Compromising Liberty: Friedrich Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom in Practice Author: Chris Grocott, Lecturer in Management and Economic History, University of Leicester School of Management Corresponding Address: University of Leicester School of Management, University of Leicester, Leicester, UK, LE1 7RH Telephone: 0116 223 1779 Email: [email protected] Biographical Note: Chris Grocott is Lecturer in Management and Economic History at the University of Leicester School of Management. His research examines capitalism and capitalist political economy both historically and in the contemporary world. He retains, from his PhD studies, an interest in all aspects of Gibraltar since 1704. 1 Abstract: This paper examines a rare and unstudied piece of consultancy work undertaken in 1944 by Friedrich Hayek for the British Colonial Office and for the Government of Gibraltar. Hayek’s subsequent reports suggested the reorganisation of the state-regulated Gibraltar housing market in line with free market principles designed to relocate the colony’s working class population into neighbouring Spain. However, rather than freeing Gibraltarians from the evils of state planning, as identified in The Road to Serfdom (also 1944), this proposal would have delivered them into the dictatorship of General Franco. Not only was Franco’s regime brutal, but also it practiced autarkic economic policies virtually identical to those which Hayek maligned in The Road to Serfdom. In sum, Hayek’s proposals would have benefited Gibraltar’s landlords at the expense of the liberty of the majority of the civilian population. Keywords: Hayek, The Road to Serfdom, Neoliberalism, Liberty, Gibraltar, Spain. 2 Introduction Friedrich Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom was one of the most influential works of political economy produced in the twentieth century. Written during the Second World War and published in 1944, Hayek outlined the view that no matter how well intentioned economic planners might be, the result of their efforts would be totalitarian government (Hayek, 1962, p. 23). For Hayek moral government was government based upon liberal economic policies. At a time when post-war reconstruction was foremost on the minds of European states, The Road to Serfdom sought to set-out how in practice liberty might be achieved and how totalitarianism could be avoided. As a practical document, targeted at politicians, bureaucrats and the public in general, The Road to Serfdom differed somewhat to Hayek’s later work The Constitution of Liberty (Hayek, 1960), which advanced his political-philosophy rather than specific policy tools for obtaining, and sustaining, liberty. In the decades following the publication of The Road to Serfdom, neoliberal political economists built upon Hayek’s advocacy of liberal economic policies which, he argued, were politically consistent with, and indeed a requirement for, personal liberty. From the 1960s onwards, Hayek’s manifesto in The Road to Serfdom helped to justify the globally issued neoliberal economic policy prescriptions of, amongst others, Milton Friedman and members of the Chicago School of Economics. In the long-run, therefore, Hayek’s work played a substantial part in justifying the dismantlement of the post-Second World War social democracies of North West Europe and of the developmental economies of Latin America. Given the influential role that Hayek’s work played in the late twentieth century shift to neoliberal economic policies, it is unsurprising that Hayek was Margaret Thatcher’s favourite political economist. Moreover, the popularity of Hayek’s ideas amongst the right brought him numerous and prestigious awards. In 1971, he received a Nobel Prize; in 1984, in Britain, he was admitted to the Order of the Companions of Honour; 1 and in 1991 he was awarded the US Presidential Medal of Freedom. However, despite Hayek’s immediate and lasting popularity and the usefulness of his ideas to policy makers, after 1931 and his arrival at the London School of Economics, Hayek preferred the role of theorist, rather than of practitioner. Hayek felt that his contribution to society should be advancing the cause of liberal economics in intellectual debates about capitalism. Within these on-going debates Hayek argued for the implementation of liberal economic policies, just as he had in The Road to Serfdom (1962 [1944]). Indeed, only four years later in 1948, in order to further his position within this debate, Hayek acted as the main driving force behind the establishment of the Mont Pèlerin society. The society brought together academics, business leaders, and politicians to campaign for the implementation of liberal economic policies. But, nevertheless, Hayek asserted ‘…a theory that all economists that serve in government are corrupted as a result of serving in government’ (Hayek, Kresge, Wenar, 1994, p. 82). Because of this, it has been difficult for scholars to discern whether or not Hayek was committed in practice to the implementation of the policies he laid down in theory in The Road to Serfdom. In Britain during the Second World War, Hayek was not given war work because he was born in Austria, and after he moved to the United States in 1950, he showed little interest in developing his theoretical insights through practical application. Up to now, therefore, it has not been known how Hayek would have recommended implementing his ideas; whether or not he would have remained true to them in practice; or what the outcome of Hayek’s efforts might have been. Yet despite Hayek maintaining the view that working for government was corruptive, in 1944 he did nevertheless undertake some such work. After completing The Road to Serfdom, in March 1944, but prior to going to the United States in April 1945 to undertake a lecture tour to publicise his ideas, Hayek was engaged by the British Colonial Office 2 and the Government of Gibraltar to write a set of reports and proposals relating to the Rock’s post-war economic development. In later years, Hayek dismissed the importance of a reading of his work on Gibraltar to an understanding of his political economy. In Hayek on Hayek, for example, following a conversation about Keynes and Robbins in which he condemned both for being statesmen rather the economists, Hayek closed down a discussion of his time on the Rock. He stated that he had accepted his commission in Gibraltar simply so that he could go overseas during the long vacation, ‘so I went for six weeks to Gibraltar, which was extraordinary – again, don’t tempt me to tell you anecdotes about this, it would be endless’ (Hayek, et al, 1994, p. 83). Yet Hayek’s reports on Gibraltar do deserve attention. Written in the months following his completion of The Road to Serfdom, the proposals contained in his Gibraltar reports provokes a reassessment of Hayek’s conception of liberty. Specifically, the reports reveal an early tension between his treatment of economic liberty and personal freedom, two concepts which Hayek often uses inter-changeably but which, in his Gibraltar reports, are clearly treated separately. As will be seen, one of Hayek’s proposals in his Gibraltar report was that market forces should be applied to the state-regulated, and rent restricted, housing market in Gibraltar so that the invisible hand of the market would deliver Gibraltar’s working class population from residence in Gibraltar across the frontier and into Spain. He argued that this mechanism would remove people from a relatively high cost of living economy in Gibraltar, to a relatively low cost of living economy in the neighbouring city of La Línea. At the same time, the unfettering of the market would allow rents to increase in Gibraltar to the benefit of landlords. The use of market forces to improve living standards was, of course, consistent with Hayek’s beliefs as stated in The Road to Serfdom. Consistent too was the apparent ease that Hayek felt towards the Spanish state being a dictatorship from 1939. 3 What cannot be considered consistent with the ideas of The Road to Serfdom was that the consequence of Hayek’s proposals would have been to relocate Gibraltar’s working class population into a Spanish economy that was organised around the economic principles of autarky. In short, Hayek’s commitment to the establishment of free markets went so far as to allow landlords in Gibraltar to enjoy higher rents but not so far as to protect the Rock’s working class population from an economic system which he himself had argued was tyrannical in The Road to Serfdom. What Hayek attempted to implement in Gibraltar was a small-scale embryonic-neoliberal experiment. But in the attempt, he was forced to contradict his writing on liberty, calling into question the extent to which Hayek prized this above his commitment to free markets. Hayek’s consultancy work in Gibraltar, and on its economy, has received minimal attention from academics. Neither scholars of Hayek’s political economy nor historians of Gibraltar have considered Hayek’s report in any depth. 1 Nevertheless, for such scholars and, equally, for those interested more broadly in the development of political economy in the latter half of the twentieth century, and in particularly of neoliberalism, Hayek’s reports on Gibraltar are significant because they cast a shadow on his commitment to liberty as expressed in The Road to Serfdom. Such an examination is timely for at least two reasons. First, there has been a recent upsurge in interest in lesser-known aspects of Hayek’s work (Spieker, 2013), whilst Hayek’s views on planning (O’Neill 2003; Cumbers and McMaster 2010; Dean 2010) remain of interest to those studying the role of the state in the economy. Second, disruption of the flow of traffic over the Gibraltar frontier, beginning at the end of July 2013 reminds us of the importance of the frontier relationship for the Gibraltar economy. 2 In order to examine just how closely Hayek’s prescriptions for Gibraltar match his ideas in The Road to Serfdom, this article brings together research undertaken in, as 4 well as hitherto unused material from, The National Archives/Public Record Office in London, the Gibraltar Government Archives in Gibraltar, and the Hoover Institution Archive in California (where Hayek’s papers are stored). Using these materials, first the background to Hayek’s visit is outlined; second, Hayek’s analysis of the Rock’s economy and some of his more modest proposals, are examined; third, his significant liberal economic proposals are examined and the implications of Hayek’s proposals for our understanding of his political economy are considered; and finally, we see the reasons why Hayek’s proposals were rejected by the Colonial Office and the Government of Gibraltar. Hayek Visits Gibraltar That Hayek was engaged to undertake his work on Gibraltar was something of a fluke. In the summer of 1944, the Colonial Office wrote to Hayek, then at Peterhouse, Cambridge, where the LSE had been evacuated to from London, to enquire if he had a suitable doctoral candidate available to prepare a cost of living index for Gibraltar. Hayek responded to say that he had no such person available because all of his postgraduates had joined the forces or were engaged in other war work, and he offered to go to Gibraltar and complete the task himself. Delighted at the prospect of engaging a senior academic economist, the Government of Gibraltar asked Hayek if he would consider broadening out his brief to include an investigation into the future organisation of the Rock’s economy. Hayek agreed, and visited Gibraltar to this end between 14 August 1944 and 27 September 1944. 3 Conditions in wartime Gibraltar, as Hayek would have found them, were very different to those that had prevailed in the 1930s. With the exception of adult males of working age (of which there were around 4,000), the most obvious difference was that the civilian population of Gibraltar, which had stood at around 18,000 people, had been evacuated in 1940. 4 In place of the civilians, there was an influx of service personnel. In peacetime, the naval and military forces in Gibraltar, including families, 5 numbered around 4,000 people (Constantine, 2009, p. 233). By July 1944, however, there were a total of 15,801 men from the army, navy and RAF on the Rock. 5 This figure was augmented at various points during the war. On a regular basis convoys would visit Gibraltar, whilst between 1940-1 an aircraft carrier fleet, Force H, operated from the Rock’s dockyard. When in port, the crews of its two battleships, a battle cruiser, two cruisers, eleven destroyers and the aircraft carrier Ark Royal, bolstered the number of people resident on the Rock considerably. Later, in 1942, Gibraltar positively groaned under the weight of the invasion force that rallied there just prior to the allied invasion of North Africa. The considerable increase in service personnel in Gibraltar brought with it a great number of economic opportunities. For Gibraltar’s merchants, supplying the garrison and victualling ships was a profitable trade. For the working class population, providing the labour for this trade meant that the hard times of the 1930s were replaced with full employment. Even for those living in Gibraltar’s hinterland, the Campo de Gibraltar (known locally simply as ‘the campo’), opportunities flourished. Gibraltar’s economy had relied upon Spanish labour crossing the frontier from at least the 1890s, and the average number of workers making the daily commute increased from 6,633 in 1939 to 7,800 in 1944 (Stockey, 2009). Despite these opportunities for work, the considerable increase in the number of transient workers in Gibraltar created a number of problems. First and foremost, they needed to be housed. The vast majority of the population of Gibraltar rented its accommodation. Now vacated, these dwellings were turned over to the military, whilst rents were restricted by ordinance (Gibraltar’s equivalent of legislative acts) in order to prevent racketeering. Much of this housing was little better than slum housing, the upkeep of which had been in the hands of private landlords with little direction from government as to how it should be improved. Over fifty per cent of it had been overcrowded before the war, and it was mostly poorly treated by the 6 servicemen who occupied it. Moreover, the war had forced up the prices of goods and services in Gibraltar, not least of all because of the various global scarcities created by the conflict. For the Government of Gibraltar, issues of rents, housing stock, wages, and prices were central to its policymaking towards post-war economic reconstruction. Accurate information was vital to this planning and, after all, this is why they had engaged Hayek’s services in the first place. Prior to Hayek’s cost of living index of 1944, the last time a survey of the Rock’s economy had been undertaken was 1939. Circumstances had changed considerably in the five intervening years. By 1943, officials in Gibraltar estimated that in the post-war era accommodation would be required for a population of around 24,000 people (Constantine, 2009, p. 353). Gibraltar’s Governor, Lieutenant-General Sir Ralph Eastwood, and its Colonial Secretary, Miles Clifford agreed that conditions were utterly unacceptable. 6 In early 1944 they formed a Re-housing and Town Planning Board to oversee the planning of the redevelopment of Gibraltar’s housing stock (Constantine, p. 354). Whilst the housing situation in Gibraltar required new directions in government policy, another factor of the Rock’s economy remained consistent with pre-war conditions – the state was both the largest employer and the main source of the colony’s wealth. Given the small size of Gibraltar (around two and a half square miles) and its unsuitability for agriculture, the Rock relied upon the import-export trade both to sustain itself and as a source of income. This trade was facilitated by the colony’s free port status (though despite the name some very low taxes were levied on a small number of goods), and its rewards were undiminished by income tax. For the Rock’s merchants the main two markets were the military and navy in the colony, both garrisoned and transitory, as well as smugglers looking to illegally take goods such as tobacco from relatively low-tax Gibraltar into relatively high-tax Spain. A sizeable minority of Gibraltar’s population was involved in the private import-export 7 trade in jobs ranging from coalheaver, whose job it was to carry coal from stationary hulks to ships out in the bay, through to clerical worker in the shops and warehouses of the merchants themselves. But it was the state that employed the majority of workers in Gibraltar. And of those employed by government, it was the Admiralty who employed the majority of these workers in the naval dockyard, whilst a smaller group worked for the Government of Gibraltar as part of the City Council’s staff. Such was the situation that Hayek found in August and September 1944. In short, Gibraltar’s economy was directly dependent upon the presence of the British on the Rock; the government was the major employer; and the colony’s authorities were already engaged in a process of planning its post-war housing and economic development. Hayek liked none if it. Hayek’s Reports and Preliminary Proposals Hayek produced four reports whilst in Gibraltar. The first, completed on 8 September 1944, was a proposal that a detailed statistical analysis be carried out immediately in order to gain a full picture both of the population of Gibraltar and of those Gibraltarians who had been evacuated. The second report, completed on 20 September 1944, was the Gibraltar cost of living index that he had originally been asked to complete. A few days later, on 24 September 1944, Hayek completed a wages and salaries report. These were largely anodyne and statistical in nature. When he returned home, Hayek set about writing the more substantial ‘Report on Some Economic Problems in Gibraltar’, which he completed in October. It was this report that contained his proposals for a reorganisation of the Gibraltar economy upon liberal economic lines. To produce the above reports, Hayek consulted a substantial amount of statistical data and qualitative material in Gibraltar. For population statistics, Hayek used the 1931 census and reports on births and deaths collected by the local Police; the Roman Catholic Bishop provided figures relating to marriages (with the overwhelming 8 majority of the population being Roman Catholics, this would have been a very significant sample); whilst the colonial secretariat provided information about rates, death duties, repatriation priorities, and a companies register. The secretariat also provided information about wages in, and the establishment of, the colonial government, dockyard, city council, the war department and the top 15 firms in Gibraltar. Hayek also consulted a 1938 report on overcrowding produced by Major R. A. Mansell, the Medical Officer of Health; a 1943 report on trade unions and labour in Gibraltar produced by Major Granville St. John Orde Browne, the labour advisor to the Secretary of State for the Colonies; and a 1943 report on labour unrest in Malta produced by an advisor at the Colonial Office, Mr. MacLeod. All three of these reports proceeded from the presumption that it was the state’s role to help plan colonial economies and, as we shall see, Hayek took issue with them. 7 In addition to the materials made available to him by the colonial government in Gibraltar, Hayek also went about the Rock interviewing people on topics of interest to him. He met, for example, with representatives of the Association for the Advancement of Civil Rights (AACR). This group was formed in 1942 to press for the swift return of the evacuees from Gibraltar. In a short space of time, it established itself as a respectable political force in the colony under the leadership of local lawyer Joshua Hassan. In addition to containing a number of local notables, the AACR was also associated with a number of trade union organisers, giving it a broad representative voice (Grocott & Stockey, 2012, pp. 70-4). It was because of the AACR’s interest in labour issues that Hayek met with its representatives during his time in Gibraltar. Hayek also went about the dockyard and made an effort to talk to ordinary dockworkers in order to gauge employees’ feelings towards their wages and conditions in the dockyard. So thorough was Hayek’s investigation that, in order to discover if there was likely to be a reduction in the birth rate after the war, he even went from chemist to chemist to enquire if the use of condoms had been increasing in recent years (he was assured that, in Roman Catholic Gibraltar, it had not). 8 9 The results of Hayek’s analysis of the Rock’s economy can be broken down into three strands. First, Hayek was not convinced that the Government of Gibraltar was making its decisions based on solid demographic data. Second, he felt that a solution to the housing problem in Gibraltar also had to speak to problems of the declining real terms value of wages and the increasing cost of living. Third, he was deeply unhappy at the role the Admiralty played in the Gibraltar labour market and in particular, as he saw it, the injustice brought about by importing skilled labour from Britain, rather than training up workers in Gibraltar. In his 8 September 1944 report on the issue of population statistics, Hayek argued that the census taken in 1931 was scant in detail and that its results could not be reconciled with the Police statistics on deaths and marriages. 9 Hayek proposed making use of the materials gathered during the evacuation, which gave extensive details of households and individuals, combined with some supplementary forms of data, to produce a detailed survey of the population. Hayek outlined that this data could be transferred onto punch cards that could be read by a machine so that the information could then be sorted and tabulated to suit the government’s needs. In order to undertake this, Hayek recommended that technicians and two card-punching machines be sent from Britain as soon as possible. As we shall see, Hayek’s proposal to conduct a statistical survey was separate to his ideas on the Gibraltar economy. Nevertheless, his understanding of the situation, and his proposals, were criticised by officials at the Colonial Office. In his analysis of the economy, which underpinned his proposals in ‘Some Economic Problems in Gibraltar’, Hayek identified that Gibraltar exerted significant influence on the surrounding Campo. For Hayek, Gibraltar formed ‘the commercial centre of an urban conglomeration of nearly 100,000 inhabitants, whose working class suburbs are located in Spain’. 10 Rather than seeing Gibraltar as solely comprising the area 10 within the boundaries of the colony itself, Hayek re-imagined the scale of the Rock’s limits by including the surrounding Spanish hinterland. By doing this, Hayek was able to begin to think of some radical solutions to the Gibraltar economy’s problems, as he saw them, which others had been unable to do. Hayek pointed out in his report that, until the outbreak of the Spanish Civil War in 1936 the relationship between Gibraltar and its hinterland had been a cordial one. Nevertheless, the Civil War had prompted hundreds of Gibraltarians living in the Campo to flee to the Rock to escape the fighting and possible persecution from either those forces fighting for the Republic or for the Nationalists. Many of these refuges held left-wing political beliefs and they were reluctant to return to the Campo when Nationalist forces quickly overran the area in the first weeks of the Civil War. They then found themselves permanently unable to return to Spain when the Civil War ended in a Nationalist victory in April 1939. Hayek also noted that many of the Rock’s wealthy inhabitants still maintained second homes in the Campo. Gibraltar’s wealthy inhabitants were welcome in Spain because they had, almost unanimously, supported the Nationalists during the Civil War. As we shall see, from this analysis Hayek’s thinking was moving towards the idea that in peacetime some of the Gibraltarian population in Gibraltar might be induced to live in the Campo. In addition to the labour provided in Gibraltar by those who lived on the Rock and by Gibraltarians in the Campo, such was the need for hands that a substantial number of Spaniards made the daily commute across the frontier in search of work. Indeed, this abundance of work; the relatively higher pay that could be obtained in comparison to wages in Spain (even though Spaniards were paid less than either British or Gibraltarian workers); and the opportunity to boost income by smuggling goods back across the frontier from Gibraltar into Spain, all made working on the Rock a tempting prospect. In peacetime around half of those entering from Spain were women working in domestic service (either for the families of the military or for 11 Gibraltar’s well-to-do). The rest, more often than not, were men working in private employment either in the commercial dockyard or for wholesalers (Stockey, 2009). In contrast to the private sector, most of the work for the City Council was reserved for Gibraltarians. And in the admiralty-controlled dockyard, the authorities were sure to fill up places with Gibraltarians before taking on Spaniards. In part, this was a security precaution (indeed two Spaniards working in the admiralty-controlled portion of the dockyard attempted to plant a bomb in 1943), and in part, this was an attempt to ensure that sufficient employment was available for Gibraltarians. In addition to steering Gibraltarians into the more stable jobs, the existence of a substantial state sector in Gibraltar had an effect on wages. Because the cost of living in Gibraltar was more expensive than in Spain, the wages of Gibraltarians needed to be higher than those offered to Spaniards. The effect of the Government of Gibraltar and of the admiralty paying Gibraltarians enhanced pay in the public sector was that this had to be replicated, at least to some degree, in the private sector if employers wished to have any hope of attracting capable employees. Despite the employment created by war, Hayek was concerned that Gibraltar’s heavy reliance on the state sector for its economic prosperity would not translate into the post-war world. He estimated that at the time of the 1931 census, 51.7% of the population worked for the government in one form or another. 11 He was of the opinion that when the war ended, the reduction in the number of service personnel based in Gibraltar would mean that there would not be enough employment on the Rock to provide for its population. In addition to issues of labour supply, Hayek also gave consideration to the colony’s wealth and to issues such as the cost of living. One of the problems facing Hayek in his analysis of the Gibraltar economy was the relative lack of taxation in the colony. Hayek had to work with the information that was available to him in September 1944. 12 Naturally, revenues from the small forms of taxation imposed in Gibraltar gave an indication as to overall economic activity. But the lack of an income tax made calculating the income of the wealthy difficult. (It was easier to work out the income of the poor because, as we have seen, over half of the workforce was employed either by the government or by the admiralty both of which published their rates of pay and the size of their workforces.) Indeed, the only way in which Hayek could even begin to estimate the wealth of Gibraltar’s entrepreneurial community was through figures relating to estate duties and even these had only been imposed since 1934 (Constantine, 2009, pp.339-343). Using information supplied by the registrar of births and deaths, as well as by the colonial secretariat, Hayek was able to establish how many of the estates left by the 733 people who had died between 1935-9 had been worth over £3,000. He then put these into four categories, those worth £3,000-£9,999; £10,000-£24,499; £25,000£99,999; and those worth more than £100,000. Extrapolating these figures and applying them to the whole colony, Hayek estimated that there were five people in Gibraltar worth more than £100,000; fifty people worth between £25,000-£99,999; 20 worth £10,000-£24,499; and 125 worth £3,000-£9,999. Hayek was informed, anonymously, that since 1939, one person had died leaving an estate valued at £1.2 million.12 In 2010’s money, using the retail price index, this amount was equivalent to around £51 million. Based on average earnings it was worth the equivalent of nearly £150 million. Even the 125 people in the lowest category were worth, at the top end, nearly £426,000 (retail price index) or £1.27 million (average earnings). As Hayek put it, ‘these are remarkably high figures for a community of this size’. He also noted that none of the property or wealth that the colony’s rich owned or held in Spain was subject to this tax. This hinted at the possibility that these people were worth substantially more than these figures suggested. 13 13 The issue at the working class end of the spectrum was not so much working out how much people earned. Rather, the question was whether or not the income of the average Gibraltarian was adequate for a decent living in the colony. One of the principal problems was the lack of affordable housing. Non-government owned properties tended to be blocks of tenements, three of four stories high and arranged in a square around a central patio containing a water pump. Because space was at a premium, rents were high. In 1938, Major Mansell had argued that this resulted in workers cramming their families into one- or two-room dwellings in order to save on rent. In support of this, Mansell noted that in 1938 51.5% of accommodation in Gibraltar was overcrowded. This represented around 1250 dwellings, of which the vast majority comprised only one or two rooms and this with an average family size of 4.1 people. 14 Major Orde Brown’s labour report of 1943 revisited this issue. He argued that whilst he had visited Gibraltarians in their homes and found the dwellings to be clean and the habits of their inhabitants ‘neat’, conditions were nevertheless so squalid as to pose a serious risk to health. 15 At the very least, Orde Brown noted, these dwellings were not likely to produce a happy workforce or contented population in Gibraltar. As Mansell had before him, Orde Brown recommended that the Government of Gibraltar bring an expert into the colony to investigate and propose ways of remedying the situation. This, then, in addition to happenstance, and more than simply Hayek’s reputation, goes some way to explaining why in 1944 the Government of Gibraltar was so keen to engage Hayek’s services. In addition to the need to collect reliable population statistics, and the need to address poor housing, declining real wages and inflation, Hayek also argued that the admiralty was acting in bad faith both as an economic force in the colony and as an employer. Hayek argued that by engaging workers locally and then topping-up the workforce by importing labour from Britain, the dockyard authorities were acting like a private monopoly when attempting to prevent local wage rates rising. Hayek condemned this as ‘exploitation’ and made it very clear that he had deliberately chosen this word to 14 describe the admiralty’s practise. 16 Hayek urged strongly that the admiralty offer sufficient wages locally to attract Gibraltarian workers into the dockyard, providing that the wages offered were less than the wages that would be offered to an imported worker from Britain. By not doing so, Hayek argued, the admiralty was conspiring to keep the Gibraltarian workforce unhappy, as well as financially worse off, because Gibraltarians were paid substantially less than their equivalents from Britain. As Hayek saw it, the main barrier to Gibraltarians reducing the wage differential between themselves and British workers was that the admiralty reserved the higher positions in the dockyard, in practice if not in theory, for imported workers from Britain. If Gibraltarians could access the more skilled jobs, or those requiring clerical or supervisory skills, then the need for imported workers would diminish. Not only would this de facto end the wages differential, but also Hayek envisaged that it would lead to an increase in wages for Gibraltarians across the board. Moreover, to offset this, as Gibraltarian workers moved to more senior positions, Spaniards could be engaged in the more unskilled work vacated by them. As the Spanish workers were paid less, this would lead to economies in the wage bill for unskilled labour. In sum, the situation that Hayek found at Gibraltar stood in sharp contrast to the ideas he set out in The Road to Serfdom. A substantial amount of the economy was under the control of the Government of Gibraltar and, so Hayek felt, the admiralty was using its significant position in the labour market to artificially distort wage levels on the Rock. Moreover, perhaps the largest and most obvious state-generated economic mechanism, the imposition of a frontier, and the creation of different wage and tax policies on either side of it, created what Hayek perceived to be an unnatural market. Indeed, Gibraltar’s economy, which relied heavily on the smuggling trade, relied on illiberal Spanish economic policies to maintain itself (Stockey, 2009). In addition, differences in the cost of living on either side of the frontier served artificially to inflate not only wages for Gibraltarians but also, to a lesser degree, for Spaniards 15 resident in La Línea (when compared to the average wage elsewhere in Andalucía). When taken as a whole, Hayek’s ‘greater Gibraltar’ was an economy in which the British imperial state forestalled the natural operation of market forces. Worse still, in its attempts to remedy the problems which Hayek believed this had caused, the Government of Gibraltar was relying on reports, such as Mansell’s report on housing, Orde Brown’s on labour, and MacLeod’s on the dockyard, that all strongly supported state planning of the Gibraltar economy, and of the labour and housing markets. In the spirit of his recently finished treatise on liberalism, Hayek setout proposals to thwart these ‘totalitarians in our midst’. 17 Proposals to Reorganise the Gibraltar Economy We have already seen Hayek’s proposals concerning collecting useful statistical data. He proposed that consultants be employed to make use of information collected as part of the evacuation process. Below we examine the ways in which Hayek proposed reforming housing and wages policy on the Rock, and his views on how the admiralty should alter its employment practices respectively. In relation to housing policy, Hayek’s proposals proceeded from a totally different understanding of the causes of poverty in Gibraltar than Mansell’s. As we have seen, Mansell argued that high rents in Gibraltar restricted Gibraltarian families to one or two room dwellings. Indeed, Mansell’s report had proved to be the final blow in the battle which had been on-going in the colony’s Executive Council over the imposition of a rent restriction ordinance. Such an ordinance had been introduced in 1920 but had been repealed in 1923. From that point onwards, the unofficial nominated members of the Executive Council (who were always drawn from the ranks of the Rock’s entrepreneurial community or else were professionals such as lawyers) fought hard to ensure that pressure from the main trade union of the inter-war years, the Transport and General Worker’s Union (a branch of the British trade union), were not acceded to. In 1938, Mansell’s report put an end to this resistance, and the governor 16 authorised the reintroduction of a rent restriction ordinance. In 1940, the Government of Gibraltar extended the provisions in the Rent Restriction Ordinance in order to ensure that no profiteering went on in regards to the rent of premises to servicemen stationed on the Rock. The principles behind rent restriction were simple. Given the small amount of space available to build on, the reluctance of Gibraltarians to live in Spain, and the size of the population, housing space was limited. Property owners had, in unregulated times, demonstrated that they were prepared to increase rents to take advantage of this scarcity. Mansell, the TGWU, and, by 1938, the Government of Gibraltar saw this situation as being exploitative and sought to restrict rents by ordinance. Hayek took completely the opposite view to that which prevailed in Gibraltar. He argued that in fact, rather than high rents forcing families into overcrowded conditions, the lowering of rents by ordinance resulted in people renting property which they would normally not be able to afford. For Hayek, then, the problem of overcrowding was created by the rent restriction ordinance. Worse still, Hayek argued, property owners were barely getting enough rent to make improving their housing stock worthwhile. This had gotten worse because of the additional rent restrictions that had been imposed since 1 May 1940, combined with the difficulties of encouraging temporary residents to maintain their dwellings. Higher rents, then, would not only compel the working class to move to more suitable accommodation but also allow for the improvement of the conditions which people like Mansell had maligned. In Hayek’s opinion, there was another compelling reason to end rent restriction. This related to the state’s role in the housing market. Hayek argued that the position landlords had been placed in amounted to the confiscation of their property without compensation, which he saw as being unjust. Moreover, he believed that in time the government would have to supplement the incomes of property owners if they were to maintain their dwellings. Ultimately, he stated, this would 17 result in the government’s necessary nationalisation of housing in Gibraltar, something which Hayek did not want to develop. Hayek’s solution to the problems of overcrowded and poor housing was a radical one. 18 He proposed not only that restrictions on rents be ended, but also that rents be allowed to rise in line with market forces to such a point at which a significant proportion of the population would relocate across the frontier to live in La Línea, where housing was cheaper. Hayek argued that there would be a significant number of benefits to this. In the first place it would mean that occupation of Gibraltar’s limited number of premises would reflect market forces and, therefore, serve the economy more efficiently. Second, the additional rents would encourage the better upkeep of properties and also encourage the building of new properties. Third, Hayek argued that the working class population that would be displaced into La Línea would have an improved lifestyle. He noted Gibraltar’s humid climate in the summer, caused occasionally when air is forced to rise when it comes into contact with the Rock itself forming a cloud (known locally as a levanter) that dominated Gibraltar but not the surrounding area. (This was one of the reasons that the wealthier inhabitants maintained summerhouses in the Campo.) Not only would those living across the frontier benefit from escaping the weather in Gibraltar, they would also have more space to live in. This would allow them to grow crops and boost their standard of living through subsistence agriculture. In addition, this ‘contact with rural life’ would be valuable in the job market. 19 Whilst living in Gibraltar, workers aspired to ‘urban occupations’, which reduced their employment prospects. 20 Once in Spain, if there was not sufficient work in Gibraltar, workers could look to the surrounding region of Andalucia for agricultural employment. Finally, by moving its unskilled working class population into Spain, the Government of Gibraltar would benefit from not having to support unproductive workers. Moreover, Hayek argued that because such people would have their link with the Rock severed they would be more likely, as we have seen, to move away from La Línea and into the surrounding region if they were 18 unemployed. In this way, the government would be exporting any potential future unemployment problems into Spain. Hayek was aware that his proposals might be met with opposition. He outlined several possible objections, namely: that the admiralty would want a supply of workers of all varieties available in Gibraltar in case of war; that it would be undesirable to encourage the British population of Gibraltar to develop Spanish habits and identities; and that in Spain British subjects would be deprived of the advantages (such as health care and education) that they had enjoyed in Gibraltar. He took care to address each of these responses. In the first instance, Hayek argued that the Gibraltarian population would not be a benefit in wartime because if the Rock were under attack its dockyard would be rendered useless. In this circumstance, the working population would represent additional mouths to feed and would not contribute to the defence of the colony. He was also of the belief that Gibraltar’s economy was so vital to that of the surrounding hinterland that the Spanish government would not shut it for ‘any great length of time’. 21 (He was, in fact, wrong – the Spanish Government closed the frontier from 1969 to 1985.) As to the issue of Gibraltarians losing their British identities, Hayek argued that the working class in Gibraltar were all-but Spanish in their habits. Whilst wages remained lower than those enjoyed by British workers, he believed that Gibraltarians would be unable to develop British tastes and identities. This then chimed with Hayek’s ideas about the admiralty, which will be addressed below. Hayek argued that if Gibraltarians had greater access to skilled work then they would become more British in character. They would also be able to afford to live in Gibraltar. The low-skilled workers left over would, by his reasoning, be all-but indistinguishable from the Spaniards they would then live alongside. At any rate Hayek saw this as being ‘in part not inevitable and in part not undesirable’. 22 Finally, in relation to Gibraltarians being deprived of the amenities available on the Rock, 19 Hayek argued that a private company could be formed, sufficiently induced by subsidies from the colonial government, to build a housing estate in La Línea for those Gibraltarians displaced by Hayek’s proposed rent policy. This company could then be required to provide amenities such as hospitals and schools. After addressing the issue of relocating the working class population of Gibraltar into Spain, Hayek turned his attentions to the admiralty’s employment practises. First of all, he proposed that no employer in Gibraltar, the admiralty included, should pay higher wages to Gibraltarian workers than to Spaniards. This was necessary for Hayek’s plan to remove people into Spain to work. Not only did the market for renting accommodation in Gibraltar need to be liberalised, but also the link between wages and the cost of living on the Rock needed to be broken in order to prevent inflation and to prevent Hayek’s plans being thwarted. Moreover, Hayek saw this as an opportunity to increase the commercial dockyard’s competitiveness against the ports of Oran and Algiers, both of which drew on cheap African labour. By reducing the wages of those in government employment, private employers too would be able to reduce their salary bills. Hayek recognised that some small benefit might be given to those workers travelling across the frontier, to compensate them for their effort, but he argued that this should not be too much more than the prevailing wage levels in the Spanish hinterland. This underscored the objective of moving people out of Gibraltar, and not attracting Spaniards to the Campo in search of work on the Rock. Hayek had another reason for recommending that wages be allowed to fall; it would give a distinct market advantage to skilled labour. Hayek argued that the British character of the Gibraltarian population would be encouraged by improved education and access to middle class occupations. He therefore encouraged a two-fold approach in which technical education would be improved and whereby Gibraltarians would gradually take positions currently given to British workers in the dockyard. Those 20 who so benefited would then be able to remain in Gibraltar itself, whilst the unskilled proportion of the population would move into Spain. Above, we have seen Hayek’s proposals on the future of Gibraltar’s economy. In particular, we have seen his ideas for liberalising the housing and labour market on the Rock by conceiving of a ‘greater’ Gibraltar into the suburbs of which he proposed that the working class population be relocated. We now consider the implications of these proposals for understanding Hayek’s political economy. Combating the ‘Totalitarians in Our Midst’ In The Road to Serfdom, Hayek argued that free markets underpin liberty within societies. However, for Hayek the liberal tradition in Britain had, since the late nineteenth century, been polluted by attempts to find a ‘middle way’ between total state direction of the economy and laissez-faire principles extolled by groups such as the Manchester School of Economics (Hayek, 1962, p.31). He laid blame at both doors. As Andrew Gamble points out, Hayek was not an ‘anarcho-capitalist’ and as such Hayek criticised those who in the nineteenth century argued that attempts should be made to remove the state from all aspects of economic life (Gamble, 1996, p.75; Hayek, 1962, p.13). Nevertheless, Hayek argued that this simple rendering of the meaning of liberalism was made necessary by the attempts of well-meaning political economists, such as John Stuart Mill, to ameliorate the worst aspects of capitalist economics through state intervention. Noble though the idea might be, Hayek argued that planning would necessarily lead to state control of the entire economy and, therefore, totalitarianism. Because of this, the state’s only duty was to provide a framework within which the free market could operate ‘naturally’. Throughout the 1930s and 1940s political economy in Britain was increasingly dominated by the belief, held by many in the establishment, that state planning of the economy was necessary. Against this, Hayek argued that it was all too easy to 21 sleepwalk into totalitarianism and that, worse still, members of the British establishment were paving the way for this journey. The Road to Serfdom was, then, a plea from Hayek to reverse this trend. It reflected the bitter disputes, both public and private, which Hayek had entered into with Keynes in the 1930s. And whilst Keynes was not directly accused in Hayek’s chapter ‘The Totalitarians in Our Midst’, E. H. Carr and others certainly were (Hayek, 1962, pp. 135-149). For Hayek, planning, socialism, and totalitarianism were parts of the same problem. IN 1944, by his way of thinking Hayek was therefore surrounded by socialists and unwitting totalitarians. Even the Bretton Woods agreements, which eventually edged the global economy closer to neoliberal political economy, would, at the time, have represented to him a potential deviation from the path of liberalism. This was because the British delegation there, led by Keynes, argued strongly for a supra-national organisation dedicated to smoothing out trade deficits and surpluses between the developed and developing world. And if the global situation looked bleak, the domestic situation looked little better. The Beveridge proposals, adopted by the British Labour Party as a blueprint for the post-war welfare state contained substantial recommendations of state planning. 23 Whilst the Conservatives did not adopt Beveridge’s proposals as wholeheartedly as the Labour Party, even the Tories under Churchill were prepared to see a move towards an expansion of the state’s role in welfare. Little wonder, then, that Hayek decided that the United States, already beginning to experience a backlash against New Deal politics, would be a better place to head, in early 1945, to publicise the ideas in The Road to Serfdom. In Hayek on Hayek, Hayek gave the impression that his trip to Gibraltar was to be partly about work and partly about relaxation. Unbeknown to him when he accepted his commission there was little about the situation on the Rock that would put his mind at rest. As we have seen, planning was being undertaken in all aspects of Gibraltar’s economy; the state was a significant economic actor because it employed 22 so many people; and the very presence of the British on the Rock created, what Hayek considered to be, a false divide between the economic centre of the region, Gibraltar, and its ‘suburb’, La Línea. Hayek saw reports such those of Mansell and of Orde Browne as beating a path to serfdom, just as he had outlined in his recently published manifesto. His proposals for the Gibraltar economy were, therefore, a direct attempt to counter this tendency. Hayek argued in The Road to Serfdom that the ‘blueprint’ by which a society could be planned-out could take two different forms (Hayek, 1962, p. 26). The first, which he rejected, was planning for state intervention in the economy. The second was the creation, by the state, of a liberal economy in which market forces could operate, hindered only by sufficient measures required for capitalism to be maintained. But whereas The Road to Serfdom made the case for producing a blueprint for the British economy that resembled the latter option, Hayek’s report on Gibraltar actually made firm recommendations as to what the Rock’s government should do to reform the economy in a liberal fashion. It is easy enough to see how some of Hayek’s proposals reflected the principles that underpinned his ideas in The Road to Serfdom. Hayek’s proposal to deregulate the market in rental housing in Gibraltar was justified on the basis that it would allow the market to allocate resources more properly. More broadly, Hayek’s proposals to consider the ‘greater’ Gibraltar area, including parts of Spain, clearly reflects Hayek’s belief that government should construct structures in which a liberal economy, free from state planning but distinct from the stricter laissez-faire principles of the nineteenth century, could flourish. Indeed, his suggestion that the government finance a private company to establish a housing estate in La Línea prefaced later moves towards private finance initiatives undertaken in the more neoliberal age of the New Labour government in Britain. It also represented a close reading of Smith’s The Wealth of Nations, as advocated in The Road to Serfdom, wherein it was argued that 23 the state should act to facilitate, rather than regulate, capital. Even in the labour market, this sense was reflected in Hayek’s pointed statement about the admiralty’s restrictions on promotion for Gibraltarians into skilled jobs: It is essential that the entry into the different trades should be open to all on equal terms, and that the law should not tolerate any attempts by individuals or groups to restrict this entry by open or concealed force. 24 Yet, as we shall see, the Government rejected Hayek’s proposal to use the market to relocate Gibraltarians into Spain precisely because it did require the use of concealed economic force to achieve its goals. Critics of neoliberal political economy, such as David Harvey, have argued that one of the problems with neoliberalism, as a practical programme, is that it is more concerned with establishing markets than with establishing liberty for individuals (Harvey, 2007). Hitherto, because of his near-refusal to apply his ideas in practise and because his proposals on Gibraltar have been almost totally neglected, Hayek was unimpeachable on this front. Any claim that Hayek was more concerned with markets than people was at best conjecture and at worse name-calling. Yet, just as the Governor of Gibraltar did, we can see in Hayek’s proposals clear signs that he was prepared to sacrifice liberty of individuals to liberty for markets. Were Hayek’s proposals simply about relocating Gibraltarians into Spain, with the possible and unfortunate consequence of depriving them of their British nationality and identity, then they would not have conflicted with the ideas contained in The Road to Serfdom. But given that Hayek’s stated aim was to rescue society from the ideas of ‘those who can think of nothing better than to imitate Hitler’, the proposal to move Gibraltarians into Franco’s Spain was self-defeating (Hayek, 1962, p. 177). Franco had consciously modelled his own government on those of the inter-war fascist regimes. Like, Germany and Italy, Spain was a single-party state controlled by an authoritarian ruler. 25 Similarly, violence underpinned the creation and 24 maintenance of the regime. Franco, whose forces in the Civil War were augmented by the Luftwaffe, the German navy, and by Italian troops, had deliberately prolonged the conflict in order to cause as many casualties as possible amongst not only Republican troops but also amongst civilians too (Preston, 1994). And as in Germany and Italy, after the Civil War a secret police and series of state sponsored informers reported on those who opposed the regime. Many of those so accused were either executed or else given life sentences in hard labour camps. Paul Preston has recently argued that Franco’s treatment of political prisoners, amongst others, amounted to nothing less than a Spanish Holocaust (Preston, 2012). Moreover, not only did Franco consciously model his post-Civil War state on those of the fascist powers, but also in 1940 he had attempted to join the Axis war effort and to this end met with Hitler at Hendaye, on the Franco-Spanish border (Preston, 1992). Indeed, part of these negotiations involved discussions over a joint Spanish and German assault on Gibraltar itself. 26 Ultimately, it was only Franco’s excessive demands asked in return for Spanish entry into the war that prevented an accommodation between Franco’s Spain and Nazi Germany. In the light of Hayek’s proposal to deliver the vast majority of the working class of Gibraltar into Spain, his stated desire to protect people from those who aped the policies of Hitler, articulated in the same year as his Gibraltar report, rings hollow. In Hayek’s defence it might be argued that he was not an ardent defender of democracy. There is indeed some truth in this. Hayek argued, for example, that he would rather live in an undemocratic country with a liberal economy than in a democratic country run on socialist principles. In principle, by Hayek’s argument, it would be the liberal economy dictatorship which would best guard people’s liberty. Later in his life, it was on this basis that Hayek approved of Pinochet’s dictatorship in Chile (and accused the democratically elected Allende of being the real dictator). 27 But whilst Pinochet was the only head of state to attend Franco’s funeral, there were considerable differences between the two. Whereas Pinochet’s Chile became the 25 testing ground for the neoliberal economic doctrines of Milton Friedman and the Chicago School of Economics, Franco’s Spain, aping Germany and Italy, spent the years between 1939 and 1959 attempting to establish an autarkic economy. As Preston argues in his biography of Franco, the dictator ‘denounced the principles of free trade as an evil sham behind which Spain had been colonized’ (Preston, 1993, p. 344; see also Richards, 1998, Blanco, 2010). Franco personally oversaw the implementation of an economic policy that involved cutting imports, refusing credit from the allies, and imposing rationing (Preston, 1993, 344-5). But Franco’s economic policies went beyond the unorthodox and into the bizarre. For a time, for example, an Austrian confidence trickster led Franco to believe that the Spanish economy could be revived by investing money in the development of a new industrial process that would turn water into synthetic petrol through the addition of a few simple herbs (Preston, 2000, p. 62). The consequence of this micro managing of the Spanish economy (as both Hayek and Friedman could have readily predicted) was total economic catastrophe. As an academic working in Britain during the late 1930s and early 1940s we can only assume that Hayek had followed events in Spain, which were reported on at length in the press. At any rate, we know from the papers relating to his visit to Gibraltar that in 1944 he had undertaken a close investigation of the situation both in Gibraltar and in Spain. In sum, when faced with making practical proposals for economic reform, Hayek’s desire to establish a free market along neoliberal lines won out over his principles as stated in The Road to Serfdom. Whilst his proposals would give landlords the liberty to realise more substantial rents, the consequences for the working class population in Gibraltar would have been disastrous. Not only would Hayek’s proposals for Gibraltar certainly have robbed many Gibraltarians of political freedom, but also they would have been deprived of the economic liberty which Hayek stated he prized not only in 1944 but throughout his future writings. The contrast between the principles established in The Road to Serfdom, which, after all, 26 were meant to be universally beneficial rather than a defence of sectional interest, and the practical proposals laid out in ‘Some Economic Problems of Gibraltar’ could not be more striking. The Response of the British Colonial Office and the Government of Gibraltar Despite, as we have seen, the Government of Gibraltar having been keen to bring in an expert to advise them on the future of the Rock’s economy, and despite the enthusiasm that greeted Hayek’s agreement to visit Gibraltar to this end, none of his proposals were implemented. Indeed, his substantive ideas for the Gibraltar economy were hardly discussed in the Colonial Office in the weeks immediately following their submission. In part this was accidental. The official dealing with Hayek’s report, Mr. A. B. Acheson, went on long-term leave only weeks after Hayek submitted his report in October 1944 and it took sometime for his replacement, Mr. P. A. Wilson, to be appointed. In part, however, it was because of the political storm the report had already caused in Gibraltar and because the Colonial Office was nervous about confronting the Admiralty with Hayek’s blistering criticism of its employment practises in the dockyard. In the meantime, whilst Acheson’s successor was being appointed, the proposal for a new statistical survey of the population, which had arrived at the Colonial Office in September, a few week’s before ‘Some Economic Problems’, was circulated amongst various officials and advisors. Hayek’s proposal for a statistical survey was sent to Dr. Robert René Kuczynski, a prominent demographer who, after retiring from the London School of Economics as Britain’s first Reader in Demographics, went to work in the Colonial Office and promoted new methods for taking census data in the empire (Anonymous, 1947). In a note written in February 1945, Kuczynski dismissed Hayek’s concerns about the 1931 census data. He also suggested that the operation Hayek proposed be carried out would be a complex one and that it should only be approved if Hayek were prepared to oversee the procedure. 28 But by February 1945, 27 Hayek was preparing to visit the USA on his publicity tour for The Road to Serfdom and was not, therefore, available. Moreover, the Government of Gibraltar was cold towards Hayek’s proposal. The idea of taking a detailed statistical survey as quickly as possible rested on the premise that the returning evacuees would present the Gibraltar government with immediate accommodation problems. In reality, however, the timescale for the return of the evacuees was much longer than Hayek anticipated. It was not until 1951 that the last group of evacuees returned, just in time for the annual ten-year census to be taken as scheduled. On 15 March 1945, Sir Arthur J. Dawe, assistant under-secretary of state in the Colonial Office, wrote to Hayek apologising profusely for the delay in acknowledging formally Hayek’s report. In his letter, Dawe gave the impression that the Colonial Office had not yet given Hayek’s reports much consideration due to Acheson’s absence. He invited Hayek to come to London to discuss his proposals, and a meeting was arranged for 6 June, after Hayek’s return from the United States. In fact, in the meantime and as we have seen, Hayek’s proposals for a statistical survey had already been rejected. His other proposals were discussed in the weeks to follow. None of the staff at the Colonial Office were particularly impressed with Hayek’s suggestions. P. A. Wilson, in the typically understated fashion of Colonial Office officials noted that Hayek’s proposals on relocating Gibraltarians into Spain would ‘arouse a pretty little storm in Gibraltar’. 29 Major Orde Browne commented that Hayek’s proposals were interesting but that ‘he seems to me to adopt a somewhat bloodless scientific attitude, as in his suggestion that superfluous Gibraltarians should be squeezed out into Spain’. 30 He noted the comment of one of the under-secretaries at the Colonial Office, made in the file dealing with Hayek’s report, that ‘there would be almost insuperable difficulties in following a policy based on Professor Hayek’s views in this respect’. 31 Orde Browne agreed, ‘the introduction of a policy which sought deliberately to drive Gibraltarians into Spain would be indefensible’. 32 He 28 recommended that this idea not be pursued further. On the subject of wage policy, Orde Browne suggested sending the information collected by Hayek to the newly formed Labour Advisory Committee for consideration. This, however, was kicking Hayek’s report into the long grass. Orde Browne confessed that the committee was ‘a plant of somewhat tender growth, and it is hardly likely to develop enough initiative and experience to settle the thorny problems that are involved’. 33 S. E. V. Luke, an official in the Colonial Office, noted the controversial nature of Hayek’s report. He also pointed out that its proposals ran counter to the philosophy of the Secretary of State for the Colonies, Oliver Stanley. 34 Stanley was committed to developing the economies of British colonies and made available a Colonial Development Fund from which colonies could draw money to improve their infrastructure and economic prospects (Hubbard, 2011, p. 90). Stanley was also committed to increasing accountability in colonial government, not to reducing the role of the state in governing the empire. By pointing this out, Luke effectively decapitated Hayek’s proposals by setting his ideas on relocating the working class population against the development policy of the secretary of state. There was little enthusiasm for Hayek’s proposals from the Government of Gibraltar either. Whilst Governor Eastwood was only officially sent the report in March 1945, officials in Gibraltar had been in possession of a copy since late 1944. Eastwood had visited Dawe at the Colonial Office in early January 1945 and expressed dissatisfaction at Hayek’s reports. On 26 April, Eastwood wrote formally to Oliver Stanley outlining his views on Hayek’s report. In a lengthy letter, Eastwood condemned Hayek’s, cynical process of compelling British subjects to accept reduced standards of subsistence and education in a foreign country and it seems to me that such a conception is alien to the fundamental ideas governing the development of the British Colonial peoples. 35 29 If Gibraltarians were to be relocated anywhere, Eastwood argued, it would be elsewhere in the British Empire and not outside of it. Generally, and throughout his treatment of Hayek’s report, Eastwood was dismissive of Hayek’s work. The proposals that Hayek had put forward had fallen utterly flat. By the end of May 1945, Hayek’s proposals were rejected both by the Government of Gibraltar and by officials in the Colonial Office. Sir Arthur Dawe, in his meeting with Hayek on 6 June 1945 made one last attempt to revive them. He outlined the problems which officials in the Colonial Office and the Government of Gibraltar had with Hayek’s proposals and asked if he would reconsider them. Buoyed by the positive reception Hayek had received in the United States, he refused to remove any passages from his report or to change any of his proposals. 36 Hayek left the Colonial Office, and Dawe instructed that no further action need be taken over the report. Hayek’s contribution to the war effort was unequivocally over. Unintended Consequences Whilst by July 1945 Hayek’s report had been rejected, its influence was not quite at an end. The Colonial Office still needed to raise with the Admiralty the delicate issue of training and wages in the Gibraltar dockyard. In the end, the report was sent, unaltered to the Admiralty, who responded that, because of the pressure of war work, they would only be able to consider the proposals setout by Hayek in due course. Unsurprisingly, no actual response was ever sent. This refusal by the Admiralty to engage with Hayek’s report created a significant problem for the Government of Gibraltar. In correspondence between Eastwood and Stanley, Stanley pointed out that it was impossible to publish Hayek’s report because the Admiralty would not allow the passages critical to it to be published and because Hayek would not withdraw them. But for his part, Eastwood informed the secretary of state that the AACR suspected that the Government of Gibraltar was covering up Hayek’s report, which they assumed must have recommended pay increases for dockyard workers. 37 This 30 erroneous understanding had arisen when Hayek had met with the AACR in 1944. He had promised them that he was going to make proposals in his report that would materially improve the conditions of workers in Gibraltar. But he did not tell the AACR delegates what those proposals would be. Instead of anticipating that Hayek was to propose that the working class population should be relocated to Spain, the AACR reasoned that Hayek had proposed that workers in the dockyard be given substantial pay increases and that this was the reason that the report had been suppressed by the Government of Gibraltar. At the end of July 1945, the AACR called for a strike in the dockyard and more generally throughout the colony aimed at compelling the government to concede the higher wages which they believed Hayek had promised them in his report. After urgent telegrams between Gibraltar and London were exchanged, the Colonial Office brought pressure to bear on the Admiralty to grant higher wages and authorised an increase in wages for City Council workers. Rather than free the wages market in Gibraltar, the outcome of Hayek’s visit to Gibraltar was, in fact, to prompt suspicion and industrial unrest which in turn inaugurated a new era of micro-managing wage levels on the Rock. Not only had Hayek’s proposals for a neoliberal Gibraltar economy been rejected, but also his very presence on the Rock set the basis for considerable state planning in the Gibraltar economy in the years after 1945. Conclusion In Gibraltar, Hayek had attempted to pursue a small early neoliberal experiment. He did so because he believed that the Rock’s economy was structured in exactly the fashion that could easily lead to totalitarian government. Indeed, in The Road to Serfdom, Hayek pointed out that in 1928 the Weimar Government controlled over half of the economy of Germany; likewise the Government of Gibraltar in 1944 (Hayek, 1962, p. 28). We have seen how Hayek proposed to ‘correct’ these problems with the Gibraltar economy by creating a neoliberal economy in which markets dictated the lives of people in Gibraltar and its surrounding Campo. But, as argued above, rather 31 than delivering Gibraltarians from totalitarianism, Hayek’s proposals would have resulted in many of them living in the regime of General Franco. Moreover, rather than granting Gibraltarians living in La Línea the liberty of the free market, instead the system they would live under would be Spanish autarchy. It is little wonder that Hayek’s proposals were not well received, though the ironic consequences that came out of their not being published could not have been foreseen. Space has prohibited anything other than a cursory examination of the reasons that the Government of Gibraltar rejected Hayek’s proposals. Likewise, the implications of Hayek’s Gibraltar report for examining Hayek’s grasp of issues of political economy, and its significance as a document that contrasted sharply with the ideas of the era of planning, requires further attention. But in short, what we have seen is that Hayek’s Gibraltar report offers us several ways of engaging with Hayek’s work as a political economist. We have seen the way in which Hayek’s reports demonstrate that the creation of economic liberty ranked more highly and was separated out from the notion of individual freedom as outlined in The Road to Serfdom. Acknowledgements: I am very grateful to Stephen Dunne, Steve Fleetwood, Jo Grady, and Gareth Stockey for commenting on drafts of this article. Thanks also to Jenny Fichmann who undertook to photograph for me copies of Hayek’s papers in the Hoover Institution Archive. Funding: I am also grateful to the Arts and Humanities Research Council and to the Department of History at De Montfort University who funded various aspects of this research. 32 1 Hayek’s report gets a brief mention in Archer (2006, p. 57); Stockey (2009, pp. 173, 198); and Holland (2012) though it is worth noting that Holland places Hayek’s visit to Gibraltar in 1945 not 1944. There is no mention of the report on Gibraltar in any of the main Hayek biographies or in Hayek’s work after 1944. 2 The commissioning of reports on the subject of Gibraltar and its relationship with the Spanish hinterland has continued into the twenty-first century, for example Fletcher, J. (2009). 3 The National Archive (TNA), Colonial Office (CO) 91/522/2 contains the fruits of this visit and a discussion of it by members of the Colonial Office. 4 For a brief outline of the evacuation of Gibraltar during the war see, Grocott & Stockey (2012, pp. 6871). Stockey (2009, pp. 170-1) notes discrepancies in the figures for the number of workers who remained in Gibraltar. The lower figure of 4,000 fits more accurately the 1931 census combined with natural growth (adjudged by records of births and deaths) and the immigration from the surrounding hinterland occasioned by the Spanish Civil War of 1936-39. For an extended treatment, see Finlayson (1990). Accurate population figures are very difficult to find for the late 1930s and early 1940s because of the lack of a census in 1941. In 1944, at Hayek’s request, the head of the Crown Works department in Gibraltar estimated that in 1939 that the population was 17,600. See, Hoover Institution Archive, Stanford, Box 113/5, letter from Hoare to Hayek 25 September 1944 and enclosure. 5 TNA, CO 91/522/2, F. A. Hayek, ‘Report on Some Economic Problems in Gibraltar’, October 1944. 6 Throughout, the title Colonial Secretary refers to the head of the administration of the Government of Gibraltar and not to the Secretary of State for the Colonies who was the political head of the Colonial Office in Britain and a member of the British government’s cabinet. 7 Hoover Institution Archive, Box 113, files 5 and 6 contain Hayek’s source material, though sadly no notes written by Hayek other than marginalia. 8 TNA, CO 91/522/1, ‘Some Economic Problems’, p.6. 9 TNA, CO 91/522/2 contains Hayek’s report on, and proposals about, population statistics. 10 TNA, CO 91/522/1, ‘Some Economic Problems’, p. 2. 11 Ibid, p. 1. 12 It is likely that this was a reference to the estate of John Mackintosh, who had died in 1940 leaving a fortune of, in fact, around £2 million. Constantine, (2009, p. 289). 13 TNA, CO 91/522/2 ‘Some problems’, pp. 8-9 gives Hayek’s figures, calculations, and methodology for working out the amount of wealth available to the colony’s entrepreneurial community. See http://www.measuringworth.com for a useful calculator of money conversions and equivalents (accessed 17 January 2012). 14 Hoover Institution Archive, Hayek Papers, Box 113/5, Report on the Overcrowding Survey in Gibraltar 1938, 10 June 1938. 15 TNA, CO 888/3, Colonial Labour Advisory Committee (Minutes and Papers), 1944-46. 16 TNA, CO 91/522/2, ‘Some Economic Problems’, p. 15. 17 ‘The totalitarians in our midst’ was how Hayek labelled Britain’s planners in The Road to Serfdom. 18 They are contained in TNA, CO 91/522/2, ‘Some economic problems’ pp. 10-13. 19 Ibid, p. 12. 20 Ibid. 21 Ibid. 22 Ibid. 23 Indeed, the ideas of Beveridge took substantial work to break down on the part of neoliberals. Seem for example, Grady (2010). 24 Hayek, ‘Some Economic Problems’. 25 For the Spanish fascist party, the Falange, see, Preston (1995, pp. 109-130); distinctly more sympathetic is Payne (1962), nevertheless, the status of Spain as a one party state under Franco is undeniable. 26 Stockey (2009, Chapter Six) outlines in detail Spanish plans to attack Gibraltar, and subsequent Spanish espionage against the Rock (including hosting in the Campo German and Italian spies and military units) once the Hendaye negotiations broke-down. 27 The Times, Letter by Hayek, 2 August 1978. 28 TNA, CO 91/522/2, Note by Dr. Kuczynski, 26 February 1945. 29 TNA, CO 91/535/1, Notes by P. A. Wilson, 7 March 1945. 30 TNA, CO 91/535/1, Note by Major St. John Orde Browne, 24 May 1945. 31 TNA, CO 91/535/1, Note by S. E. V. Luke, 18 May 1945. 32 TNA, CO 91/535/1, Note by Major St. John Orde Browne, 23 May 1945. 33 TNA, CO 91/535/1, Note by Major St. John Orde Browne, 24 May 1945. 33 34 TNA, CO 91/535/1, Note by S. E. V. Luke, 2 March 1945. TNA, CO 91/535/1, Eastwood to Stanley, 26 April 1945. 36 TNA, CO 91/535/1, Note by S. E. V. Luke, 2 July 1945. 37 TNA, CO 91/522/3, Correspondence between Eastwood and Stanley, July 1945 onwards. 35 References Anonymous. (1947). Robert Rene Kuczynski, 1876-1947. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 110 (4), 383-384. Archer, E. G. (2006). Gibraltar, Identity and Empire. London: Routledge. Arco del Blanco, M. (2010). Hunger and the Consolidation of the Franco Regime 1939-1951. European History Quarterly, 40(3), 458-483. Constantine, S. (2009). Community and Identity: The Making of Modern Gibraltar Since 1704. Manchester: Manchester University Press. Cumbers, A. & McMaster, R. (2010). Socialism, Knowledge, the Instrumental Valuation Principle and the Enhancement of Individual Dignity. Economy and Society, 39(2), 247-270. Dean, M. (2002). Liberal Government and Authoritarianism. Economy and Society, (31)1, 37-61. Fletcher, J. (2009). An Economic Impact Study and Analysis of the Economies of Gibraltar and the Campo de Gibraltar. Gibraltar Chamber of Commerce. Finlayson, T. (1990). The Fortress Came First. Northampton: Gibraltar Books. Gamble, A. (1996). Hayek: The Iron Cage of Liberty. London: Polity Press. Grady, J. (2010). From Beveridge to Turner: Laissez-Faire to Neoliberalism. Capital and Class, 34(2), 163-180. Grocott, C. & Stockey, G. (2012). Gibraltar: A Modern History. Wales: University of Wales Press. Harvey, D. (2007). A Brief History of Neoliberalism. Oxford: Oxford University. Hayek, F. (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Hayek, F. (1962) [1945]. The Road to Serfdom. London: Routledge. Hayek, F. A., Kresge, S., & Wenar, L. (1994). Hayek on Hayek. London: Routledge. Hayek, F. (1978). Freedom of Choice The Times, 3 August. 34 Holland, R. (2012). Blue-Water Empire: The British in the Mediterranean Since 1800. London: Penguin. Hubbard, J. P. (2011). The United States and the End of British Colonial Rule in Africa, 1941-1968. North Carolina: McFarland and Co. O'Neill, J. (2003). Socialism, Associations and the Market. Economy and Society, (32)2, 184-206. Payne, S. G. (1962). Falange: A History of Spanish Fascism. London: Oxford University Press. Preston, P. (1992). Franco and Hitler: The Myth of Hendaye 1940. Contemporary History Review, 1(1), 1-16. Preston, P. (1993). Franco. London: Fontana. Preston, P. (1994). General Franco as a Military Leader. Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, 4, 21-41. Preston, P. (1995). The Politics of Revenge. London: Routledge. Preston, P. (2000). Comrades. London: Fontana. Preston, P. (2012). The Spanish Holocaust. London: HarperPress. Richards, M. (1998). A Time of Silence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Spieker, J. (2013). Defending the open society: Foucault, Hayek, and the problem of biopolitical order. Economy and Society, (42)2, 304-321. Stockey, G. (2009). Gibraltar: A Dagger in the Spine of Spain? Sussex: Sussex University Press. 35
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz