Australasian Journal of Economics Education Volume 10, Number 1, 2013, pp.32-38 ANALYSING EMISSION COMPLIANCE IN THE TEXTBOOK MODEL* Gerald Visgilio Connecticut College ABSTRACT The model used in most undergraduate environmental economics textbooks to analyze pollution control policies shows an emission source reducing its waste in a least cost manner, operating in full compliance with the law. In this paper, the conventional textbook model is extended by analyzing how a polluting facility, operating under a cap-and-trade (CAT) program, responds to the imposition of an excess emission penalty. Specifically, the discussion is framed in terms of the following questions: Will a source discharge in excess of its permits and pay a fine for its excess emissions? Will it abate its excess emissions? Will it buy additional permits to cover these emissions? Hopefully, this paper will encourage a productive interchange between teachers and students about the level of emission compliance by a polluting facility. Keywords: cap-and-trade, command-and-control, expected net cost, excess emission penalty JEL classifications: A20, Q50, Q52, Q58 1. INTRODUCTION Title IV of the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 in the United States, less formally called the Acid Rain Program (ARP), was a major policy initiative for regulating sulfur dioxide (SO2) emissions. Title IV, which uses a cap-and-trade (CAT) approach for SO2, has been referred to as the “grand policy experiment” (Stavins 1998, p. 69) and a “living * Correspondence: Gerald Visgilio, Department of Economics, Connecticut College, Box 5571, 270 Mohegan Ave, New London, CT 06320, USA, Email: [email protected]. Thanks to two anonymous referees for comments and suggestions. ISSN 1448-448X © 2013 Australasian Journal of Economics Education Emission Compliance in the Textbook Model 33 legend” (Burtraw & Palmer 2004, p. 41) with considerable scholarly research showing it to be a cost-effective approach for achieving the annual SO2 statutory cap of 8.95 million tons.1 Under Title IV, an individual ARP unit is free to select its least cost abatement strategy, which may involve placing scrubbers on smoke stacks, switching from high sulfur to low sulfur coal, blending fuels, and reducing output. Although Title IV allows the trading and banking of SO2 discharge permits (referred to as allowances in the law),2 each ARP emitting unit is legally required to hold one allowance for each ton of SO 2 that it discharges into the atmosphere, and since the start of the program in 1995, there has been nearly perfect compliance among regulated units.3 Can the model presented in introductory environmental economics textbooks be used to shed light on the issue of high compliance among emission sources? In most basic textbooks the discussion of cap-andtrade usually focuses on major efficiency aspects of the policy – cost effectiveness, the equi-marginal principle, and technological innovation.4 This analysis shows the typical emission source operating in a least cost manner by selecting its best pollution control strategy from an array of activities that may involve output reduction, input changes, waste treatment, and residual recycling. The individual source, which also may buy or sell discharge permits at the marketestablished price, holds enough permits to cover its emissions. The 1 Burtraw & Palmer (2004) provide a detailed discussion of Title IV, Harrington & Morgenstern (2007) give a comparison between economic incentives policies and command and control (CAC) policies, and Chan et al. (2012) discuss SO2 allowance trading and its implications for the construction of a climate change policy. 2 Stavins (1998) indicates that by a “statutory provision” of the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990, permits (allowances) are not property rights. 3 The reader is directed to EPA Acid Rain Progress Reports for the years from 1995 to 2009. Under the law, each APR emission source, at the end of every calendar year, has a sixty-day grace period in which to adjust its allowance holdings – to make sure that it holds a sufficient number of allowances to cover its discharge of SO2 for the preceding year. When an ARP source neglects to reconcile the number of allowances its holds with the amount of its emissions, the source must pay a fine of $2,000 (inflation-adjusted to $3,337 in 2008) per ton of excess SO2 emissions. The fine must be paid to the EPA by July 1 of the current year for excess emissions that were discharged in the previous year. In addition, a violating source also must surrender discharge permits to the EPA, from its current year allowance allocation, equal to its excess emissions. 4 Field & Field (2012), Kahn (2005), Kolstad (2010), and Tietenberg & Lewis (2009) provide a good economic evaluation of market-based policy instruments. 34 G. Visgilio issue of non-compliance generally is omitted or given little attention in the textbook explanation of cap-and-trade.5 The purpose of this paper is to provide an economic analysis of compliance by discussing how an individual emission source, operating under a CAT policy, responds to imposition of a penalty for its excess emissions. My analysis uses the marginal abatement cost (MAC) diagram that is presented in most introductory environmental economics textbooks. Although my analysis draws from the conventional textbook model, it goes beyond that model by discussing how a polluting facility will respond to the economic incentive effect of an excess emissions penalty. Specifically, this paper looks at cost effective approach decision making by an emission source when faced with a penalty for emissions in excess of the number of permits that it holds.6 More specifically, my analysis frames the discussion in terms of the following important questions: Will an emission source discharge in excess of its permits and risk paying a fine for its excess emissions? Will it abate its excess emissions? Will it acquire additional permits to cover these emissions? By recognizing that CAT policies may provide emission sources with an efficient incentive for full compliance, this paper addresses an important and perhaps overlooked pedagogical issue for undergraduate students in introductory environmental courses. 2. THE ECONOMICS OF COMPLIANCE With a CAT policy, a violating firm, facing a penalty for each unit of its excess emissions, responds by selecting its least cost strategy from the following options: (1) it continues to emit in excess of the number of permits it holds; (2) the source eliminates excess emissions by purchasing permits; or (3) it reduces its waste discharge so that its emissions just equal its permits. A source, when deciding on its preferred emission control strategy, considers both the total and marginal costs of compliance and noncompliance. In reaching a 5 Berck & Hefand (2011) and Downing (1984) provide a detailed discussion of compliance under command and control. My analysis is different from theirs by discussing compliance under cap-and-trade and by comparing incentives for compliance under both CAT and CAC. 6 With respect to enforcement and monitoring, an added “advantage of market-based instruments is that they may enhance compliance” (Keohane & Olmstead 2007, p.178). Under CAT, emission sources have a strong incentive to inform the environmental control agency whenever they purchase additional discharge permits (See Field & Field 2012, p.260). Emission Compliance in the Textbook Model 35 decision about whether it should comply with the law, the source will compare the total cost of compliance with that of noncompliance. When making its decision at the margin, an individual source compares the incremental cost of compliance with that of noncompliance. Since a source may not be caught and punished each time it violates the law, the offending source may find it cost effective to emit in excess of the number of permits that it holds. In my analysis, the source’s decision about compliance or noncompliance is expressed as follows: E[NC] = E[TP] – LCC (1) where E[NC] is the expected net cost, E[TP] is the expected total penalty for noncompliance, and LCC is the least cost means of compliance. The source’s decision to comply with the law depends on whether E[NC] is positive or negative – when E[TP] > LCC, the source complies and when E[TP] < LCC, it violates. The source’s decision to comply with the law depends on the severity and the certainty of the punishment as well as the cost of compliance. In other words, high expected penalties and/or low compliance costs are likely to induce full or high compliance. My graphical illustration of a polluting source, operating under a marketable permit policy, is shown in Figure 1. In my diagram, emissions (e) and permits (q) are represented on the upper and lower horizontal axes respectively. The vertical axis shows the market price of p per permit and the expected fine of βf per unit of excess emissions, with β being the probability of getting caught and f the per unit fine. The MAC curve, in the body of the illustration, is increasing as abatement increases. As with any CAT program, each emission source may buy or sell discharge permits and it is required by law to hold enough permits to cover its aggregate emissions. In the analysis that follows, Figure 1 is used to discuss two scenarios where a polluting facility, operating within the framework of a CAT policy, contemplates whether it should discharge in excess of the number of permits it holds. In scenario (1), an emission source is holding q1 and thinking about reducing its emissions from e2 to e1. Here, the source will have excess emissions of (e2 – e1), and it faces an expected penalty of βf(e2 – e1), or Area (D+E+F). The source, however, may eliminate its excess emissions either by purchasing additional permits or by reducing its emissions. If it purchases (q2 – q1) permits, the source pays a total 36 G. Visgilio permit cost of p(q2 – q1), or Area (E+F). If, however, it reduces emissions from e2 to e1, it incurs a total abatement cost of only Area (F). The emission source, in this situation, will compare its least cost compliance strategy to the expected fine for noncompliance, and equation (1) may be rewritten as: E[NC] = Area (D + E + F) – Area (F) (2) Since Area (D+E+F) > Area (F), E[NC] is positive and the source will reduce its emissions to comply with the law. In short, Figure 1 shows that a CAT policy will induce an emission source to achieve optimal abatement at least cost whenever βf exceeds p. Figure 1: Excess Emissions for an Individual Emission Source The source also may bring about excess emissions by selling permits without undertaking an equivalent amount of emission abatement. In scenario (2), the source is assumed to be operating at q1 and e1. If the source contemplates selling (q1 – q0) permits, while continuing to discharge at e1, it will have excess emissions of (e1 – e0). For these emissions, the expected total penalty or fine is βf(e1 – e0), or Area (A+B+C). Once again, the source reviews its least cost compliance strategy – either abating waste at a cost shown by Area (B+C) or not Emission Compliance in the Textbook Model 37 selling permits with a value of p(q1 – q0), or Area (C). Equation (1) now may be expressed as: E[NC] = Area (A+B+C ) – Area (C) (3) Since E[NC] > 0, the source complies and does not sell any of its permits. As in the previous example, Figure (1) again shows that whenever βf is greater than p, CAT brings about cost effective compliance. 3. CONCLUDING REMARKS Will an emission source fully comply with the cap-and-trade policy? How does the source decide the means by which it complies with pollution control policy? Under what circumstances will a polluting facility find it profitable to discharge an amount in excess of the number of permits that it holds? Hopefully, this paper serves as a platform for a productive dialogue – perhaps an exchange between teachers and students in environmental economics courses – about high levels of compliance among emission sources such as those in the U.S. ARP or those regulated under other CAT programs. In this paper, the conventional textbook model was used to graphically show and explain the economic incentive effects of penalty per unit of excess emissions for a polluting facility that operates within the framework of a cap-and-trade program. Specifically, my analysis provides some insight with respect to the least cost response of an emission source to the imposition of such a penalty. In this context, the source compares the cost of compliance with that of noncompliance and selects its preferred plan of action – it may elect to pay the fine or it may opt to eliminate its excess emissions, either by purchasing additional permits or by reducing its discharge of waste. My analysis also shows that an emission source recognizes both the severity and the certainty of the punishment when reaching a decision about whether it is profitable to violate the law. More specifically, the analysis presented in this paper suggests that, because of the uncertainty associated with detecting violations, a polluting source will not comply with the law when the expected penalty is less than its least cost compliance strategy. REFERENCES Berck, P. and Helfand, G. (2011) The Economics of the Environment, Boston, MA: Addison-Wesley. 38 G. Visgilio Burtraw, D. and Palmer, K. (2004) “SO2 Cap-and-Trade Program in the United States: A ‘Living Legend’ of Market Effectiveness,” in Harrington, W., Morgenstern, R. and Sterner, T. (eds.), Choosing Environmental Policy Comparing Instruments and Outcomes in the United States and Europe, Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. Chan, G., Stavins, R., Stowe, R. and Sweeney, R. (2012) “The S02 Allowance Trading System and the Clean Air Amendments of 1990: Reflections of Twenty Years of Policy Innovation”, National Tax Journal 65 (2), pp. 419-452. Downing, P. B. (1984) Environmental Economics and Policy, Boston, MA: Little, Brown and Company. Field, B. C. and Field, M. (2012) Environmental Economics: An Introduction, 6th edition, New York: McGraw-Hill. Harrington, W. and Morgenstern, R. D. (2007) “Economic Incentives versus Command and Control: What the Best Approach for Solving Environmental Problems?”, in Visgilio, G. R. and Whitelaw, D. M. (eds.), Acid in the Environment Lessons Learned and Future Prospects, New York: Springer Science and Business Media, LLC. Kahn, J. R. (2005) The Economic Approach to Environmental and Natural Resources, 3nd edition, Fort Worth, TX: The Dryden Press. Keohane, N. O. and Olmstead, S. M. (2007) Markets and the Environment, Washington, DC: Island Press. Kolstad, C. D. (2010) Environmental Economics, 2nd edition, New York: Oxford University Press. Stavins, R. N. (1998) “What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment? Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12 (3), pp.69-88. Tietenberg, T. and Lewis, L. (2009) Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, 8th edition, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz