jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1248 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes in U.S. Presidential Elections 1960–2000 Michael D. Martinez University of Florida Jeff Gill University of California—Davis It is commonly believed by pundits and political elites that higher turnout favors Democratic candidates, but the extant research is inconsistent in finding this effect. The purpose of this article is to provide scholars with a methodology for assessing the likely effects of turnout on an election outcome using simulations based on survey data. By varying simulated turnout rates for five U.S. elections from 1960 to 2000, we observe that Democratic advantages from higher turnout (and Republican advantages from lower turnout) have steadily ebbed since 1960, corresponding to the erosion of class cleavages in U.S. elections. While there are volumes in the scholarly literature explaining why some individuals vote and others do not, as well as explaining variations in aggregatelevel turnout between countries and between states, the literature on whether turnout matters in political outcomes is less well developed. There is, however, an enduring question about whether turnout has substantial effects on who wins and loses partisan elections. In this paper, we review the theoretical foundations of the debate about whether higher election turnout advantages leftist parties, suggest a method of assessing the effects of turnout within a single election, and provide evidence from five U.S. elections that the partisan effects of turnout have eroded, concurrent to the decline in the class cleavage in partisanship in the United States. Conventional political wisdom conveyed by practitioners and pundits suggests that there is an obvious relationship between turnout and partisan electoral outcomes. To most amateur observers, prodding, cajoling, coaxing, mobilizing, or forcing more people to vote should bring a larger proportion of poorer and less educated into the electorate, which should naturally benefit leftist parties that support more liberal social welfare benefits (Erikson 1995). Conversely, conservative parties should generally benefit from institutional factors that depress turnout, including restrictive registration laws (Wolfinger and Rosenstone 1980), less convenient voting options (Southwell and Burchett 2000), and the fractured P THE JOURNAL OF POLITICS, Vol. 67, No. 4, November 2005, Pp. 1248–1274 © 2005 Southern Political Science Association jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1249 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1249 responsibility that results from indecisive elections (Blais 2000 27–32; Jackman 1987). Empirical investigations into this simple question have produced widely varying results. There is support for the conventional wisdom that higher levels of participation are associated with greater success of Democrats in Presidential elections (Radcliff 1994), at least in some states (Tucker, Vedlitz, and DeNardo 1986). Some scholars claim that this finding travels well, based on cross-national analyses of turnout and support for left-leaning parties in 19 western democracies (Pacek and Radcliff 1995), and analyses of the impact of turnout on support for Communist successor parties in fifteen post-Communist countries (Bohrer, Pacek, and Radcliff 2000) and left parties in elections for the European Parliament (Pacek and Radcliff 2003). On the other hand, there is also some evidence that indicates a negative relationship between higher turnout and Democratic vote shares in California Assembly Districts, 1992 Clinton vote shares in U.S. states, and Democratic gains in Congressional elections (Wuffle and Collet 1997). A few analyses suggest that the relationship between turnout and election outcomes is variable (Citrin, Shickler, and Sides 2003), contingent on the party-class linkage (Pacek and Radcliff 1995; Przeworski and Sprague 1988), or on the partisan composition of the district and the strength of the short-term forces which cause peripheral voters to defect (DeNardo 1980; Grofman, Owen, and Collet 1999; Nagel and McNulty 1996, 2000). Finally, some investigations based on presidential election results in non-Southern U.S. states (Erikson 1995) and comparisons across eighteen nations (Tóka 2000) suggest either null or very minimal partisan consequences stemming from normal variations in turnout. Most simply of all, DeNardo’s (1980, 407) scatterplot of turnout and the Democratic presidential candidates’ share of the vote (which we extend through the 2004 elections in Figure 1) shows wide variations both above and below a flat regression line.1 Such a simple and obvious question (which is not even a question to many lay observers) has created a muddle of findings. Theory In essence, the conventional “lay” wisdom rests on the foundation of the Columbia school of electoral analysis. To borrow Lipset’s (1960) title, “political man” is defined by his social status. When the less wealthy, less educated, manual workers vote, they are generally more supportive of redistributive policies advocated by left parties than are wealthier, better educated professionals and managers. The left’s numerical advantages are usually thwarted, however, by two related factors. First, weaker participatory skills and limited access to resources depress the rates of participation among the lower class. Second, other crosscutting social cleavages, such as religion, can undercut the political conscious1 It is interesting to note from the figure that the 2000 and 2004 were entirely typical of the relation, despite widespread journalistic claim otherwise. P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1250 1250 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill FIGURE 1 An Update of DeNardo’s Turnout Graph: 1932–2004 R2 = 0.0022 1936 60 1964 55 1940 50 1944 1976 1948 1996 1960 2000 2004 1988 45 Democrat’s Share of Vote (%) 1932 1952 1992 1956 1980 1968 40 1984 1972 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 Rate of Turnout Among Eligible Voters (%) Data in addition to DeNardo (1980): Turnout 1980–2000 from McDonald and Popkin (2001), Partisan vote 1980–2000 from Statistical Abstract of the United States, all 2004 from http://elections.gmu.edu/voter turnout.htm (McDonald’s estimates). P ness of the working class (Lazarsfeld, Berelson, and Gaudet 1948), demobilizing the left’s electoral base. Thus, this perspective suggests that a very low turnout election is likely to produce electoral results favorable to the right, as participants with higher socioeconomic status, especially those with rightist partisan tendencies, should comprise a larger proportion of smaller electorates. As turnout increases, that predicted configuration dissipates as the rightist core voters are joined by an increasingly disproportionate share of the lower socioeconomic status voters who generally have leftist leanings. Thus, the standard story, based on the Columbia school’s sociological portrait of voters, predicts that left’s partisan advantage from higher turnout stems from the difference in the tilt of the underlying partisan predispositions between core voters and peripheral voters. An alternative theoretical foundation, introduced by DeNardo (1980), rests on the basic tenets of the Michigan model in which the core electorate is mainly comprised of “true believer” strong partisans from both the right and the left. Higher interest elections both stimulate participation by political Independents who are swayed by short-term issue and candidate factors, and weaker partisans jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1251 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1251 in both camps who are more likely to defect than are the core strong partisans. (See A. Campbell 1960 for the classic surge-and-decline model, and J. Campbell 1987 for an elegant revision.) The behavior of cross-pressured partisans is expected to vary with the partisan stimulus of the election. In low stimulus elections, cross-pressured partisans may not vote at all, because of indecision or an inability to bring themselves to vote for the opposing party’s candidate. High stimulus elections (particularly close elections) provide a greater incentive or pressure to vote, but the cross-pressures make them less likely to be faithful to their own party. DeNardo concludes that roughly comparable defection rates of weaker partisans should, in fact, work to the advantage of the minority party in an election, since a high stimulus election would produce a larger absolute number of defecting majority partisans than defecting minority partisans. Thus, from DeNardo’s perspective, higher turnout should work to the Democrats’ advantage in heavily Republican districts with more potential Republican defectors, but will advantage Republicans in heavily Democratic districts with more potential Democratic defectors (DeNardo 1980, 413–16).2 From DeNardo’s perspective, higher turnout brings higher defection rates, which should normally work to the advantage of the minority party. While DeNardo’s logic helps us understand how defections resulting from short-term electoral forces might mitigate or vitiate any advantages that the left would derive from increased turnout, it does not follow that the relationship between turnout and partisan advantage should be contingent on the balance of the long-term partisan distribution in any electoral district. The faulty conclusion, we think, stems from DeNardo’s assumption that weak partisans on both sides of the political spectrum would defect at comparable rates. They might, if candidates from the two parties were approximately equally popular (or unpopular), neither party was advantaged from a dominant issue on the political agenda, and retrospective evaluations of the economy were neither enthusiastically positive nor severely negative.3 But short-term forces vary from election to election, and could benefit either the existing minority or majority. One could easily imagine, for example, that majority Democrats might be less likely to defect than minority Republicans when a popular Democratic incumbent controls salient issues and is blessed with widespread concerns about the Republican challenger (Converse, Clausen, and Miller 1965). But Democrats might be more likely than Republicans to defect when a popular Republican incumbent presides over a booming economy. Thus, the contingent factor motivating the prevailing direction of par2 DeNardo also notes that dealigning processes might erase the concept of partisan core voters, and thus vitiate any relationship at all between turnout and partisan outcomes. Presumably, a restoration of mass partisanship (Bartels 2000; Hetherington 2001) would strengthen the relationship. Furthermore, higher turnout may bring in the more volatile crosspressured partisan abstainers who would normally resolve their dissonance simply by not voting at all. 3 DeNardo mentions the essential flaw in treating “the level of turnout and rates of defection as independent quantities” (1980, 418), so it makes sense from the same logic not to generalize across parties. P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1252 1252 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill TABLES 1 Class Voting, Selected 1960–2000 Class voting Among whites Among entire electorate 1960 1964 1976 1984 2000 12 13 19 20 17 21 8 12 -6 2 Entries represent % working class that voted Democratic minus % middle class that voted Democratic (Abramson, Aldrich, and Rohde 2002, 109). P tisan defections is not the underlying distribution of partisanship in the electorate, but the public’s evaluation of candidates, issues, and the “nature of the times.” From either the conventional wisdom or DeNardo’s perspective, the strength of the relationship between turnout and the left vote might be contingent on the strength of the partisan class cleavage (Pacek and Radcliff 1995). The addition of manual workers to the electorate helps the left if their votes are based on their class, but are less likely to help the left if their votes are based on more traditional religious values or other factors not associated with class interests. If this is indeed the case, the weakening of the class-party cleavage in the United States, as illustrated in Table 1, should have also resulted in a weakening of the relationship between turnout and partisan outcomes in U.S. elections. The muddle of empirical findings that we noted at the outset of this paper may reflect our collective desire as social scientists to seek generalizable results across elections (either across time, states, or countries) when the underlying relationship is situationally contingent. Grofman, Owen, and Collet (1999) argue that part of the existing confusion arises from the fact that we are not really addressing a single simple question, but have tangled three logically independent questions. Grofman, Owen, and Collet’s (1999) first question is whether peripheral voters have greater Democratic proclivities than core voters. The second question, which is quite different from the first, is whether elections with higher turnout should provide more favorable results to Democratic candidates. Even if peripheral voters are more Democratic than core voters, DeNardo’s logic suggests the same contingent factors that motivate peripheral Democrats to vote may also motivate them to defect from their partisanship. Both of those questions are logically independent from the third question: if turnout were increased in some given election, would Democrats have done better? Grofman, Owen, and Collet seem satisfied that the literature has provided answers to the first two questions (peripheral voters may have been more Democratic in previous eras, but that’s less true now, and partisan defections by peripheral voters tend to obviate any advantage that Democrats would gain by higher turnout), but the third question still awaits a sufficient means to answer it. We seek to answer this question by using survey data to simulate the likely effects of turnout on the partisan composition of the electorate and its aggregate electoral choice. jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1253 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1253 The Research Question and Strategy of Inquiry Our central concern is to determine whether or not increased levels of voter turnout in specific elections would have aided the Democratic party and whether decreased turnout would have aided the Republican party in U.S. presidential elections over the past 40 years. In the process of addressing this question, we will assess: • whether higher levels of turnout are associated with a greater tilt toward the Democrats into the electorate (consistent with the conventional wisdom); • whether higher levels of turnout are associated with greater defection rates (consistent with DeNardo’s hypothesis); and • whether the strength of the relationship between turnout and partisan outcomes has declined concomitant with the decline in the class-party cleavage in the United States. The difficult issue that has faced the study of voter turnout has not been with inadequate or poorly developed theory, so much as with uncertainty over how best to “test” a hypothetical question about the possible effects of changes in turnout on partisan outcomes. Political scientists cannot rerun elections, as laboratory experiments. However, students of contemporary elections have a great advantage over those who study elections prior to World War II. Owing to the National Election Studies surveys, we have a rich compendium of data on voter choice and electoral participation in virtually every major national election, with considerable continuity in questions and methods. These data open the possibility for simulations of election outcomes, based on estimations of the structure of electoral choice and turnout in each election. Our basic approach, which is similar to Lacy and Burden (1999), is as follows. We posit that U.S. citizens generally have three unordered choices in each election: vote Democratic, vote Republican, or abstain. We first estimate vote choice (including abstention) as an unordered multinomial logit function of standard variables associated with both candidate preference and the likelihood of voting. From that estimation, we derive probabilities for each respondent’s selection of each of the three choices (abstain, vote Democratic, or vote Republican). We simulate higher turnout by starting with the actual voters in a given election and progressively adding actual abstainers who had the lowest estimated probability of abstaining. We simulate lower turnout by progressively subtracting actual voters who had the highest probability of abstaining from the pool of voters. The simulated results allow us to make informed estimates about the most likely consequences in any given election as if turnout had been different. (Methodological details are provided in Appendix A of the website ancillary materials). Citrin, Shickler, and Sides (2003) also use a simulation methodology to address the same question with respect to U.S. Senate elections in 1994, 1996, and 1998. Using exit poll data, they calculate the additive effects of age, income, education, gender, ethnicity, union membership, and veteran status on voter choice among P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1254 1254 P Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill observed voters (exit poll respondents). As we do here, they estimate the impact of increased turnout on electoral outcomes by assuming that parameters of candidate choice among voters would have been the same among nonvoters if the latter had actually voted. Despite this basic similarity, there are important differences in our methods. Citrin, Shickler, and Sides’ comparisons between voters in exit poll surveys and to census distributions constrain them to a Columbia school (sociological) model of voter choice (2003, 79), while our estimation allows for the potential effects of a variety of attitudinal and other nondemographic variables on both the decision to vote and candidate preference. Second, our methodology yields estimated probabilities of abstention and candidate preference, enabling us to examine the likely impact of turnout at smaller discrete increments of turnout change. Third, since we can also estimate the probability of abstention among actual voters, our methodology allows us to estimate the likely effects of lower turnout as well as higher turnout, an aspect of the relationship which has been neglected by much of this literature. Thus, our simulation methodology offers a different approach to understand the entire turnout-partisan effects question than that proposed by Citrin and his coauthors. To the extent that the results of the two approaches converge, we can be more confident that our conclusions are not dependent on the assumptions inherent in each. We examine five presidential elections (1960, 1964, 1976, 1984, and 2000) which represent the variation in conditions that might affect the relationship between turnout and partisan outcomes. While our primary purpose is to understand partisan behavior in two-party presidential races going forward in time, we do not focus purely on the last one or two elections since it is easily possible in this study to generalize “across space” as advised in King, Keohane, and Verba (1994, 219). The unit of space here is time, and we include previous cases that address the same hypotheses and retain the same general characteristics. There are three important driving considerations for the case-selection methodology. First, the period covers the decline of class polarization in the U.S. party system noted by many authors (Abramson, Aldrich, and Rohde 2002, 113–15; Dalton 1996; Nieuwbeerta and de Graaf 1999). Table 1 (taken from Abramson, Aldrich, and Rohde 2002, 109) shows that among voters, the party-class cleavage was moderate in 1960, relatively strong in 1964 and 1976, but weakened considerably by 1984 and dwindled even further in 2000. If the relationship between partisan outcomes and turnout is conditioned on the party-class cleavage (cf. Pacek and Radcliff 1995), we would expect to see diminishing effects later in this time span. Second, our cases include elections which appeared to be (and were) close, as well as a couple of landslides. The anticipated closeness of an election might very well change the strategic behavior of elites and potential voters, which could affect both the likelihood of voting and in some circumstances, voter preferences. While it is unlikely that slight variations in the underlying conditions would have altered the outcomes of landslide elections, we include two such cases both to jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1255 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1255 serve as contrasts to close elections and to examine whether variations in turnout might have affected the winner’s margin of victory (which might, in turn, expand or contract his electoral coattails). Third, changes in election laws over this time period generally eased registration requirements in an attempt to lower the costs of voting and increase turnout. Two of our selected cases precede the 1965 federal Voting Rights Act, which eliminated some significant state restrictions on voter registration. Over this period, many states also eased voter registration requirements (either reducing or eliminating residency requirements or otherwise making registration more convenient), and the National Voter Registration Act of 1993 mandated many other states to take similar actions. Thus, the costs of voting should have abated somewhat over this time period. In sum, our selected cases represent a diverse set of electoral conditions and outcomes. The 1960 election was a landmark contest between a photogenic young challenger and the ultimate political insider, eventually decided by a razor-thin margin. The Democratic partisan majority was at its post-war peak in 1964 and contributed to a landslide victory for President Johnson and congressional Democrats. Twelve years later, the subsequent Democratic majority had eroded considerably, and Jimmy Carter eked out a close victory over President Ford. By 1984, a surge in Republican partisanship precipitated (or was precipitated by) President Reagan’s landslide reelection. The 2000 presidential election was the closest presidential contest in the twentieth century, so we were naturally curious about the possible effects of turnout on its outcome. Thus, in order to gain some leverage in understanding the effects of underlying partisan distributions and short-term forces on the relationship between turnout levels and electoral outcomes, we have selected a Democratic landslide year (1964), a Republican landslide year (1984), two close Democratic victories (1960 and 1976), and an election in which the Republican won a razor-close electoral college vote while losing an equally close popular vote (2000). While there is variation in the underlying conditions of these elections, they all were contested primarily between the two major-party candidates and thus provide a clean look at the electoral ramifications of simulating changing turnout in two-party elections. There is no doubt that George Wallace, John Anderson, and Ross Perot significantly affected electoral environments during this time period, not least by stimulating participation by some people who would have otherwise abstained. Nevertheless, the choice alternatives in the elections of 1968, 1980, 1992, and 1996 were fundamentally different, and the presence of those third-party candidates obscures direct comparisons of the effect of varying levels of turnout on the partisan advantages of the two major parties. Such effects of third-party candidacies on turnout and partisan choice are interesting questions (and perhaps subjects for future studies), but here we seek to retain a focus on two-party competition in the context of recent presidential elections that we hypothesize having similar characteristics to future contests. As Collier and Brady note “Increasing the number of observations to gain leverage in addressing rival P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1256 1256 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill explanations is not always helpful, in part because it may push scholars to compare cases that are not analytically equivalent” (2004, 8). Thus, we confine this analysis to two-party contests over this time period, while recognizing the potential significance of third parties in affecting electoral outcomes. The Data and Estimation We base our analyses on the 1960, 1964, 1976, 1984, and 2000 American National Election Studies.4 In each year, we classify respondents as abstainers, Democratic voters, or Republican voters. Voter participation is determined by self-report in 1960 and 2000 and by voter validation in 1964, 1976, and 1984.5 Candidate choice is based on self-reported presidential votes in each year. We exclude the few NES respondents who voted for minor-party candidates, as well as those who did not know or refused to report if or for whom they voted. Details on the full coding for the 1984 data are contained in Appendix C of the website ancillary materials, as an example of our work in the other elections. Table 2 shows the distribution of the outcome variable in each year. As is usually the case, NES survey self-reports of turnout are much higher than the actual turnout of eligible voters in the presidential election, due to NES’s difficulty in finding some secluded abstainers, the greater post-election survey participation rates of politically interested voters as compared to uninterested abstainers (especially after enduring the NES preelection survey), and abstainers’ misreporting. NES’s estimates of voters’ choices were much closer to the actual election outcomes (and easily within 95% confidence intervals) in 1960, 1976, 1984, and 2000, but there was a significant overreport for Johnson and under report for Goldwater in 1964. In order to derive probabilities of individuals voting Democratic, voting Republican, and abstaining, we estimate multivariate models based on a wide variety of variables. Since the outcome variable represents both the decision to P 4 The principal investigators of the American National Election Studies used in this paper were the Political Behavior Program at the University of Michigan (1960, 1964), Warren E. Miller and Arthur Miller (1976), Warren E. Miller and the National Election Studies (1984), and Nancy Burns, Donald R. Kinder, Steven J. Rosenstone, Virginia Sapiro, and the National Election Studies (2000). The 1960, 1964, 1976, and 1984 NES Data were taken from CD0010 (issued May 1995) by the Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research and the National Election Studies. 2000 NES Data were made available to us by ICPSR (Study 3131). Neither the principal investigators, NES, nor ICPSR bear any responsibility for our analyses and interpretations. 5 In cases in which the NES voter validation efforts yielded ambiguous results, we relied on respondents’ self-reports. Thus in the 1976 study, we followed the procedure described by Abramson and Claggett (1984, 737) for determining validated voters and nonvoters. Among those respondents, there were 1,053 abstainers (49.4%), 521 Carter voters (24.4%), and 557 Ford voters (26.1%). NES was unable to validate 347 respondents as either voters or nonvoters. For those respondents only, we used self-reports of voting to classify 24 as abstainers, 18 as Carter voters, and 23 as Ford voters. jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1257 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1257 TABLE 2 Abstentions and Two-Party Votes ANES 1960 Presidential Election 1964 Presidential Election 1976 Presidential Election 1984 Presidential Election 2000 Presidential Election Abstainers Kennedy voters Nixon voters Total cases Abstainers Johnson voters Goldwater voters Total cases Abstainers Carter voters Ford voters Total cases Abstainers Mondale voters Reagan voters Total cases Abstainers Gore Voters Bush Voters Total cases 329 699 722 1,750 532 682 338 1,552 1,077 539 580 2,196 706 502 712 1,920 426 550 507 1,483 18.8% 39.9% 41.3% 34.3% 43.9% 21.8% 49.0% 24.5% 26.4% 36.8% 26.1% 37.1% 28.7% 37.1% 34.2% Population Estimates 39,072,000 34,227,000 34,108,000 107,407,000 41,897,000 43,130,000 27,178,000 112,205,000 67,168,000 40,831,000 39,148,000 147,147,000 69,298,000 37,577,000 54,455,000 161,330,000 84,064,900 50,999,897 50,456,002 185,520,799 Source 36.4% 31.9% 31.8% a c c 37.3% 38.4% 24.2% a c c 45.6% 27.7% 26.6% a c c 43.0% 23.3% 33.8% a c c 45.3% 27.5% 27.2% b d d a: Voting Eligible Population minus total number of votes cast for President (McDonald and Popkin 2001, 966). b: Voting Eligible Population (McDonald and Popkin 2001, 966) minus the total number of votes cast for the president (FEC Report of the 2000 Presidential Election). c: Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2000 edition (Table 452), http://www.census.gov/prod/www/statisticalabstract-us.html. d: Federal Election Commission Report of the 2000 Presidential Election (http://www.fec.gov). vote or not to vote and the candidate choice (Democrat or Republican) for voters, we chose explanatory variables that we expect to be associated with turnout or candidate preference, or both. Exact question wordings and variable constructions varied somewhat due to the evolution of the NES between 1960 and 2000, but in general, we expected turnout to be motivated by demographic variables (age and education), mobilization variables (contact by each party), social connectedness variables (married, children living in the household, church attendance), and attitudes toward the campaign (knowledge of the issues, interest, and caring about the outcome of the election) and the political system (belief that there are important differences between the parties, internal efficacy, external efficacy, and political trust). Similarly, we selected a range of variables that might affect candidate preference, including partisanship, retrospective evaluations of the economy and the president’s job performance, demographic variables (dummies for Black, P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1258 1258 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill Catholic, Born-Again Protestant), issue preferences (which varied from year to year), and evaluations of candidates. Incorporating these and other independent variables, we utilized a multinomial logit model to generate estimates of the effects of each explanatory variable on the probabilities of voting Democratic and voting Republican compared to the baseline category of abstention.6 There are few surprises in the estimated coefficients themselves (shown in Appendix B of the web site ancillary materials). Negative evaluations of the president’s handling of the economy are a strong motivation to vote for the challenger party, more so than the overall sociotropic evaluation of the economy itself. Party identification also has a very strong influence in each model, reflecting its pervasive influence in the vote choice (Markus and Converse 1979), as well as the possibility that current party identification reflects short-term influences contemporaneously associated with the vote choice (Page and Jones 1979). Trait evaluations of presidential candidates also had sharp effects of the vote choice in 1984 and 2000. We found a variety of issues with significant direct effects (Medicare and job guarantee in 1964; environmental spending, aid to blacks, and level of services and spending in 1984; and indices of moral issues, service issues, and race issues in 2000). Regular church attendance, high levels of education, external efficacy, perceiving differences between the parties on issues, age, interest in the campaign, and caring about the outcome of the election all generally improved the likelihood of voting for either candidate over abstention in each year under study. In most instances, Republican and Democratic contact appeared to stimulate turnout for both candidates, underscoring the effects of mobilization (Gerber and Green 2000; Rosenstone and Hansen 1993) and reflecting relatively intense efforts on both sides to convert voters. In 1960, 1964, and 1984, the contact coefficients suggest that Republican mobilization efforts appeared to be more efficacious than Democratic efforts, but Democratic efforts were equally successful in 1976 and 2000. In the 2000 election, we were able to observe the mobilizing effects of increasing numbers of political discussion partners and the effects of homogeneous networks on the individual vote choice. P 6 The multinomial logit model generates estimates of the effects of each explanatory variable on the probabilities of voting Democratic and voting Republican compared to the baseline category of abstention. The most direct way to understand the magnitude of these coefficient estimates is to evalÈp ˘ uate the log ratio of the predictors given by: log Í ij ˙ = X i b j , which is just the log of the ratio of Î pi0 ˚ probability of selecting choice j to the probability of selecting the baseline choice. The fact that it is given by multiplying the jth coefficient vector by the respondent’s explanatory variable values makes this a particularly easy quantity to obtain. At first the restriction to the baseline comparison seems restrictive, but based on the properties of logs, any desired comparison can be obtained since: È pij ˘ È pij ˘ Èp ˘ Xi(bj - bk) = Xibj - Xibk = log Í ˙ - log Í ˙ = log[pij] - log[pi0] - log[pik] + log[pi0] = log Í ij ˙ , Î pi0 ˚ Î pi0 ˚ Î pik ˚ where j and k represent two arbitrarily chosen choice categories. Therefore we can estimate any relative probabilistic comparison desired. jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1259 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1259 Simulation of Turnout Based on the MNL Models Our interest is in the expected behavior of individuals given the estimated coefficients reported in Appendix B of the website ancillary materials. Since the product of the estimated coefficients and the explanatory variables for the ith individual is equal to the log of the odds of i selecting choice j (either Democrat or Republican) divided by the odds of abstaining, then we can algebraically rearrange to produce the probabilities of abstaining, voting Democratic, and voting Republican, based on the fact that the sum the three probabilities equals one for every respondent.7 Accordingly, for each respondent, we calculated a conditional probability of voting for each candidate, excluding the probability of abstention by p(Dem vote) = p(Dem) 1 - p(abstain) p(Rep vote) = p(Rep) 1 - p(abstain) To simulate the aggregate vote choice at a given level of turnout, we sum the conditional probabilities, p(Dem|vote) and p(Rep|vote), across a specific set of respondents. Table 3 shows that we generally did better at predicting a voter’s choice between candidates than in predicting an abstention. For the NES respondents who voted, the sums of the conditional probabilities are again very close to the actual reported votes. Thus, while we acknowledge that any individual’s conditional vote probability is measured with error, the model’s overall fit is reasonably good, and it appears to predict Democratic and Republican votes about equally well. Of course, we are still faced with one of the banes of survey research in U.S. elections: overestimation of turnout. Survey estimates of turnout are almost always inflated by overreports of voting (Bernstein, Chadha, and Montjoy 2001; Silver, Anderson, and Abramson 1986) due to stimulation of political interest by multielection panels and preelection surveys (Bartels 2000), and differences in survey participation rates between voters and nonvoters. We used voter validation studies (where available) to partially alleviate the problems associated with the first of those factors, but are limited in our ability to go much beyond that. Nevertheless, our purpose in this exercise is to determine whether the distribution of the two-party votes would have been substantially altered by any change in turnout above or below the actual level. Thus, in our pursuit of an answer to 7  p This is done using log ÈÍ ij ˘˙ = Xibj, and this underlying individual accounting identity, p Î i0 ˚ J j =1 p ij = 1, we obtain the marginal individual vote probabilities: J ˆ Ê pi1 = Á1 +  exp[X i b j ]˜ ¯ Ë j =2 -1 pik = exp[X i b j ] pi1 , " j Œ[2, . . . , J ]. This approach allows us to compare actual voting and abstaining outcomes to predicted outcomes, although other approaches were tried. See Appendix A of the website ancillary materials). P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1260 1260 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill TABLE 3 Predicted and Actual Choices 1960 1964 1976 1984 2000 Correlations of Actual Versus Predicted Abstention .58 Vote Democratic .86 Vote Republican .89 .46 .72 .78 .57 .68 .70 .54 .81 .81 .72 .85 .82 Reported Two-party Totals Versus Sum of Conditionals Reported Democratic 49.2% 66.9% Average Predicted Democratic 50.2% 67.7% P 48.5% 48.4% 41.4% 41.4% 52.0% 52.7% Grofman, Owen, and Collet’s third question (if turnout were increased in some given election, would Democrats have done better?), we are not so much interested in the absolute level of turnout as in the effects of changes in turnout relative to the baseline. For the moment, then, we accept the distribution of turnout as indicated by each NES survey as the baseline. Higher levels of turnout are simulated by the set of respondents who actually voted, plus the nonvoters who had the lowest probability of abstaining. In the 2000 presidential election, an electorate with a 81.79% turnout rate is represented by those respondents who actually voted (71.3%) plus the nonvoters who had no more than a .4945 probability of abstention. An electorate with a 87.63% turnout rate includes those who actually voted, plus the nonvoters who had no more than a .6984 probability of abstention. And so on. Lower levels of turnout are simulated by sequentially removing actual voters with the highest probability of abstaining. For example, in 2000, an electorate with a 54.85% turnout rate is simulated by the set of actual voters who had no more than a .2411 probability of abstention. Lower levels of turnout are simulated by lowering the thresholds of abstention probabilities. For each of twenty subsets of respondents (simulating turnout rates from 6.41% to 100% in 2000), we calculate the vote distribution between the Democrats and Republicans by summing p(Dem|vote) and p(Rep|vote) and calculating percentages based on those sums. This methodology and others like it assume that the factors which motivated voters to choose between the Democratic and Republican candidates would have similarly influenced nonvoters, if nonvoters had actually voted. These are hypothetical votes (or, more precisely, sums of conditional probabilities based on estimations), so we will never know for sure how any abstainer would have voted in that counterfactual condition. Indeed, it is possible that our parameter estimates are derived from a set of relatively high information voters, and the factors that are salient to their vote choices might not be salient in the choices of “peripheral” voters who could have been seduced to polls. jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1261 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1261 Our data suggest that is not the case, however. Nonvoters’ reports of their own candidate preferences provide validation of the methodology and justification of the assumption. Using the 2000 Presidential election as an example, among actual abstainers who expressed a post-election preference for Gore, the sums of the conditional probabilities tilted heavily in his favor (75% to 25%). Among the actual abstainers who favored Bush in the post-election survey, the sums of the conditional probabilities heavily favored Bush (73% to 27%). Among the actual abstainers who expressed no candidate preference in the post-election survey, the sums of the conditional vote probabilities were split almost right down the middle (50.2% to 49.8% in Bush’s favor).8 Thus, the abstainers themselves provided some concurrent validation of our estimates. 1960: Heavy Turnout Helps the Democrats, and They Needed It Does the level of turnout affect the distribution of the votes for Kennedy and Nixon in 1960? Panel 1 of Figure 2 arrays the simulated two-party vote percentages for Kennedy against the twenty levels of turnout,9 and shows that simulated increases in turnout would have benefited the Democratic candidate. Among the NES respondents who voted, Kennedy received 49.0% of the vote. Above that baseline, his vote share increases with increased turnout, though the rate of growth is small. For example, a 10-point increase in turnout would have raised Kennedy’s vote share less than one-half percentage point, to 49.4%. Sharper effects are evident in our simulation of reduced turnout in the 1960 election. A 20-point decline in turnout would have reduced Kennedy’s vote share by three points (to 45.7%), and the rate of Kennedy’s loss increases as turnout declines further. Over a 40-point range of simulated turnout (from 51.2% to 91.2%), we estimate that Kennedy’s vote share would vary about 5.8%. The closeness of the actual result in 1960 suggests that Kennedy could not have afforded any significantly reduced turnout in the 1960 presidential race. Lower turnout would have spelled trouble for Kennedy because, as predicted by the conventional model, the electorate quickly would have become far less Democratic in its partisanship. Table 4 shows that the Democrats enjoyed a 13.2% tilt (excluding leaners) in the electorate at the baseline turnout rate of 81.2%, but that advantage shrinks rapidly and eventually disappears as turnout declines. In the smaller electorates, partisans of both stripes are significantly more loyal to their party’s nominees, and in very small electorates, Republicans enjoy a numerical advantage and are stunningly loyal to Nixon. Turnout above the high baseline increases the Democratic tilt slightly and marginally increases the defection rate among both parties. 8 These validating analyses were based on the tenth replicate dataset from the multiple imputations in our analysis of the 2000 NES. See Appendix A of the website ancillary materials for an explanation of the multiple imputation procedure for dealing with missing data in R. 9 As turnout increases, by definition, the sample size of voters increases. Thus, the 95% confidence bands around the estimated vote for Kennedy become narrower with higher levels of turnout. P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1262 1262 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill FIGURE 2 The Effect of Turnout on Percent Votes for Democrats 5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75 85 95 5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75 85 95 Sum of Conditional Probabilities of Voting for Democrat (%) 5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75 85 95 5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75 85 95 1960 1964 1984 2000 5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75 85 95 1976 95% Confidence Bands Included Vertical Line at Actual Turnout Simulated Turnout Rate from ANES Sample 1964: Heavy Turnout Helps the Democrats, But They Apparently Did Not Need It P Panel 2 of Figure 2 shows a similar relationship between simulated turnout and partisan outcomes, but Johnson’s landslide victory made those effects basically moot. Among the 65.7% of NES respondents who voted, Johnson wins 67.4% of the vote. Above that baseline, LBJ’s vote share steadily increases with increased turnout, though the rate of growth is small. For example, a 20-point increase in turnout (to 85.7%) would have raised Johnson’s vote share a little over one percentage point, to 68.7%. Much sharper effects are evident in our simulation of reduced turnout in the 1964 election. A 20-point decline in turnout (to 45.7%) would have reduced Johnson’s vote share by almost four points (to 63.4%), and the rate of Johnson’s loss increases as turnout declines further. The overall effect of turnout on partisan choice is neither nontrivial nor overwhelming. Over the 40-point range of simulated turnout (from 45.7% of to 85.7%), we estimate that Johnson’s vote share would vary only about 5.3%. Put another way, the magnitude of the actual Democratic victory in 1964 means that Johnson would have likely won the popular vote with any turnout rate above an abysmal 24%, though his considerable presidential coattails almost surely would have been reduced by a substantially smaller electorate. jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1263 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1263 TABLE 4 Partisan Composition and Partisan Voting Behavior in 1960 Simulated Turnout 15.6 31.6 47.9 89.0 92.4 96.0 100 Partisan Self-Identification Among Voters at Varying Levels of Turnout Strong Democrat 15.3 20.5 21.4 20.8 21.6 21.4 20.9 Weak Democrat 9.0 15.1 18.8 22.1 24.3 24.2 25.0 Lean Democrat 2.5 4.2 4.4 4.8 5.7 5.9 6.1 Independent 4.3 5.2 6.7 8.0 8.1 8.3 8.4 Lean Republican 6.1 6.0 6.9 7.2 7.6 7.5 7.7 Weak Republican 17.1 16.9 16.4 15.9 14.7 14.9 14.6 Strong Republican 45.7 32.2 25.5 21.2 18.0 17.8 17.2 21.2 25.1 6.3 8.4 7.6 14.4 17.0 21.1 25.5 6.5 8.7 7.4 14.1 16.9 20.9 25.7 6.6 9.0 7.2 13.9 16.6 Democratic Tilt (%Dem–%Rep) Including Lean -42.1 -15.1 Without Lean -38.5 -13.4 -4.2 -1.7 64.6 85.4 11.3 13.2 11.3 12.9 12.6 14.2 13.6 14.9 14.7 15.6 15.6 16.2 Partisanship and Vote Choice at Varying Levels of Turnout Democrats loyal 23.6 34.6 37.7 39.6 41.8 Democrats defect 3.2 5.2 6.8 8.1 9.8 Indep. Voting Democrat 2.1 2.4 2.8 3.6 3.8 Indep. Voting Republican 2.2 2.8 3.8 4.4 4.4 Republicans defect 1.2 1.5 2.2 3.2 3.4 Republicans loyal 67.7 53.5 46.5 41.1 36.9 41.5 10.0 3.9 4.4 3.5 36.6 41.7 10.4 4.0 4.5 3.5 36.0 42.0 10.6 4.1 4.4 3.5 35.5 42.2 10.8 4.2 4.4 3.5 34.9 42.2 11.1 4.5 4.6 3.5 34.2 Percent of Partisans Defecting Dem. Defection Rate 12.0 Rep. Defection Rate 1.7 19.3 8.8 20.0 8.9 20.1 8.9 20.3 9.1 20.8 9.3 13.1 2.7 15.3 4.6 3.5 5.8 81.2 17.0 7.1 19.0 8.5 The 1964 election fits the conventional wisdom to a tee. Table 5 shows that, at high levels of turnout, Johnson benefits from an increasingly Democratic electorate. Among the actual voters in 1964, self-identified Democrats outnumbered self-identified Republicans (excluding leaners) by a margin of 25.2%. At a simulated turnout rate 20 points higher than actual, the Democratic tilt increases by nearly three points (to 28.1%). At lower levels of simulated turnout, the effects on the partisan tilt are even more evident. At a very low level of turnout (26.3%), the electorate is about evenly divided between self-identified Democrats and Republicans. As turnout increases, the Democratic tenor of the electorate becomes increasingly pronounced, though the rate of change is marginally decreasing above the baseline turnout of 65.7%. Contrary to DeNardo’s hypothesis, the defection rate among both Democrats and Republicans hardly budges at all as simulated turnout increases above the actual turnout rate of 65.7%. The lower panel of Table 5 shows that Democratic partisans were slightly less likely to defect at the simulated turnout rate 20 points higher than actual, and the Republican defection rate increased by only one-tenth of 1%. At lower simulated levels of turnout, the core Republican voters were significantly more loyal, but Democrats were only slightly so. Thus, 1964 provides P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1264 1264 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill TABLE 5 Partisan Composition and Partisan Voting Behavior in 1964 Simulated Turnout 13.1 26.3 79.4 86.3 93.1 100 Partisan Self-Identification Among Voters at Varying Levels of Turnout Strong Democrat 15.3 25.5 30.7 31.4 29.2 30.5 30.2 Weak Democrat 12.5 19.0 20.3 21.6 23.8 23.5 24.6 Lean Democrat 1.4 2.7 4.5 6.0 7.3 6.8 6.9 Independent .2 .9 2.3 3.8 5.4 5.1 5.3 Lean Republican 15.9 11.0 8.4 6.9 6.5 6.3 6.3 Weak Republican 24.4 19.3 17.4 15.9 14.9 14.9 14.4 Strong Republican 30.1 21.6 16.4 14.3 12.9 12.9 12.4 29.3 25.0 7.7 5.8 6.0 14.4 11.8 28.2 25.1 8.3 6.7 5.9 14.2 11.5 27.2 25.2 9.5 7.6 5.7 13.6 11.2 Democratic Tilt (%Dem–%Rep) Including Lean -41.1 Without Lean -26.6 4.6 3.7 39.4 72.6 26.7 26.3 28.7 28.0 29.9 28.1 30.0 27.6 31.3 27.6 Partisanship and Vote Choice at Varying Levels of Turnout Democrats loyal 27.2 43.0 50.0 52.9 53.3 Democrats defect 2.1 4.3 5.6 6.1 7.0 Indep. Voting Democrat .2 .5 1.7 2.8 4.1 Indep. Voting Republican .0 .5 .6 1.0 1.4 Republicans defect 8.3 9.0 9.2 9.4 10.0 Republicans loyal 62.1 42.8 32.9 27.7 24.3 54.0 6.8 3.8 1.3 9.7 24.4 54.8 6.9 3.9 1.3 9.5 23.5 55.0 7.0 4.3 1.5 9.4 22.7 54.4 7.2 5.1 1.7 9.5 22.1 54.6 7.2 5.8 1.9 9.5 21.1 Percent of Partisans Defecting Dem. Defection Rate 7.2 Rep. Defection Rate 11.8 11.1 28.5 11.2 28.7 11.3 29.3 11.7 30.2 11.7 31.0 10.0 21.9 21.8 22.8 65.7 26.0 25.2 9.1 17.3 13.4 17.3 52.6 10.3 25.4 11.5 29.2 no support at all for DeNardo’s conjecture that the minority party should benefit from higher turnout. 1976: Ford Should Have Prayed for Rain P In contrast to the 1964 Democratic landslide, the presidential election of 1976 was extremely close. Republican Gerald Ford’s succession to the Presidency ended, in his words, “our long national nightmare” of Watergate, but his unpopular pardon of his predecessor and a sluggish economy put him far behind at the beginning of the campaign. Despite these factors, Ford rallied until the mother of all debate gaffes stifled his momentum, and he barely lost the popular and electoral vote to his Democratic challenger, Jimmy Carter. Panel 3 in Figure 2, showing the overall relationship between turnout and outcome in 1976, is a little flatter than the curve for 1964, but the closeness of the actual election meant that the effects were substantively important. As in 1964, as simulated turnout increases above the actual turnout rate, support for the Democratic presidential candidate slowly increases. If turnout was 25 points higher than actual, we estimate that Carter’s margin of victory would have jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1265 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1265 TABLE 6 Partisan Composition and Partisan Voting Behavior in 1976 Simulated Turnout 9.6 19.7 29.8 70.7 80.3 90.1 100 Partisan Self-Identification Among Voters at Varying Levels of Turnout Strong Democrat 14.4 15.7 16.5 17.2 16.1 16.3 16.2 Weak Democrat 12.9 16.1 18.3 20.3 22.2 22.1 22.5 Lean Democrat 9.4 10.0 10.1 10.3 10.9 10.8 11.2 Independent 3.3 4.2 6.0 8.1 10.5 10.9 11.5 Lean Republican 14.5 14.7 14.1 12.5 11.3 10.9 11.0 Weak Republican 15.6 17.6 16.6 16.1 15.8 16.1 16.0 Strong Republican 30.0 21.7 18.5 15.5 13.2 12.9 11.7 16.0 23.5 11.3 12.1 10.7 15.7 10.7 15.4 24.7 11.7 13.0 10.4 15.1 9.8 14.8 25.2 11.9 14.3 10.3 14.4 9.0 Democratic Tilt (%Dem–%Rep) Including Lean -23.4 -12.2 Without Lean -18.3 -7.5 -4.3 -.3 40.3 60.8 8.8 9.2 9.2 9.4 11.1 10.9 13.9 13.2 16.5 15.3 18.2 16.6 Partisanship and Vote Choice at Varying Levels of Turnout Democrats loyal 29.7 34.0 35.8 37.7 38.4 Democrats defect 6.9 7.8 9.0 10.1 10.8 Indep. Voting Democratic 1.5 2.2 2.9 3.4 4.4 Indep. Voting Republican 1.8 2.0 3.1 4.7 6.1 Republicans defect 4.7 5.3 5.4 5.5 5.8 Republicans loyal 55.4 48.6 43.8 38.6 34.5 38.7 10.5 4.3 6.6 5.6 34.4 39.2 10.6 4.6 6.9 5.4 33.3 39.9 11.0 4.9 7.2 5.3 31.7 40.3 11.4 5.5 7.5 5.4 29.8 40.4 11.5 6.4 7.9 5.6 28.2 Percent of Partisans Defecting Dem. Defection Rate 18.9 Rep. Defection Rate 7.7 21.3 14.0 21.2 14.0 21.6 14.4 22.0 15.4 22.2 16.5 18.6 9.9 20.1 10.9 3.7 5.9 50.8 21.2 12.4 22.0 14.5 increased by 1 percentage point. Lower levels of turnout would have benefited President Ford, as we estimate that Carter would have lost his 1.1 percent margin of victory if turnout had been only 5.3 points lower, and a 20-point reduction in turnout would have lowered Carter’s share of the two-party vote by just over four percentage points. Over the 40-point range of simulated turnout from 40.2% to 80.3%, the spread of support for the Democratic candidate is 3.6 points. That effect is slightly less than 1964, but politically significant because of the closeness of the actual outcome. The compositional analysis in Table 5 presents much the same story as in 1964. Under the assumptions of our simulation, the effects of turnout on Carter’s increasing advantage stems from the increasingly Democratic partisan tilt in the electorate under higher turnout scenarios, and even more so, an increasingly Republican tilt under conditions of lower turnout. Among actual voters in 1976, self-identified Democrats outnumbered Republicans by 8.8 percentage points. That advantage increases to 16.5 percentage points at a 90.1% turnout rate, and it decreases to 3.7 percentage points at a 50.3% turnout rate. Also as in 1964, the Democratic defection rate moves hardly at all with simulated turnout. As turnout increases above the actual rate, both Democrats and P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1266 1266 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill Republicans initially become slightly more loyal, followed by an increase in the defection rate for both at very high levels of turnout. At lower levels of turnout, defections by Democrats decrease slightly, and as in 1964, core Republicans become remarkably loyal. Our simulations of the 1976 election provide no support for the DeNardo hypothesis that higher levels of turnout should be associated with greater defections among the majority party. Score another for the conventional wisdom. 1984: Rise of the Reagan Democrats In the 20 years after Johnson’s landslide victory, the electorate changed in two significant ways. First, widespread perceptions of Carter’s failures and a resurgent America under the leadership of a popular Republican president, combined with the sense that both parties were losing relevance in the political system, resulted in an electorate that was much less Democratic and more Independent (Craig 1985; Wattenberg 1986). Second, and relatedly, the electorate shrank as a percentage of those who were eligible to cast ballots. In 1964, 62.8% of the eligible population turned out, but in 1984, only 57.2% of eligible Americans voted in the Presidential election (McDonald and Popkin 2001, 966).10 Following the conventional wisdom, one might naturally wonder whether (or how much) the decline in turnout contributed to Reagan’s landslide reelection. Not much, according to our analysis. Panel 4 of Figure 2 is much flatter than the corresponding figures for 1964 and 1976. Mondale, the Democratic challenger, had the support of only 41.4% of the electorate at the baseline turnout rate of 63.2%. Increasing turnout 20 points (to 83.2%) nudges Mondale’s vote share up only a little more than one-half percentage point, to 42.0%. Mondale’s support continues to increase as turnout increases, but the rate of growth is glacial. Lower turnout in 1984 would have increased Reagan’s advantage over Mondale somewhat more. If turnout had been 20 points lower, we estimate that Mondale’s vote share would have declined about three points (from 41.4% to 38.4%). Over the 40-point range (20 points above and below the actual turnout rate), the spread of support for Mondale is 3.66 percentage points, a significant reduction from the 4.47 point spread in 1976 and the 5.28 point spread from 1964. While the direction of the effect of turnout on the partisan vote distribution in 1984 is in line with conventional wisdom, the association is weak, to put it mildly. Table 7 shows that, as in 1964, higher turnout is associated with increasing Democratic partisanship in the electorate. At the baseline turnout rate of 63.2%, the Democrats held a 4.7 point advantage over Republicans in the electorate. The tilt becomes more Democratic as turnout increases (up to a 7.8 point advantage at a turnout rate of 83.2%). Even more impressively, the tilt becomes Republican P 10 Only a quarter of the drop in turnout between 1964 and 1984 was attributable to the relaxation of the suffrage requirements in the 26th Amendment (McDonald and Popkin 2001, 967). jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1267 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1267 TABLE 7 Partisan Composition and Partisan Voting Behavior in 1984 Simulated Turnout 12.7 25.3 37.9 78.0 85.3 92.7 100 Partisan Self-Identification Among Voters at Varying Levels of Turnout Strong Democrat 29.7 26.9 24.5 23.1 21.3 21.3 21.2 Weak Democrat 4.1 7.5 10.5 14.3 17.9 18.1 18.7 Lean Democrat 4.8 5.8 6.9 7.8 8.6 8.7 8.7 Independent 3.5 3.7 4.4 4.4 5.0 4.7 5.0 Lean Republican 7.9 10.7 11.4 12.2 12.8 12.9 13.2 Weak Republican 15.3 15.3 16.4 16.2 15.9 16.2 16.1 Strong Republican 34.7 30.2 25.9 22.0 18.5 18.1 17.2 20.3 20.1 8.9 5.4 13.3 15.8 16.3 19.3 21.4 9.4 5.6 13.3 15.5 15.5 18.3 21.9 9.9 6.2 13.7 15.3 14.7 Democratic Tilt (%Dem–%Rep) Including Lean -19.3 -16.1 -11.8 Without Lean -16.2 -11.2 -7.3 50.6 -5.2 -0.8 63.2 70.6 .5 4.7 .8 5.1 2.1 6.6 4.0 8.3 5.9 9.8 6.5 10.2 Partisanship and Vote Choice at Varying Levels of Turnout Democrats loyal 35.6 35.2 35.7 37.1 37.9 Democrats defect 3.0 4.9 6.3 8.1 9.9 Indep. Voting Democratic .2 .5 .8 1.0 1.3 Indep. Voting Republican 3.3 3.2 3.6 3.4 3.7 Republicans defect .9 1.2 1.3 1.9 2.3 Republicans loyal 57.0 55.1 52.4 48.5 45.0 38.1 10.0 1.1 3.5 2.3 45.0 38.4 10.2 1.2 3.7 2.3 44.2 38.5 10.8 1.3 4.0 2.2 43.1 39.0 11.1 1.4 4.2 2.3 41.9 38.7 11.5 1.8 4.4 2.9 40.7 Percent of Partisans Defecting Dem. Defection Rate 7.8 Rep. Defection Rate 1.5 20.7 4.8 20.9 4.8 21.8 5.0 22.2 5.3 22.9 6.7 12.3 2.0 14.9 2.4 17.9 3.7 20.7 4.9 as turnout decreases from the baseline (yielding a GOP advantage of 4.6 points at a turnout rate of 43.2%). But even the small advantage that Democrats might hope to have gained from the changing partisan character of the electorate is minimized by defections. At the baseline turnout rate, one-fifth of Democrats defected to Reagan, and as Democrats came into the electorate at higher levels of turnout, they were increasingly disproportionately Reagan Democrats. That, of course, is the basic Catch22 of DeNardo’s model: higher turnout means that more Democrats might come into the electorate than Republicans, but those who do would be more likely to defect. Higher turnout also promotes greater participation by the few “Mondale Republicans” in the public, so the net effect of higher turnout on the vote is faintly pro-Democratic. Overall, the relatively flat line points to a weakening of the conventional wisdom. 2000: The Perfect, and Almost Perfectly Stubborn, Tie The extraordinarily close elections for the Presidency and control of both Houses of Congress in 2000 brought 55.6% of the voter-eligible population to P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1268 1268 P Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill the polls. That figure was a return to post-26th Amendment normalcy, following the rather stunning increase in turnout in 1992 and, for many, an alarming decline in 1996. Even very small partisan effects of turnout might have had important consequences, given the closeness of the presidential election nationally and in the pivotal state of Florida. For the Republicans, a slightly larger share of the twoparty vote might have averted a constitutional crisis and lingering questions of President Bush’s legitimacy in the minds of some people, as well as preserved control of the Senate in spite of Senator Jeffords’s switch in May 2001. For the Democrats, a slightly larger share of the two-party vote might have given them unified (but razor-thin) control of the executive and legislative branches. The final panel of Figure 2 shows another remarkably flat relationship: turnout had only the slightest effect on the two-party race for the presidency. Gore does ever so slightly better with higher levels of turnout. If turnout was five points higher, at the 1992 level, we estimate that Gore’s share would have improved only a scant .04% (from 52.47% to 52.51%), and had it been 20 points higher, Gore’s share of the vote would have increased only .31%. If turnout had been eight points lower, we estimate that Gore’s share of the vote would have declined .73% (from 52.47% to 51.74%), and had it been 20 points lower, it would have declined only .51%. In general, the relationship between turnout and the Democratic share of the vote in 2000 is positively sloped, but it is very weak and nonmonotonic. Gore’s high point is at 81.8% turnout, and his low point is at 20% turnout. But the range of possible Gore two-party shares of the vote across our simulation of 20 levels of turnout is only 4.27%. Within the 40-point range (20 points above and below the actual turnout level), Gore’s share of the vote varies only from 52.0% to 52.8%. Table 8 shows that the weak relationship results from the refrain of 1984: higher turnout brings out more Democrats, but they defect at higher rates. Whether or not leaners are counted as partisans, the Democratic partisan advantage generally increases with higher simulated levels of turnout. Above the 71.3% baseline turnout, the Democratic advantage in the electorate steadily increases, and below that baseline, it fades fairly quickly. At the lowest simulated turnout levels, the Republicans enjoy a slight partisan advantage. However, as DeNardo predicted, defections undercut the small compositional advantage that Democrats enjoy from higher levels of turnout. At very low levels of turnout, about 5% of Republicans defect and the Republican defection rate doubles at the highest simulated level of turnout. Among Democrats, the defection-turnout slope is even steeper. At low levels of turnout, Democrats are remarkably loyal, but Democrats who enter the electorate at high levels of turnout defected to Bush at an even higher rate than peripheral Republicans defected to Gore. A comparison of the baseline turnout rate of 71.3% to the 81.8% in the second section of Table 8 illustrates the Democrats’ dilemma. Over this interval, a greater number of Democrats come into the electorate than do Republicans, increasing the overall Democratic tilt by 1.6%. But 15% of these “peripheral” Democrats defect to Bush, increasing the overall Democratic defection rate .8%. jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1269 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1269 TABLE 8 Partisan Composition and Partisan Voting Behavior in 2000 Simulated Turnout 12.9 81.8 87.6 93.5 100 Partisan Self-Identification Among Voters at Varying Levels of Turnout Strong Democrat 30.1 26.1 24.9 24.1 22.1 22.1 21.7 Weak Democrat 10.5 12.2 14.1 15.3 15.5 15.5 16.1 Lean Democrat 7.6 8.0 9.2 11.6 12.8 13.2 13.2 Independent .6 1.4 3.3 4.8 7.3 7.1 7.6 Lean Republican 9.5 12.4 13.0 12.0 12.9 12.8 12.9 Weak Republican 12.0 10.7 10.8 11.6 12.3 12.2 12.2 Strong Republican 29.7 29.2 24.7 20.5 17.2 17.1 16.2 20.8 16.4 13.4 8.3 13.1 12.7 15.2 20.4 16.2 13.9 9.3 13.1 12.7 14.4 19.5 15.7 14.8 11.1 13.1 12.3 13.5 Democratic Tilt (%Dem–%Rep) Including Lean -3.0 Without Lean -1.1 26.4 -5.9 -1.6 40.2 -.3 3.5 54.9 76.3 8.0 8.1 8.6 8.3 9.6 9.3 9.5 9.2 10.4 9.6 11.1 9.5 Partisanship and Vote Choice at Varying Levels of Turnout Democrats loyal 47.3 45.1 46.1 47.2 45.0 Democrats defect .9 1.3 2.1 3.9 5.4 Indep. Voting Democratic .5 1.0 1.7 2.2 3.3 Indep. Voting Republican .1 .4 1.7 2.7 3.9 Republicans defect 2.8 2.7 2.9 3.2 4.2 Republicans loyal 48.3 49.5 45.6 40.9 38.2 45.1 5.6 3.3 3.8 4.1 38.1 45.2 5.8 3.6 4.0 4.1 37.3 44.4 6.2 4.0 4.3 4.3 36.8 43.9 6.6 4.4 4.9 4.4 35.8 42.8 7.2 5.3 5.7 4.4 34.6 Percent of Partisans Defecting Dem. Defection Rate 1.9 Rep. Defection Rate 5.6 11.1 9.6 11.4 9.8 12.2 10.4 13.1 10.9 14.4 11.2 2.8 5.2 4.3 5.9 7.0 7.3 71.3 7.6 7.3 10.6 9.8 By comparison, 10% of the “peripheral” Republicans defect to Gore, resulting in no effect on the overall Republican defection rate. The net result is that Gore’s share of partisans’ votes over this interval changes hardly at all (from 53.0% to 53.3%). Combined with a slight tilt of “peripheral” independents to Gore, the net result is a very modest increase in his overall vote share (from 52.5% to 52.9%). By 2000, the “joke” really is on the Democrats! Discussion The relationship between turnout and partisan outcomes in the five U.S. presidential elections we observe is characterized by both regularities and change over time. As a rule, Democrats do benefit from higher turnout—and probably would have lost both the 1960 and the 1976 elections had turnout been much lower. Similarly, the Republicans benefit from low turnout, and conceivably could have lost the 2000 election legally as well as empirically with some slight and wellplaced increases in turnout. On the other hand, there is a limit to the explanatory or determinative power of turnout: no realistic shift in turnout could have cost LBJ the 1964 election, nor could any realistic shift have threatened Reagan in P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1270 1270 P Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill 1984, though in each case, alternative turnout patterns could have had significant effects on each party’s margin of victory and length of electoral coattails. Perhaps most notably, these findings suggest that the Democratic advantage from increased turnout (and the Republican vulnerability from it) has changed over time. In 1984 and 2000, Democrats’ benefits from higher turnout (and Republican benefits from lower turnout) were limited by the propensity for peripheral Democrats to defect, as DeNardo predicted. In the 2000 presidential election, the relationship between turnout and Gore’s share of the vote was very nearly flat. Gore would have benefited slightly from higher turnout and Bush would have benefited slightly from lower levels of turnout, but that the overall effects of turnout on the aggregate vote choice are pretty small. Compositional analyses of the electorates at varying levels of turnout show that Democrats do comprise a greater proportion of the electorate at higher levels of turnout, but in 2000, almost all the advantage that might have accrued to Gore was wiped out by the greater defection rates of these peripheral Democrats. Taken together, our results across these five elections provide partial support for both the conventional SES-based model and the alternative defection-based model, though neither model’s predictions are completely born out empirically. As predicted by conventional thought, we find that the electorate has a greater Democratic tilt at higher levels of turnout, although that relationship has significantly weakened over time. In 1960 and 1964, a simulated small electorate was notably Republican and a simulated large electorate was very Democratic. By 2000, the slope flattened out considerably, with the result that a small electorate would only be slightly more Republican than a large electorate. The flattening of the turnout—outcome curves, showing an erosion of support for the conventional model, corresponds to the weakening of the class-based partisan cleavages in the United States and is broadly consistent with DeNardo’s speculation and findings by Nagel and McNulty (1996) that a shrinkage of the “core” partisan electorate might weaken the overall relationship between turnout and vote choice. DeNardo (1980) apparently was more right than wrong, owing to his insights about the relationship between turnout and partisan defection rates. In general, the relationship between turnout and defection is positive for both Democrats and Republicans, but the strength of the relationship varies a great deal. Peripheral Democrats in 1964 and peripheral Republicans in 1984 were very nearly as loyal as their copartisans were, but the slightly higher defection rates among peripheral Democrats in 1984 and 2000 stymied whatever compositional advantages Democrats gleaned from higher turnout in those elections. On the other hand, we did not find support for DeNardo’s proposition that minority parties would be advantaged by low turnout. DeNardo suggested that high stimulus elections would result in more votes for minority Republicans, since a majority of defectors would be Democrats voting for Republican candidates. In our analysis, the election in which the Democrats held the strongest partisan advantage (1964) was also the one in which Democrats enjoyed the greatest advantage from high turnout. In that year, we estimate that peripheral Democrats jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1271 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1271 were as loyal as core Democrats, but peripheral Republicans were much more likely to abandon Goldwater than were core Republican voters. Thus, the alternative model proposed by DeNardo helps us to understand why Democrats are often not advantaged by high turnout, but we found no instance of Republicans being advantaged by heavy turnout when they were the minority party. While the short-term forces tend to deflect the compositional advantages Democrats would have realized from higher turnout in 1984 and 2000, the shortterm forces in 1964 reinforced those advantages by motivating a disproportionate number of Republican defections. A few caveats are in order. Obviously, partisan mobilization can matter a lot more than our results suggest. Increasing turnout among Democrats or among Republicans can dramatically alter election outcomes much more than simply making it a little easier or a little harder to vote. However, mobilization efforts by one side are often met with countermobilization efforts on the other side, as in the case of increased mobilization by Southern whites in reaction to the mobilization of blacks (see, for example, Faw and Skelton 1986, 212–15; Stanley 1986), and the effects of those efforts on the turnout rate is dependent in part on the relative ease of registration and voting. Moreover, our motivation was to develop a method to estimate the possible effect resulting from altering turnout in a single election, necessarily conditioned on the existing party and campaign strategies, and to suggest how turnout might have mattered in five elections in the United States. Obviously, conditions in other elections in other settings (including a highly energized American election) could be very different. The results provided here depend on the plausibility and fit of our multinomial logit models, including the assumption that voters and nonvoters weigh their considerations in voter preferences similarly (Gant and Lyons 1993) and that preference orders between choices are not affected by the inclusion (or elimination) of other choices. We think that this is a very reasonable model choice since the IIA condition is not important given the elections we study. Moreover, the multinomial logit estimates from these five elections did reasonably well in predicting vote choice among voters, as well as candidate preference among abstainers. As we and others (Pacek and Radcliff 1995) have suggested, the weak partyclass cleavage in the United States may make it a particularly difficult setting in which to find a significant relationship between turnout levels and partisan outcomes. Though class cleavages appear to be declining throughout western democracies (Franklin 1992), class cleavages remain strong in some old democracies (Britain and the Scandinavian countries; see Nieuwbeerta and De Graaf 1999), and are becoming significant in some new ones, such as Russia and the Czech Republic (see Evans and Whitefield 1999; Mateju, Rehakova, and Evans 1999). Those countries may be more fertile grounds for finding support for the conventional model’s predictions, though we do not yet know how much potential partisan defections may weaken that relationship, as it does in the United States. We hope that scholars of other democracies will find the methodology we propose here helpful in making that assessment. P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1272 1272 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill Acknowledgments Michael D. Martinez (communicating author), Associate Professor, Department of Political Science, University of Florida, 234 Anderson Hall, Gainesville FL 32611, [email protected], (352) 392-0262x282. Jeff Gill, Associate Professor, Department of Political Science, University of California-Davis, Department of Political Science, One Shields Avenue, Davis, CA 95616, [email protected], (530) 752-3077. We appreciate helpful comments from Larry Dodd, Jason Gainous, Jan Leighley, and Joe Stewart on earlier drafts of this paper. Manuscript submitted October 4, 2004 Final manuscript received June 9, 2005 References P Abramson, Paul R., John H. Aldrich, and David W. Rohde. 2002. Change and Continuity in the 2000 Elections. Washington: Congressional Quarterly Press. Abramson, Paul R., and William Claggett. 1984. “Race-Related Differences in Self-Reported and Validated Turnout.” Journal of Politics 46: 719–38. Bartels, Larry M. 2000. “Partisanship and voting behavior, 1952–1996” American Journal of Political Science 44: 35–50. Bernstein, Robert, Anita Chadha, and Robert Montjoy. 2001. “Overreporting voting—Why it happens and why it matters.” Public Opinion Quarterly 65: 22–44. Blais, Andre. 2000. To Vote or Not to Vote: The Merits and Limits of Rational Choice Theory. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. Bohrer, Robert E., II, Alexander C. Pacek, and Benjamin Radcliff. 2000. “Electoral Participation, Ideology, and Party Politics in Post-Communist Europe.” Journal of Politics 62: 1161–72. Campbell, Angus. 1960. “Surge and Decline: A Study of Electoral Change.” Public Opinion Quarterly 24: 397–418. Campbell, James E. 1987. “The Revised Theory of Surge and Decline.” American Journal of Political Science 31(4): 965–79. Citrin, Jack, Eric Schickler, and John Sides. 2003. “What If Everyone Voted? Simulating the Impact of Increased Turnout in Senate Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 47: 75–90. Collier, David, and Henry E. Brady. 2004. Rethinking Social Inquiry: Diverse Tools, Shared Standards. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield. Converse, Philip E., Aage R. Clausen, andWarren E. Miller. 1965. “Electoral Myth and Reality—the 1964 Election.” American Political Science Review 59: 321–36. Craig, Stephen E. 1985. “Partisanship, Independence, and No Preference—Another Look at the Measurement of Party Identification.” American Journal of Political Science 29: 274–90. Dalton, Russell J. 1996. “Political Cleavages, Issues, and Electoral Change.” In Comparing Democracies Elections and Voting in Global Perspective, ed. LeDuc, Richard G. Niemi, and Pippa Norris. Thousand Oaks, California Sage, pp. 319–42. DeNardo, James. 1980. “Turnout and the Vote: The Joke’s on the Democrats.” American Political Science Review 74: 406–20. Erikson, Robert S. 1995. “State Turnout and Presidential Voting—a Closer Look.” American Politics Quarterly 23: 387–96. jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1273 The Effects of Turnout on Partisan Outcomes 1273 Evans, Geoffrey, and StephenWhitefield. 1999. “The Emergence of Class Politics and Class Voting in Post-Communist Russia.” In The End of Class Politics? Class Voting in Comparative Context, ed. Geoffrey Evans. New York Oxford University Press, pp. 254–77. Faw, Bob, and Nancy Skelton. 1986. Thunder in America: The improbable presidential campaign of Jesse Jackson. Austin: Texas Monthly Press. Franklin, Mark N. 1992. “The Decline of Cleavage Politics.” In Electoral Change: Responsiveness to Evolving Social and Attitudinal Structures in Western Countries, ed. Mark N. Franklin, Thomas T. Mackie, and Henry Valen. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 383–405. Gant, Michael M., and William Lyons. 1993. “Democratic Theory, Nonvoting, and Public Policy: The 1972–1988 Presidential Elections.” American Politics Quarterly 21: 185–204. Gerber, Alan S., and Donald P. Green. 2000. “The Effects of Canvassing, Telephone Calls, and Direct Mail on Voter Turnout: a Field Experiment.” American Political Science Review 94: 653–63. Grofman, B., G. Owen, and C. Collet. 1999. “Rethinking the Partisan Effects of Higher Turnout: So What’s the question?” Public Choice 99: 357–76. Hetherington, Marc J. 2001. “Resurgent mass partisanship: The role of elite polarization.” American Political Science Review 95: 619–31. Jackman, Robert W. 1987. “Political Institutions and Voter Turnout in the Industrial Democracies.” American Political Science Review 81: 405–23. King, Gary, Robert O. Keohane, and Sidney Verba. 1994. Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Lacy, Dean, and Barry C. Burden. 1999. “The Vote-Stealing and Turnout Effects of Ross Perot in the 1992 U.S. Presidential Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 42: 233–55. Lazarsfeld, Paul F., Bernard Berelson, and Hazel Gaudet. 1948. The People’s Choice. New York: Columbia University Press. Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1960. Political Man: The social bases of politics. Garden City: Doubleday. Markus, Gregory B., and Philip E. Converse. 1979. “A Dynamic Simultaneous Equation of Electoral Choice.” American Political Science Review 73: 1055–70. Mateju, Petr, Blanka Rehakova, and Geoffrey Evans. 1999. “The Politics of Interests and Class Realignment in the Czech Republic, 1992–1996.” In The End of Class Politics? Class Voting in Comparative Context, ed. Geoffrey Evans. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 231–53. McDonald, Michael P., and Samuel L. Popkin. 2001. “The Myth of the Vanishing Voter.” American Political Science Review 95: 963–74. Nagel, Jack H., and John E. McNulty. 1996. “Partisan Effects of Voter Turnout in Senatorial and Gubernatorial Elections.” American Political Science Review 90: 780–93. Nagel, Jack H., and John E. McNulty. 2000. “Partisan Effects of Voter Turnout in Presidential Elections.” American Politics Quarterly 28: 408–29. Nieuwbeerta, Paul, and Nan Dirk de Graaf. 1999. “Traditional class voting in twenty postwar societies.” In The End of Class Politics? Class Voting in Comparative Context, ed. Geoffrey Evans. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 23–58. Pacek, Alexander, and Benjamin Radcliff. 1995. “The Political Economy of Competitive Elections in the Developing World.” American Journal of Political Science 39: 745–59. Pacek, Alexander, and Benjamin Radcliff. 2003. “Voter Participation and Party-group Fortunes in European Party Elections, 1979–1999: A Cross-National Analysis.” Political Research Quarterly 56: 91–6. Page, Benjamin I., and Calvin Jones. 1979. “Reciprocal Effects of Policy Preferences, Party Loyalties, and the Vote.” American Political Science Review 73: 1071–89. Przeworski, Adam, and John Sprague. 1988. Paper Stones: A History of Electoral Socialism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Rosenstone, Steven J., and John Mark Hansen. 1993. Mobilization, Participation, and Democracy in America. New York: Macmillan Publishing Company. Radcliff, Benjamin. 1994. “Turnout and the Democratic Vote.” American Politics Quarterly 22: 259–76. P jopo_359 8/10/05 7:17 PM Page 1274 1274 Michael D. Martinez and Jeff Gill Silver, Brian D, Barbara A. Anderson, and Paul R. Abramson. 1986. “Who Overreports Voting?” American Political Science Review 80: 613–24. Stanley, Harold W. 1986. “The 1984 Presidential Election in the South: Race and Realignment.” In The 1984 Presidential Election in the South: Patterns of Southern Party Politics, ed. Robert P. Steed, Laurence W. Moreland, and Tod A. Baker. New York: Praeger, pp. 303–305. Statistical Abstract of the United States. 1999. Washington: Bernan Press. Southwell, Priscilla L., and Justin I. Burchett. 2000. “The Effect of All-Mail Elections on Voter Turnout.” American Politics Quarterly 28: 72–9. Tóka, Gabor. 2000. “Turnout and Information Effects on Election Outcomes.” Presented at the Conference on Political Participation: Building a Research Agenda, Center for the Study of Democratic Politics, Princeton University. Tucker, Harvey J., Arnold Vedlitz, and James DeNardo. 1986. “Does Heavy Turnout Help Democrats in Presidential Elections?” American Political Science Review 80: 1291–304. Wattenberg, Martin P. 1986. The decline of American political parties, 1952–1984. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Wolfinger, Raymond E., and Steven Rosenstone. 1980. Who Votes. New Haven: Yale University Press. Wuffle, A., and C. Collet. 1997. “Why Democrats Shouldn’t Vote.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 9: 137–40. Michael D. Martinez ([email protected]) is associate professor of political science, University of Florida, Gainesville, FL 32611-7325. Jeff Gill ([email protected]) is associate professor of political science, University of California—Davis, Davis, CA 95616. P
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz