules set the stage for other agreements to follow, including the Treaty of the River Plate Basin (1969), the Great Lakes Water Quality Agreement (1972), and the Amazon Cooperation Treaty (1978). Since the 1990s, rapid population growth and urbanization have led to environmental problems such as water shortages and water pollution, arousing the concern of the international community. During this period, rules governing the sustainable use of water resources have been incorporated into the provisions of a number of international agreements concerning water, including the Convention on the Protection and Use of Transboundary Watercourses and International Lakes (1992), Convention on Cooperation for 131 the Protection and Sustainable Use of the Danube River (1995), and Agreement on the Cooperation for the Sustainable Development of the Mekong River Basin (1995). In 1997, the United Nations General Assembly adopted the Convention on the Law of the Non-Navigational Uses of International Watercourses (hereinafter the Watercourses Convention). This sets out comprehensive principles, mechanisms, and management systems for the non-navigational use of international waterways and is considered a multilateral framework for regulating the use of transboundary freshwater resources. However, the convention has some shortcomings. For example, there are internal conflicts between the clauses concerning “reasonable and fair use of water resources “and” the obligations of not causing obvious damage to others” (Cooley et al., 2009). In 2004 the Berlin Rules on Water Resources further developed rules for the utilization of transboundary rivers with respect to individual water use rights, environment flows, and impact assessments. The Berlin Rules are based on the Helsinki Rules and the Watercourses Convention. After being promoted by the international community for 17 years, in 2014 the Watercourses Convention entered into force and attained binding treaty status (Li, 2014). The development of international water law over a number of years has resulted in the gradual establishment of a basic framework for the distribution of transboundary river water resources. Included in this framework are items concerning freedom of navigation, fair and reasonable use, obligations to avoid significant harm, obligations for general cooperation, obligations to exchange information and data, and obligations to maintain and protect water resources and the ecological system (Feng et al., 2006; Kliot et al., 2001). Kliot et al. (2001) summarized the theoretical principles of international laws for the allocation of water resources from the perspective of the transboundary water resources utilization theories, of which there are four types: Haman’s absolute territorial sovereignty theory, absolute territorial integrity theory, limited territorial sovereignty theory, and coastal state community theory. With respect to the allocation of transboundary water resources, upstream and downstream countries often have different ideas and adhere to different principles. Upstream countries generally advocate the absolute territorial sovereignty theory. They consider that they have absolute rights to dominate the river crossing their territory and that other countries have no right to interfere. By contrast, the downstream countries advocate the absolute territorial integrity theory. They consider that water resources are an integral part of their territory and that any form of damage to those resources is an infringement of their sovereignty (Gao, 2009; Kliot et al., 2001). At the end of the 18th century, the emergence of the limited territorial sovereignty theory reconciled these two completely opposite theories. It emphasized that riparian states have equal rights 132 Journal of Resources and Ecology Vol. 8 No. 2, 2017 Table 1 Basic principles of some important water laws Year Laws and Regulations Navigation freedom No significant harm 1815 Final Act of the Congress of Vienna ✔ 1887 Freedom of Navigation Principles ✔ 1911 International Regulations regarding the Use of International Watercourses for Purposes other than Navigation 1921 International Convention and Statute Concerning the Regime of Navigable Waterways of International Concern 1923 The Convention relating to the Development of Hydraulic Power Affecting More than One State ✔ 1933 Declaration on the Industrial and Agricultural Use of International Rivers ✔ 1934 Regulation governing Navigation on International Rivers ✔ 1948 Convention regarding the regime of navigation on the Danube ✔ 1961 Resolution on the Use of International Non-Maritime Water 1963 Act regarding the navigation and economic co-operation between the States of the River Niger basin ✔ ✔ 1966 The Helsinki Rules on the Uses of the Waters of International Rivers ✔ ✔ 1969 Treaty of the River Plate Basin 1972 The Great Lakes Water Quality Agreement 1992 The Convention on the Protection and Use of Transboundary Watercourses and International Lakes 1994 Equitable and reasonable utilization ✔ General obligation to cooperation Sustainable development ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ Convention on Cooperation for the Protection and Sustainable Use of the Danube River ✔ ✔ 1995 Agreement on the Cooperation for the Sustainable Development of the Mekong River Basin ✔ ✔ 1997 Convention on the Law of the Nonnavigational Uses of International Watercourses ✔ ✔ ✔ 1998 Convention on the Protection of the Rhine ✔ 2004 The Berlin Rules on Water Resources ✔ with respect to the utilization of water resources and proposed that one riparian country should avoid significant damage to relevant rights of other countries when it used and developed transboundary rivers in order to realize a positivesum result instead of engaging in a zero-sum game. In the early 20th century, the riparian state community theory appeared, arguing that riparian states should form economic communities and cooperate to exploit and use of transboundary water resources (Bai, 2013). The basic principles of international water laws and the evolution ideas concerning water resources sovereignty illustrate that sustainable development and international cooperation are important trends. ✔ 3 ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ Benefit-sharing of transboundary rivers and international cooperation Water rights are an important part of national sovereignty and are often at the heart of conflicts and disputes. The allocation of water rights between riparian countries has always raised complex and difficult questions and thinking about these questions has moved from early absolute sovereignty principles (including the absolute territorial sovereignty theory and the absolute territorial integrity theory) to the limited territorial sovereignty theory and to the riparian state community theory (Yang and Shen, 2009). The tradi- HAN Ze, et al.: Progress in the Research on Benefit-sharing and Ecological Compensation Mechanisms for Transboundary Rivers tional allocation of water resources ensures that water rights of transboundary rivers are assigned based on hydrology, climate and ecological characteristics, actual water demand, and social development factors such as basin population and economic level. However, cases of existing practices indicate that this allocation mode has certain limitations (Palesa and Mokorosi, 2007). A simple or single division of water resources may result in a zero-sum result. In contrast, benefit-sharing deals for the utilization of water resources that take into consideration economic, policy and environmental concerns, and are focused on the efficient use of water resources by the riparian states of transboundary rivers can bypass the complex problems produced by water rights disputes and achieve positive-sum results (Arjoon et al., 2016; He et al., 2014; Lee, 2015; Qaddumi, 2008; Skinner et al., 2009; Suhardiman et al., 2014). Sadoff and Grey (2002) defined benefit-sharing as a kind of bilateral cooperation behavior to alter the allocation of costs and benefits. From the perspective of environmental economy externalities, the utilization of water resources in the river basin (such as hydroelectric developments, water source protection, etc.) is bound to produce positive or negative externalities. If this external economy has not been internalized in the basin, it will reduce the benefits and output of the whole basin (Qaddumi, 2008). Therefore, benefit-sharing is not only an effective way of relieving the conflicts over the use of transboundary water resources (Bhaduri and Liebe, 2013; Lee, 2015; McIntyre, 2015; Qaddumi, 2008; Skinner et al., 2009; Suhardiman et al., 2014), it is also a basic principle of water resources cooperation (Sadoff and Grey, 2005). The main goals of building a benefit-sharing mechanism are to endow the regions with monetary or non-monetary means to provide welfare to various groups and thus reduce poverty through sustainable development (Institute and Euroconsult, 2000), and also to strengthen the relationship between the social economy and the ecological environment. Many scholars have analyzed the possible benefits of water resources cooperation, including environmental benefits, economic benefits, benefits to regional integration, increased trade, reductions in military spending, and so on (Klaphake, 2005; Sadoff and Grey, 2005; Suhardiman et al., 2014; Teasley and McKinney, 2011; Tilmant and Kinzelbach, 2012). Sadoff and Grey (2002) classified the possible benefits into three types: safety benefits, environmental benefits, and economic benefits. For example, the cooperation and benefit-sharing between riparian countries of transboundary rivers can directly affect the hydrological characteristics of a river, including reducing the risk of flooding, increasing surface runoff, etc., and thus promotes the construction of hydroelectric projects. All of these changes significantly affect the development of regional economies (Qaddumi, 2008). Using static game and numerical analysis methodologies, Bhaduri and Liebe (2013) 133 analyzed the case of water resources sharing in the Walter River basin, located between Burkina Faso and Ghana in Africa, and determined that Burkina Faso could limit water consumption of upstream hydropower stations by using discounted hydropower as compensation, thereby increasing water resources for agricultural use in Ghana. In terms of efficiency analysis, current studies focus maInly on economic benefits by using the hydrologic-economic model (Arjoon et al., 2014; Arjoon et al., 2016; Jeuland et al., 2014; Teasley and McKinney, 2011; Tilmant and Kinzelbach, 2012). For example, in order to understand how net benefits from the eastern Nile valley are maximized, Arjoon et al. (2016) evaluated the hydrological and economic risks faced by agricultural and hydropower sectors of Sudan and Egypt, using the stochastic dual dynamic programming (SDDP) model. Similarly, Jeuland et al. (2014) assessed the economic benefits brought by infrastructure development and operations, using hydro-economic optimization models. Benefit-sharing mechanisms can take many forms, including monetary and non-monetary forms, and can consist of revenue sharing, development funds, interest sharing, tax preferences, and so on (Fan, 2010). Refining the understanding of “fairness” and precisely defining “benefit allocation” for riparian states are major challenges for establishing benefit-sharing mechanisms in the future (Klaphake, 2005). Benefit-sharing mechanisms for transboundary rivers should also consider factors such as policy, economics, and systems; for example, regulations from international conventions, maintenance of human wellbeing in upstream and downstream countries, protection of land productivity, migration of ecological products in land and aquatic ecosystems, and the recoverability of ecological systems from natural or manmade disturbances (Palesa and Mokorosi, 2007). 4 Ecological compensation mechanism for transboundary rivers Ecological environmental services are the core of benefitsharing for the riparian states of transboundary rivers. Ecological compensation, which is considered in international water agreements such as the Helsinki Rules and the Convention on the Law of the Non-Navigational Uses of International Watercourses is an important method of alleviating water resources conflicts and protecting transboundary river ecosystems. The rules contained in these conventions provide guidelines for the riparian states of transboundary rivers to establish ecological compensation mechanisms. As an institutional arrangement, ecological compensation is mainly a transparent system that offers conditional payments to resource providers for their environmental gain services and focuses on achieving the goal of ecological environmental protection by incentives (Yuan and Zhou, 2014). Therefore, the use of ecological compensation to stimulate ecological 134 Journal of Resources and Ecology Vol. 8 No. 2, 2017 Fig.1 Basic framework of ecological compensation environmental protection behaviors for the use of transboundary river resources can well make up for the unfairness between the rights and obligations of the riparian states (Huang and Zheng, 2012). In general, the establishment of ecological compensation mechanisms consists of stakeholder analysis, formulation of ecological compensation standards, and confirmation of ecological compensation modes. 4.1 Stakeholder identification and interest analysis The term “stakeholder” first appeared in the book Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach, first published by Freeman in 1984 (Freeman, 2010). He considers stakeholders to be any group or individuals that can affect or be affected by the realization of organizational goals. With respect to transboundary ecological compensation, internalizing the externalities of the ecosystem environment and further realizing the coordinated development of the ecological environment and the social economy are the core goals of compensation mechanism construction. In the process of compensation mechanism construction, riparian governments, environmental saboteurs and polluters, downstream beneficiaries and victims, and other direct or indirect stakeholders will all affect the realization of the goal. Meissner (2005) stated that the role of different interest groups in the formulation of transboundary water policy should not be ignored. Therefore, it is necessary to identify and define the interested subjects at different levels in ecological compensation and differentiate their respective interest relationships (Hua et al., 2016; Huffman, 2009). Previous studies have shown that unreasonable definitions of stakeholder subjects can cause a variety of problems, such as unitary ecological compensation subjects and incomplete compensation objects, and thus encourage “free rider” behavior and “government failure” phenomena, finally leading to an imbalanced allocation of rights and obligations that is not conducive to the realization of environmental justice (Sun and He, 2011). Stakeholders that participate in an ecological compensation process are rational entities that can rationally make choices regarding their behaviors by judging their own interest goals and welfare situations in order to maximize their interests (Wang et al., 2015). From the perspective of the relationship between ecological environmental protection behavior and characteristics of its effect on the environment, ecological compensation includes not only those who protect and those who benefit from the ecological environment, but also environmental saboteurs and victims (Ma and Chen, 2014) (Figure 2). For transboundary rivers, consideration of the entire basin should be used to identify stakeholders. Meissner (2005) used an assessment of organizational forms to divide the stakeholders in transboundary river basins into several categories: disorganized individuals, ethnic groups, consumer groups, social organizations, and government departments. The China Council for International Co-operation on Environment and Development (Jia and Gao, 2015) considers that the objects of ecological compensation should be the regions that contribute to the sustainable use of water resources, e.g. by implementing ecological protections for water resources. These are usually the upstream regions of the basin. Wang et al. (2007a) argued that the subjects of ecological compensation should be downstream water-consuming residents, all enterprises and institutions, tourists, and all districts in the basin, while the objects should be migrant farmers and the shut-down enterprises that have sacrificed their interests to protect and restore the ecological environment. Currently, the methods used to identify stakeholders are not fixed for transboundary river watersheds. Zhang et.al (2010) think that there are three kinds of river basin ecological compensation stakeholders: (1) owners of river basin resources, (2) developers and users of river basin resources, and (3) managers of river basin resources. Zhang and Michael (2011) supposed that clearly delineated administrative rights and responsibilities should be anticipated, and the identification of stakeholders needs to be done outside the eco-compensation regulatory framework. There are some cases in which regions have chosen the flux of pollutants as a tool to identify the stakeholders (Jiang and Ke, 2016). 4.2 Ecological compensation standard The beneficiaries of ecological compensation in transbou- Fig.2 Relationship between ecological compensation stakeholders and environmental protection behaviors HAN Ze, et al.: Progress in the Research on Benefit-sharing and Ecological Compensation Mechanisms for Transboundary Rivers ndary river cases generally have demands of one of two types: first, for good water quality and quantity and second, for water-related ecosystem services. Moreover, transboundary ecological compensation patterns can be divided into pollution-based compensation and protection-based compensation (Yu, 2011). On the whole, the methods for determining transboundary river ecological compensation standards are as follows: (1) An accounting method based on the flux of pollutants. This method has been used in some ecological compensation pilot projects for trans-provincial watersheds (Chen, 2012; Yu, 2011), such as Taihu Lake basin of Jiangsu Province, Ziya River of Hebei Province, Liaohe River basin of Liaoning Province, and the Shayinghe River basin of Henan Province. To calculate the amount of compensation by this method, a data acquisition platform that has real-time monitoring and can simulate the flow and concentration of major pollutants of the transboundary section or the transboundary drainage basin is necessary. The main idea of this method is to combine the monitoring data with the cost of controlling water pollution in order to fulfill a clear water environmental responsibility. (2) An accounting method based on the value of ecological system services and the cost of ecological protection. At present, there are two ideas concerning the assessment of value: one is to assess the value of ecosystem service functions and the other is to assess the loss of ecological and environmental value. The former determines an ecological compensation standard based on the original or corrected values of ecosystem service functions. By contrast, the latter includes such methods as the opportunity cost method, the willingness-to-pay method, the contingent valuation method, and Pareto optimality; and thus is more practicable than the former. In theory, the standard of ecological compensation should between in the value of the ecological service function and opportunity cost for ecological conservation. However, the result obtained by the algorithm is close to the opportunity cost, thus leading to inadequate compensation. Van Hecken et al. (2012) evaluated the willingness-to-pay (WTP) of downstream users when land owners of the upstream watershed improved water quality. As demonstrated by the comparison results, the WTP method is significantly affected by regional differences in the calculation process, which can lead to large differences in the compensation results arrived at by upstream and downstream entities. In contrast, the contingent valuation method integrates factors such as the ability of stakeholders to pay and the cost together on the basis of the WTP method and therefore obtains more reliable compensation standards, which usually appears as the lower limit of the compensation standard. Compared with formulating standards for ordinary rivers, the formulation of ecological compensation standards for transboundary rivers (or trans-provincial boundary rivers) involves more influencing factors, especially political crite- 135 ria, that complicate the formulation of ecological compensation standards. In practice, ecological compensation is calculated through negotiations and game playing based on estimates from the valuation methods noted above (Bennett et al., 2010). 4.3 Ecological compensation mode Ecological compensation forms are becoming more and more diversified. They include fund compensation, material compensation, policy compensation, and intellectual compensation (Bennett et al., 2010). There are many different classifications based on their defining characteristics (Xie et al., 2012). According to the implementing body or operating mechanism used, ecological compensation is generally categorized as either government compensation or as market-based compensation (Table 2). Government compensation can be broken down into vertical and horizontal forms of compensation. The typical market-based compensation mechanism includes the trading of water rights, and development in different places that can encourage the individuals to develop economy in other suitable places by means of compensation (Jiang and Ke, 2016; Bennett et al., 2010). Concerning ecological compensation in transboundary river cases, the choice of the form of ecological compensation is not only the result of the negotiations and gameplaying between the governments on the upper and lower reaches of the river, the characteristics of the different compensation forms also need to be considered. Financial transfers use administrative actions by government to force beneficiaries to pay compensation (Zhang, 2012). Vertical transfer payments are often used for small and independent watersheds that belong to the higher administrative level (Wang, 2013). Currently, many trans-provincial boundary rivers in China, such as the Dongjiang River basin of Jiangxi Province, have chosen national fiscal transfers as their main source of compensation. In contrast, horizontal ecocompensation is more suitable for governments that are at the same administrative level. The ecological compensation scheme for the Elbe River watershed in Germany is a good example. In addition, in the case of some special ecological protection watersheds, multi-party financing led by government and special compensation funds are also an important funding source and play an important role in some cases; the Quito Water Fund (FONAG) in Ecuador is an example of this. In most ecological compensation cases, the implementing bodies are usually a mixture of both government and market-based entities. Therefore, market-based transactions are essential. For instance, ecological compensation in New York’s Catskill/Delaware watershed chose public payment led by government as the funding source. There are three parts to this funding: additional taxes imposed on water users by the government, New York municipal bonds, and trust fund (Gao and Yang, 2006). In recent years, China has 136 Journal of Resources and Ecology Vol. 8 No. 2, 2017 Table 2 The main forms of eco-compensation for cross-boundary rivers (or watersheds) Operating mechanism used Government modes The characterizes of applicable objects Cases Horizontal eco-compensation Governments at the same level Germany: the Elbe river ecological compensation policy Guangdong and Jiangxi Province: ecological compensation in Dongjiang river basin Vertical eco-compensation Government(s) in a superiorsubordinate relationship Jiangxi Province: ecological compensation in Dongjiang river basin (Fiscal transfer payment) Special funds Special ecological protection in River Basin Ecuador: The Quito Water Fund (FONAG); Fujian: ecological compensation in Minjiang, nine Longjiang and Jinjiang basin Ecological tax/Sewage charges Market Germany and Australia: using ecological taxes, environmental taxes and other measures to control the excessive utilization of natural resources; Germany: the Elbe river ecological compensation policy; U.S.: New York's Catskill/Delaware watershed; Trading water rights development in different places Zhejiang: Dongyang, Yiwu cities water right transfer; The economic level of the indemnified party is relatively low developed some innovate measures, such as water rights trading and development in different places to implement pilot projects for transboundary ecological compensation. For example, water-rich Dongyang City permanently transferred its use of Hengjin reservoir to the water-poor Yiwu City (Shen, 2005). 4.4 Adaptive management countermeasures Adaptive management is a powerful tool to manage dynamic systems characterized by uncertainty (Stankey et al., 2005). The tool achieves an optimal management effect by utilizing scientific identification management to reduce the uncertainty caused by factors such as natural change, random behavior of systems, lack of data, and impacts of human society changes on natural resources (Gunderson, 1999; Walters, 1986). Operating in the context of dynamic and complex social–ecological systems, adaptive decisionmaking for sustainable resource management needs to be carried out in a PES program (Salafsky et al. 2002). The adaptive management of ecological compensation draws on knowledge and experience from past failures and successes and then applies these to a management process aimed at developing a tight feedback loop between ecosystem change and decision makers (Allen et al. 2011, Westgate et al. 2013). Folke et al. (1998) think that successful adaptive approaches for ecosystem management in conditions of uncertainty need to (1) build knowledge and understanding of resource and ecosystem dynamics, (2) develop practices that interpret and respond to ecological feedback, and (3) support flexible institutions and organizations and adaptive management processes. On the whole, in terms of policy choices generated by an adaptive management process, the standards for and modes of ecological compensation are dynamic, requiring a continuous loop for program design, implementation, monitoring, evaluation, and redesign in response to real-world Zhejiang: Ecological compensation in Jinhua River Basin; events and stakeholder feedback (Sims et al., 2014). Phughes et al. (2007) developed an adaptive system for the management of ecological conditions in the Great Barrier Reef and in Colorado. Their efforts involved multi-level government-public cooperation that made important contributions to solving environmental problems and restoring regional ecological stability. Targeting a series of downstream ecological problems caused by the establishment of the Colorado Canyon Dam, the United States conducted adaptive management research on ecological restoration and made great progress in terms of improving water quality, wetland restoration, and reasonable water resource use (Williams, 2011). Considering the high complexity and unpredictability of ecological systems and the limitations of human cognition, Ge (2013) proposed an adaptive management mode for ecological protection of the downstream dam based on the ecology-hydrology response mechanism and carried out an onsite analysis at the Xiaolangdi Reservoir, finally developing an adaptive management theory and a system for ecological protection of the downstream dam suitable for the situation in China. Wang et al. (2007b) proposed the basic concepts for adaptive regional ecological system management, built the theoretical framework, and put forward the specific adaptive management methods and modes. When designing an adaptive management system for ecological compensation, there are several key questions that need to be answered. These include what the aims of the adaptive management are, what has been achieved, what has been learnt, how has the learning taken place and what modes of learning have been used (Fabricius and Cundill, 2014). Furthermore, several key positive factors can facilitate the implementation of adaptive management (Sims et al., 2014), such as the policy environment, the availability of high quality data, adequate technical capacity, and stakeholder participation in the design and implementation proc- HAN Ze, et al.: Progress in the Research on Benefit-sharing and Ecological Compensation Mechanisms for Transboundary Rivers ess. A number of factors can present obstacles to adaptive management, including situations in which there is high organizational resistance, system boundaries are unclear, and the stakeholders are many (Allen et al., 2010; Fabricius and Cundill, 2014). 5 Prospect In order to alleviate conflicts over the use of water resources of transboundary rivers, considerable research has been conducted all over the world. Legislation, international cooperation, and benefit-sharing have been explored as means to address conflicts. As water resource agreements and customary law have developed over time, clauses concerning theories of sustainable development and benefit compensation principles have been incorporated into these agreements and laws. At the same time, there has been an increased focus on international cooperation. In the case of China, the concept of legislation concerning the use of transboundary water resources is relatively weak, and there have few instances of international cooperation. In the future, China will need to pay more attention to international cooperation and formulate or sign bilateral or multilateral treaties/agreements based on principles including those of fair and reasonable use, the obligation to avoid significant harm, the obligation for general cooperation, the obligation to exchange information and data, the obligation to maintain and protect water resources and ecological systems, and benefit compensation. These treaties or agreements can, on the one hand, standardize the development and utilization of water resources and, on the other hand, provide a basis for regional ecological compensation and benefit-sharing. To reduce tension that can develop between water resources usage and socio-economic development, and to promote the coordinated development of the upper and lower reaches of rivers, the use horizontal ecological compensation is imperative. Since 2012, the Chinese government has introduced a series of policy initiatives. It has proposed establishing horizontal ecological compensation between upstream and downstream. Owing to the national policy, some inter-provincial ecological compensation practices and pilot projects have been undertaken, such as project for the Xin’An River basin, the Dingjiang-Hanjiang River basin, and the Jiuzhou River basin. It is obvious that the Chinese government is paying considerable attention to horizontal ecological compensation between upstream and downstream and is offering guidance to promote the establishment of inter-province ecological compensation. However, transboundary ecological compensation involves political, institutional, policy and economic issues, and it employs different compensation types, targets, contents, and methods. Currently, for a number of reasons China’s use of transboundary ecological compensation is still in its infancy. First, although quantitative research methods have been widely applied to formulate compensation standards for ecological com- 137 pensation, comprehensive systems and compensation standards for transboundary problems are still lacking. This is the case because the environmental background of transboundary resources is often not known nor are the environmental conditions of the whole river basin, especially the outside part of his own country, known. Second, government compensation mechanisms are the most important form of ecological compensation for trans-provincial watersheds in China, but in other countries, the role of public payments is more important. Last, transboundary ecological compensation needs a strategic, comprehensive, and longterm framework. Decision makers need an adaptive management scheme in place to ensure there is constant feedback from dynamic and complex social–ecological systems. At present, the theoretical development of adaptive management concepts is well ahead of the application of adaptive management practices to ecological compensation schemes. As Scherr and Bennett (2011) tell us, the government plays multiple roles in ecological compensation. The government should play an important role in schemes for watershed ecological conservation for the future, especially schemes for transboundary rivers. First, as an enabler, the government not only needs to consider the balance between local economic development and ecological conservation, but also the fairness of economic and ecological welfare distribution between countries and regions on the upper and lower reaches of the river. Sharing data that has consistent quality and spatial-temporal matching is fundamental. Therefore, the government must expeditiously establish an inter-jurisdictional water environment dynamics monitoring system that can help to effectively calculate compensation amounts and evaluate the effects of ecological compensation. Moreover, to meet and encourage market development, intergovernmental policies and ordinances concerning ecological compensation need to be formulated. Second, as a buyer, government compensation mechanisms are the principal means of payments at the present time; however, relying on this financial channel alone puts added pressure on the government. Based on the results of intergovernmental negotiations and game-playing, multichannel financial mechanisms such as special watershed funds should also be set up. Finally, as a regulator, government needs to establish inter-regional standards of water consumption behavior. By comparing water consumption behaviors with the inter-regional standards, the government can not only supervise the protective and damaging behaviors of individuals but also identify stakeholders effectively. This will help to effectivity implement a transboundary ecological compensation. References Allen C R, Fontaine J J, Pope K L, et al. 2010. Adaptive Management for a Turbulent Future. Journal of Environmental Management, 92(5): 1339– 1345. 138 Arjoon D, Mohamed Y, Goor Q, et al. 2014. Hydro-Economic Risk Assessment in the Eastern Nile River Basin. Water Resources and Economics, 8: 16–31. Arjoon D, Tilmant A, Herrmann M. 2016. Sharing Water and Benefits in Transboundary River Basins. Hydrology and Earth System Sciences, 20(6): 2135–2150. Bai M H. 2013. The Evolution of International Water Laws and International Cooperation Theory. Foreign Affairs Review, 30(5): 102–112. (in Chinese) Zhang Q, Bennett M T, Kannan K, et al. 2010. Payments for Ecological Services and Eco-Compensation: Practices and Innovations in the People’s Republic of China. In: Proceedings from the International Conference on Payments for Ecological Services. Mandaluyong City, Philippines: Asian Development Bank. Bhaduri A, Liebe J. 2013. Cooperation in Transboundary Water Sharing with Issue Linkage: Game-Theoretical Case Study in the Volta Basin. Journal of Water Resources Planning and Management, 139(3): 235– 245. Chen H P, Rieu-Clarke A, Wouters P. 2013. Exploring China's Transboundary Water Treaty Practice through the Prism of the Un Watercourses Convention. Water International, 38(2): 217–230. Cheng B, Tian R, Dong Z. 2012. Patterns and Assessment of the Watershed Eco-Compensation Standard Practices in China. Ecological Economy.(4): 24–29. (in Chinese) Cooley H, Christian-Smith J, Gleick P H, et al. 2009. Understanding and Reducing the Risks of Climate Change for Transboundary Waters. Oakland: Pacific Institute. Deng X Z, Li Z H, Gibson J. 2016. A Review on Trade-Off Analysis of Ecosystem Services for Sustainable Land-Use Management. Journal of Geographical Sciences, 26(7): 953–968. Deng X Z, Zhao C H. 2015. Identification of Water Scarcity and Providing Solutions for Adapting to Climate Changes in the Heihe River Basin of China. Advances in Meteorology, 2015(7): 1–13. Du X, Lu C. 2012. Evaluation and Trend Analysis of Surface Water Quality in Zhengzhou in 1998–2008. Chinese Journal of Population, Resources and Environment, 10(4): 44–51. Fabricius C, Cundill G. 2014. Learning in Adaptive Management: Insights from Published Practice. Ecology & Society, 19(19): 360–375. Fan Q X. 2010. Research on the Benefit Sharing Model of Hydropower Project Development[D]. Beijing, Tsinghua University. (in Chinese) Fang C, Liu H M, Li G. 2016. International Progress and Evaluation on Interactive Coupling Effects between Urbanization and the Eco- Environment. Journal of Geographical Sciences, 26(8): 1081–1116. Feng Y, He D M, Gan S, et al. 2006. Linkages of Transboundary Water Allocation and Its Eco-Thresholds with International Laws. Chinese Science Bulletin, 51(22): 25–32. Freeman R E. 2010. Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach. Cambridge University Press, New York. Folke C, Berkes F, Colding J. 1998. Ecological Practises and Social Mechanisms for Building Resilience and Sustainability. In: Berkes F, Folke C (eds.). Linking social and ecological systems: management practices and social mechanisms for building resilience. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 414–436. Gao X L. 2009. Trends of Development of Modern International Water Law and Its Suggestions to China. Academic Exchange, 4: 56-58. (in Chinese) Gao T, Yang S. 2006. The Significance of International Ecological Compensation Policy to China. Environmental Protection, 19: 71–76. (in Chinese) Ge H F. 2013. Study on the Adaptive Management of the Downstream Reservoir Based on the Eco-Hydrology Responding Mechanism[D]. Journal of Resources and Ecology Vol. 8 No. 2, 2017 Beijing, China Institute of Water Resources and Hydropower Research. (in Chinese) He D, Wu R, Feng Y, et al. 2014. China’s Transboundary Waters: New Paradigms for Water and Ecological Security through Applied Ecology. Journal of Applied Ecology, 51(5): 1159–1168. Hua J, Li Z, Huang D. 2016. An International River Water Resource Development Cooperation System Based on Dissipative Structure Theory. Resources Science, 38(2): 239–247. Huang X S, Zheng R. 2012. Compensation Principle of the Beneficiaries of the Tansboundary Rivers. Resources and Environment in the Yangtze Basin, 21(11): 1402–1408. (in Chinese) Huffman J L. 2009. Comprehensive River Basin Management: The Limits of Collaborative, Stakeholder-Based, Water Governance. Natural Resources Journal, 49(1): 117–149. ILA (International Law Association). 1966. Report of the Fifty-Second Conference, Helsinki, pp. 447 –533 (London: ILA). Jägerskog A, Granit J, Risberg J, et al. 2007. Transboundary Water Management as a Regional Public Good. Financing Development: An Example from the Nile Basin. Report Number 20. Stockholm: Stockholm International Water Institute (SIWI). Jeuland M, Baker J, Bartlett R, et al. 2014. The Costs of Uncoordinated Infrastructure Management in Multi-Reservoir River Basins. Environmental Research Letters, 9(10):105006. Jia R X, Gao G L. 2015. Study on the Establishment of Horizontal Ecological Compensation System between Regions. Macroeconomics, 3: 13–23. (in Chinese) Jiang Y Q, Ke C. 2016. A Review of Researches on Payment for Watershed Ecosystem Services. Ecological Economy, 32(04): 175–180. (in Chinese) Jo S Y, Jae-Won O, Jeong J H, et al. 1997. Transboundary Water Management as an International Public Good. Environmental Engineering Research, 2(3): 26–26. Klaphake A. 2005. Economic and Political Benefits of Transboundary Water Cooperation. In: Value of Water – Different Approaches in Transboundary Water Management. Koblenz: Proceedings of the International Workshop, 91–99. Kliot N, Shmueli D, Shamir U. 2001. Institutions for Management of Transboundary Water Resources: Their Nature, Characteristics and Shortcomings. Water Policy, 3(3): 229–255. Kong X. 2014. China Must Protect High-Quality Arable Land. Nature, 506(7486): 7. Lee S. 2015. Benefit Sharing in the Mekong River Basin. Water International, 40(1): 139–152. Li W F. How to Deal with the Entry into Force of "Convention on the Law of the Non Navigational Uses of International Watercourses" 2014 [cited 2016 October 8]. Available from: http://epaper.legaldaily.com. cn/fzrb/content/20140826/Articel10002GN.htm. (in Chinese) Liu M, Tian H, Lu C, et al. 2012. Effects of Multiple Environment Stresses on Evapotranspiration and Runoff over Eastern China. Journal of Hydrology, 426–427: 39–54. Ma G Y, Chen H. 2014. Study of an Ecological Compensation Mechanism Based on Stakeholders. Ecological Economy, 30(4): 33–36. (in Chinese) McCaffrey, S. 1998. The UN Convention on the Law of the Non- Navigational Uses of International Watercourses: prospects and pitfalls, in: S. Salman & L. Boisson de Chazournes (Eds) International Watercourses—Enhancing Cooperation and Managing Conflict, pp. 17–28, World Bank Technical Paper No. 414. McIntyre O. 2015. Benefit-Sharing and Upstream/Downstream Cooperation for Ecological Protection of Transboundary Waters: Opportunities for China as an Upstream State. Water International, 40(1): 48–70. Meissner R. 2005. Interest Groups as Local Stakeholders Involved in the HAN Ze, et al.: Progress in the Research on Benefit-sharing and Ecological Compensation Mechanisms for Transboundary Rivers Water Politics of a Transboundary River: The Case of the Proposed Epupa Dam in the Kunene River. In Wirkus L (eds.). Water, Development and Conflict – A Comparative Perspective: Euphrates-Tigris and Southern Africa. Bonn: Bonn International Center for Conversion, 101–121. ODI (Overseas Development Institute), Arcadis Euroconsult. 2000. Transboundary Water Management as an International Public Good: Prepared for Ministry for Foreign Affairs, Sweden. Ministry for Foreign Affairs, Sockholm, Sweden. Palesa S, Mokorosi. 2007. Can Benefits Be Shared Equitably among a Variety of Stakeholders in a Transboundary River Basin? Learning from Zambezi and Orange-Senqu River Basins. In: Proceedings of 8th WaterNet/WARFSA/GWP-SA Symposium, Pretoria: Global water partnership. Phughes T, Hgunderson L, Folke C, et al. 2007. Adaptive Management of the Great Barrier Reef and the Grand Canyon World Heritage Areas. Ambio A Journal of the Human Environment, 36(7): 586–592. Qaddumi H. 2008. Practical Approaches to Transboundary Water Benefit Sharing. Overseas Development Institute. Sadoff C W, Grey D. 2002. Beyond the River: The Benefits of Cooperation on International Rivers. Water Science & Technology A Journal of the International Association on Water Pollution Research, 47(6): 91–96. Sadoff C W, Grey D. 2005. Cooperation on International Rivers: A Continuum for Securing and Sharing Benefits. Water International, 30(4): 420–427. Salafsky N, Margoluis R, Redford K H, et al. 2002. Improving the Practice of Conservation: A Conceptual Framework and Research Agenda for Conservation Science. Conservation Biology, 16(6): 1469–1479. Salman S A A. 2007. The Helsinki Rules, the UN Watercourses Convention and the Berlin Rules: Perspectives on International Water Law. International Journal of Water Resources Development, 23(4): 625–640. Scherr S J, Bennett M T. 2011. Buyer, Regulator, and Enabler: The Government's Role in Ecosystem Services Markets: International lessons learned for payments for ecological services in the People’s Republic of China. Mandaluyong City, Philippines: Asian Development Bank. Shen M. 2005. Water Rights Trading and Government Innovation: A Case Study of Water Rights Trading in Dongyang and Yiwu Management World(6): 45–56. (in Chinese) Sims K R, Alixgarcia J M, Shapirogarza E, et al. 2014. Improving Environmental and Social Targeting through Adaptive Management in Mexico’s Payments for Hydrological Services Program. Conservation Biology, 28(5): 1151–1159. Skinner J, Niasse M, Haas L. 2009. Sharing the Benefits of Large Dams in West Africa. Iied Natural Resource Issues. Sneddon C, Fox C. 2006. Rethinking Transboundary Waters: A Critical Hydropolitics of the Mekong Basin. Political Geography, 25(2): 181– 202. Song W, Deng X Z. 2015. Effects of Urbanization-Induced Cultivated Land Loss on Ecosystem Services in the North China Plain. Energies, 8(6): 5678–5693. Song W, Deng X Z, Yuan Y W, et al. 2015a. Impacts of Land-Use Change on Valued Ecosystem Service in Rapidly Urbanized North China Plain. Ecological Modelling, 318: 245–253. Song W, Pijanowski B C, Tayyebi A. 2015b. Urban Expansion and Its Consumption of High-Quality Farmland in Beijing, China. Ecological Indicators, 54: 60–70. Stankey G H, Clark R N, Bormann B T. 2005. Adaptive Management of Natural Resources: Theory, Concepts, and Management Institutions. USDA Forest Service-General Technical Report PNW, 3(654): 286– 290. Suhardiman D, Wichelns D, Lebel L, et al. 2014. Benefit Sharing in Me- 139 kong Region Hydropower: Whose Benefits Count? Water Resources & Rural Development, 4: 3–11. Sun G J, He J. 2011. Research on Eco-Compensation in China. Commercial Times, 28(12): 100–102. (in Chinese) Tan M, Li X, Lu C, et al. 2008. Urban Population Densities and Their Policy Implications in China. Habitat International, 32(4): 471–484. Teasley R L, McKinney D C. 2011. Calculating the Benefits of Transboundary River Basin Cooperation: Syr Darya Basin. J Water Res Pl-Asce, 137(6): 481–490. Tilmant A, Kinzelbach W. 2012. The Cost of Noncooperation in International River Basins. Water Resources Research, 48(1): 283–283. Van Hecken G, Bastiaensen J, Vásquez W F. 2012. The Viability of Local Payments for Watershed Services: Empirical Evidence from Matigu s, Nicaragua. Ecological Economics, 74: 169–176. Wang A M, Ge Y X, Y. G X. 2015. Analysis of Behavior Selection Mechanism of Ecological Compensation Stakeholders in Water Source Protection Areas. Chinese Journal of Agricultural Resources and Regional Planning, 36(5): 16–22. (in Chinese) Wang J, Hou C. 2013. Study on Implementation Framework and Compensation Pattern of Basin Ecological Compensation Mechanism in China: From the Perspective of Compensation Funds Source. China Population, Resources And Environment, 23(2): 23–29. (in Chinese) Wang J, Lin X H, Zhou Y. 2007a. Consideration on the Theory of Circular Economy to Guide the Ecological Compensation of the River Basin. Environmental Protection, 380(18): 47–49. (in Chinese) Wang L, Li Q, Bi H, et al. 2016. Human Impacts and Changes in the Coastal Waters of South China. Science of the Total Environment, 562: 108–114. Wang W J, Pan Y Z, Wang M C, et al. 2007b. Research on the Concept, Theory Framework and Application of Regional Ecosystem Adaptive Management. Environmental Monitoring In China, 23(02): 1–8. (in Chinese) Westgate M J, Likens G E, Lindenmayer D B. 2013. Adaptive Management of Biological Systems: A Review. Biological Conservation, 158: 128–139. Williams B K. 2011. Passive and Active Adaptive Management: Approaches and an Example. Journal of Environmental Management, 92(5): 1371–1378. Wouters P. 2014. The Yin and Yang of International Water Law: China’s Transboundary Water Practice and the Changing Contours of State Sovereignty. Review of European Comparative & International Environmental Law, 23(1): 67–75. Wouters P, Chen H. 2013. China's ‘Soft-Path’ to Transboundary Water Cooperation Examined in the Light of Two Un Global Water Conventions – Exploring the ‘Chinese Way’. Social Science Electronic Publishing, 22(6): 119–128. Wu J, Zhang J, Wang S, et al. 2016. Assessment of Food Security in China: A New Perspective Based on Production-Consumption Coordination. Sustainability, 8(3): 183. WWAP (United Nations World Water Assessment Programme), 2015. The Un World Water Development Report 2015, Water for a Sustainable World. UNESCO, Paris. Xie G, Cao S, Lu C, et al. 2012. Current Status and Future Trends for Eco-Compensation in China. Journal of Resources & Ecology, 6(6): 355–362. Yang L W, Zhen L, WU S T. 2010. An Analysis of Identificaiton of Provider and Receiver for Eco-Compensation and Methods of Compensation Standard Calculation in China. Ecological Economy. (01): 298–302. (in Chinese) Yang S, Shen X C. 2009. The International Law as the Foundation in Solving the Water Resources Distribution of International Rivers. Journal of 140 Journal of Resources and Ecology Vol. 8 No. 2, 2017 Lanzhou University (Social Sciences), 37(4): 8–15. (in Chinese) Yang Q, Tian H, Friedrichs M A M, et al. 2014. Hydrological Responses to Climate and Land‐Use Changes Along the North American East Coast: A 110‐Year Historical Reconstruction. Jawra Journal of the American Water Resources Association, 51(1): 47–67. Yuan W Y, Zhou X K. 2014. Review of Research Progress Abroad in Payments for Ecosystem Services. China Population, Resources and Environment, 24(11): 76–82. (in Chinese) Yu X, Feng S. 2011. Analysis of Ecological Compensation Standard Estimation of River Basins in China. China Population, Resources and Environment, 21(9): 14–19. (in Chinese) Zhao X Y, Xu W, Dong X, et al. 2009. The Research Advances and Persp- ectives of Spatial Selection of Ecological Compensation Objects. Journal of Natural Resources, 24(10): 1772–1784. (in Chinese) Zhang Q, Michael B. 2011. Eco-compensation for watershed services in the People’s Republic of China. Mandaluyong City, Philippines, Asian Development Bank. Zhang Q, Bennett M, Kannan K, et al. 2010. Payments for ecological services and eco-compensation: Practices and innovations in the People’s Republic of China. Mandaluyong City, Philippines, Asian Development Bank. Zhang Z, Cheng L, Shang H, et al. 2012. Review and Trend of Eco-Compensation Mechanism on River Basin. Acta Ecologica Sinica, 32(20): 6543–6552. (in Chinese) 跨境河流的利益共享及生态补偿机制研究进展 韩赜 1,2,宋伟 1,邓祥征 1,3 1. 中国科学院地理科学与资源研究所,北京 100101; 2. 中国地质大学 信息工程学院,北京 100083; 3. 中国科学院农业政策研究中心,北京 100101 摘 要: 跨境河流具有重要的地缘政治和地缘经济内涵,但由于人口与经济的快速发展,跨境河流沿岸国常围绕水资源的开 发和利用引发地区矛盾。因此,如何从生态的视角解决水资源的公平合理地开发与有效保护生态环境之间的不平衡性成为国际社 会面临的主要问题。本文从跨境河流的相关国际水法出发,综述了利益共享、生态补偿机制以及适应性管理体系的研究进展。并 发现在法律制度上,国际水法已经形成了一套完整体系,并更加注重水资源的跨境合作与可持续利用;在解决跨境水资源冲突的 实践上,呈现从单一的水资源分配(零和结果)向利益共享转变的趋势,以期达到沿岸国多赢的目的,但跨境的生态补偿仍然存 在一定困难。在中国,上下游间的横向生态补偿已被中央政府高度重视,为建立省际之间的生态补偿机制提供了指导。从现有实 践来看,横向的生态补偿机制仍处于起步阶段,所实施范围小,法律制度薄弱,缺乏市场机制的动力并且依赖财政转移支付。未 来,中国应加强跨境水资源在法律制度、国际合作与利益共享方面的研究。由于政府在生态补偿的实践中兼具的多重身份(如推 动者,监管机构和买方),为了构建具有适应性管理的跨境生态补偿机制,政府应尽快完善在数据共享平台,水资源消耗标准及 相关政策和标准(或条例)等方面的建设。 关键词: 跨境河流;水资源;生态补偿;利益共享
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz