I·'. 'I, ' .. O'Brien, P.K. _/! (2000). 'The reconstruction, rehabilitation and reconfiguration of he British industrial revolution as a conjuncture in global history,' in: Itinerario, 3/4, p. 117134. fin J 117 The Reconstruction, Rehabilitation and Reconftguration of the British Industrial Revolution as a Conjuncture in Global History* PATRICK KARL O'BRIEN The First Industrial Revolution as a Conjuncture in Global History All historical research, however micro and focussed can be represented as part of a process of 'reconfiguration', Research is simply the crafts dominant and traditional activity of transforming archival evidence into printed narratives which validate, qualify and occasionally demolish dominant metanarratives. Most historians continue to be engaged in Von Ranke's grand project for construction of history by making different, more durable and better quality bricks that are piled up awaiting to be used as more modem architecture for national histories. They agree as a point of discipline (if not belief) that this remains the best way to proceed. Some (as Randolph Churchill remarked of Gladstone) are 'old men in a hurry' and opting to proceed from the top down by relocating national histories within the wider spaces, larger chronologies and cosmopolitan concerns of global history. There is, however, nothing new about writing of world histories. They go back to Herodotus, characterised the writings of clerical scholars in the times of Christendom, blossomed briefly during the Enlightenment and have (for obvious reasons, that can be summed up by reference to the accelerated globalisation of times) reappeared as a serious agenda for scholars to pursue. Indeed two distinct approaches have now clearly emerged. First, is the model, persuasively elaborated in several books by William McNeill. He has inspired a programme of historical investigation into connexions across continents, countries and geographies as well as through very long spans of time. NcNeill's paradigm assumes that such 'interactions', '·encounters', 'contacts with others', can be represented as the origins and motor of economic, social, political, military, cultural, religious, technological, and presumably all other conceivable types of change studied by historians. Put simply, the other major approach extends geographical catchment areas and time spans for comparative histories of topics that might be illuminating to study across national boundaries, continents and separate f-i ,.JJ ~ (t ~ (!) UVkf~'if'' 0} C0 118 1'ATRJCK KARL O'BRJEN cultures. Although the linguistic qualifications for research in this style of history are difficult to acquire and the scholarship needed to make sense of verified contrasts is formidable, the methodological problems involved are similar to those encountered for exercises in comparative history conducted within European, national or regional frames of reference. Comparative history helps scholars to escape from the complexity and tyranny of local detail and to offer controlled if conjectural, answers to the variety of questions they select for investigation. For global historians, insights derived from the method tends to be realised when they concentrate upon well defined historical episodes, artefacts, institutions, social practices, attitudes and beliefs that are found in many places and which have already been studied in depth in the context of particular locations; and which exhibit comparable but, more important, dissimilar ecological, political, cultural, social, economic and other features. Then, as Marc Bloch anticipated, 'the comparative method can elicit from the chaotic multiplicity of circumstances these contrasts which were generally effective'. For obvious reasons and in order to communicate contrasts of major significance, global historians will aggregate and average data and information pertaining to wider spaces (continents, oceans, civilisations) than evidence mobilised within the parameters of national histories. For purposes of constructing building blocks for an ongoing programme designed to produce metanarratives that are of 'universal' interest the comparative method looks set to dominate the renaissance in global history for years to come. It has, for example, already generated a bibliography of global histories concerned with the family, youth, marriage, diet, housing, health, military organisation, government, human rights, parliaments, nationalism, religions, revolutions, gender and, of course, material life or material change. No surprise will be occasioned by the appearance in recent decades of histories encompassing 'the world economy', going back in time to Sung China and written to explain disparate levels of economic progress achieved by countries, societies and communities located in all continents. Such cDncerns will continue to be a litmus test of the field's mission to keep humanity in view, because throughout history most people in most places have been preoccupied with obtaining food, shelter, clothing and manufactured artefacts that they required to sustain either a basic, comfortable and, only latterly, an agreeable standard of living. Before the end of the twentieth century, a modern generation of economic historians began to resituate the acclaimed scientific, technological and economic achievements of Western societies in a global context. Not long after the second World War, and during an era of decolonisation, historians were offered the opportunity- provided by the accumulation of a body of knowledge, (long available about Europe, but emerging for Asia , the Middle East, Mrica and Latin America) - to 'reposition' their hitherto disconnected histories of wealth and poverty, one against another, in order THE BRITISH INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION AS A CONJUNCTURE IN GLOBAL HISTORY 119 to construct global histories of material progress that could have satisfied the aspirations of Voltaire , Adam Smith and their enlightened followers and pleased Max Weber. Those who follow Max Weber, Karl Marx and a tradition of writing that can be traced back to Montesquieu , insist that Europe's competing national economies had been on a potentially more promising trajectory for long run growth for several centuries. They emphasise evolving, but persistent contrasts, between European and Asian institutional arrangements, political systems, legal frameworks , cultural conditioning and religious beliefs, within which economic activities were embedded for at least four centuries before 1815. Cruder Weberians simply juxtapose selected 'preconditions' for Smithian growth that they observed operating efficiently in Europe (or rather in some countries in northwestern Europe), in stark contrast to Asia, where, in their perception, political, social, familial, cultural and ecological 'impediments' to growth and structural change prevented or constrained the emergence of competitive markets for commodities, capital, land and labour. Their critics often more widely and deeply read in the now massive bibliography of economic history dealing with South, East and Southeast Asia and the Ottoman Empire, have traduced samples of data (related to population growth, urbanisation, balances of trade, yields per hectare and real wages) for selected regions of Asia that at least qualify traditional impressions that levels of labour productivity and standards of living afforded by European economies to their populations were 'definitely' let alone 'significantly' superior much before the era of the French revolution. Yet at this level of 'continental' aggregation the selection of samples of data for comparative history must be problematical, not simply because quantitative information is scarcer and of poor quality, but because the 'Asian' economy included much larger shares of the world's cultivable land, resources, income and population . AI though we remain a long way from offering statistically secure comparisons for average levels of productivity and real incomes, the accumulating volume of research (now available on Asian agricultures, industries, trad.es, credit systems, mercantile enterprise, u·ansportation networks, markets for commodities and factors of production) 'degrades' simplistic Weberian perceptions that Europe alone had evolved the political institutional, legal, cultural and religious frameworks required for Smithian growth. That outcome would not have surprised Marshal Hodgson who decades ago observed that 'all attempts to invoke pre-modern seminal traits in the occident can be shown to fail under close historical analysis'. William McNeill, Fernand Braude!, Kirti Chaudhuri, Gunder Frank, Ken Pomeranz, Jack GDldstone, Kaoru Sugihara, David Washbrook and other historians would agree. Eric jones continues to revise some of the positions he adopted for the first edition of the European Miracle. From his detailed comparisons of levels and types of development achieved by Europe and Asia for the _,_ 120 THE BRITIS. .NDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION AS A CONJUNCfURE IN GLOBAL HISTORY _,ATRlCK KARL O'BRIEN achieved by advanced and industrialised economies in Europe, North America, Australasia, Japan and East Asia would be much difjr?rent were it not for a unique and trans-national event in world history that occurred in the British Isles from 1750-1850. early modern period, Braude! inferred that 'the populated regions of the world faced with demands of numbers seem to us to be quite close to each other'. But there is, he continued 'a historiographical inequality between Europe and the rest of the world. Europe invented historians and made good use of them. Her own history is well lit and can be called as evidence or used as claim. The history of non-Europe is still being written. And until the balance of knowledge and interpretation has been restored, the historian will be reluctant to cut the Gordian knot of world history'. Since Braude! wrote these wise words, more knowledge has accumulated and the Gordian knot of world history has been cut, not merely by those who sweep through history with 'chain saws', but by up-to-date, widely read and sophisticated scholars like Ken Pomeranz, Bin Wong, and Jack Goldstone, who have found a way not 'through' but 'round' the Gordian knot by 'rehabilitating' the British Industrial Revolution as a seminal event in world history. The British will once again be delighted that their American cousins have restored the First Industrial Revolution to the canonical status it has long held, not only in their own historical estimation, but as the 'bridge' constructed by the godfathers of social science (Tocqueville, St Simon, List, Marx, Comte, Durkheim and Weber) to carry their grand narratives of modernisation through a phase of transition to our modern world. The industrial market economy, along with liberty and democracy, has long been widely perceived by Anglo-Americans as part of their nation's bequest to modern civilisation. That is why so many of that fraternity of NATO intellectuals continue to represent the First Industrial Revolution as superior in significance for the welfare of mankind compared to the transition from the paleolithic to the neolithic civilisation; to urban industrial developments under the Sung, to the Florentine Renaissance and, above all, to that unnecessary and destructive revolution that occurred in France round about the same time. Revising the Old Story Global historians should be aware that over the past two decades British and American economic historians have engaged in a wide ranging debate about the nature and significance of the First Industrial Revolution. Although the label Industrial Revolution has, will and perhaps should survive, 'triumphalist' books with such titles as the 'First Industrial Revolution', 'the First Industrial Nation', will probably no longer be published by historians with posts in higher education. Furthermore, the deployment of a British 'paradigm' to analyse the 'retardation' or the 'industrialisation' of 'follower countries' on the continent or elsewhere, in Eurasia has been effectively 'disabled'. Few historians (and fewer social scientists) are now prepared to argue that current levels of per capita income and productivity 121 Reconfiguration of the British Industrial Revolution is now being transformed into a modern consensus because scholars have: l rJ v 'fl ~~ -~_I a!B-\q\. 'fJ""/ / • redefined the pace and chronology of British industrialisation re-specified the nature, extent and origins of innovations that appeared during the classic period of the Industrial Revolution, I 763-1846 investigated the European (and Asian) antecedents of the new and re~iable knowl~dge_ introduced into British industry d~lfing this period 1• rejected the diffusiOn model as a way of understandmg the spread of " modern industry onto the mainland of Europe in the nineteenth century and to Asia in the twentieth century • brought 'contingent factors' to the foreground of the established story, including the availability of natural resources such as coal, mineral ores and fecund soils • rediscovered the important role played by massive investment in naval and military power by the Hanoverian state on behalf of the economy • failed to isolate enduring and peculiarly 'British' features of the kingdom's institutions, religion or culture behind its precocious transition to urban industrial society. • • Revisionists have addressed an old story that journalists and far too many professional historians still carry in their heads; and defend perhaps for the sake of prolonging an argument. But as ever, one of the problems with old stories is that many versions float around and the one regaled here does, in several respects replicate, an 'old/ old story', going back as historiography to Arnold Toynbee, the Hammonds, Tawney and the Webbs. Yet in form and substance the story addressed by revisionists is post war and revises classic texts by Ashton, Rostow, Landes, Hobsbawrn, Chambers, Hartwell, Gerschenkron, Flinn, Deane and Cole et al. None of these 'scholars' and teachers ever maintained that the British Industrial Revolution came without antecedents, preparation, exemplars, or that it lacked a European dimension. Nevertheless this (let's call it the Ashtonian story) agreed and elaborated upon several features of a quintessentially British Industrial Revolution that was chronologically confined. (The chronologies varied: Ashton favoured 1760-1830; Hartwell preferred 1783-1832; Rostow boldly plumped for 1783-1802.) Most maintained the revolution was not on stream much before 1750 and had run its course from the late eighteenth to the first quarter of the nineteenth century. At the core of the story are growth rates which accelerated (visibly and rapidly, particularly for industrial output, but also for agricultural production and gross domestic product). Long 122 "RICK KARL O'BRIEN run growth in per capita income emerged as normal over the course of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. Accelerated growth emanated from: an abrupt jack up' in rates of investment (capital formation), but above all from innovations (new technologies techniques and processes) for the production of manufactured goods and also from the application of inanimate forms of energy (steam power) to industry and transportation. Industries, beginning with cotton and iron (but followed in fairly rapid sequence by others), were 'radically transformed' in terms of their capital/ labour ratios; technologies; modes and scale of organisation, and location. In short, the old story of the Industrial Revolution was represented as: • led by industry • revolutionary in tempo (a short sharp discontinuity, take off, watershed, great divide or break-through) conceived essentially as an economic, not a social and certainly not a cultural episode • funded, prompted, managed by private enterprise - largely by entrepreneurs and humble artisans from the North of England and the Midlands, \lnassisted by the State • as British (if not English). Finally and following canonical traditions in the social sciences the British Industrial Revolution could be offered to other nations as 'paradigm' for modern economic growth. Thus implicitly and as an historical process industrialisation could be understood as the diffusion of best practice (i.e. British and by extension, North American) techniques of production, modes of organisation, institutions and political frameworks for the operation of factor and commodity markets onto the mainland of Europe and (in the fullness of time) eastward to Asia. Although this tale in ever more sophisticated forms was told to British, North Americans and European students for three decades after the war, its origins can be traced back to the generation's of scholars writing economic history during the 'high tide' of British imperialism and beginnings of socialism before the Great War, 1914-18. New and Old Stories Juxtaposed The current (and contested) story (which might be labelled as a 'new/old' story) has utilised economic theory and statistics to locate the British 'case' of economic growth within: • a framework of general theory concerned to model how economies grow and are transformed into affluent market economies • a body of statistical information about British economic growth gathered, calibrated and refined since the War THE BRITISH lSTRlAL REVOLUTION AS A CONJUNCTURE IN GLOBAL HISTORY 123 • an international database largely related to European and North American economies, within which the British case can be resituated • deeper investigations into the political, institutional and cultural foundations for economic development in general and for Britain in particular. By re-contextualising Britain (as a 'case study') within a broader and even broadening geographical space (which is now includes Eurasia); a longer chronology going back millennia; a body of more rigorous and sophisticated theory about economic growth, and an explicitly comparative framework. British economic historians have 'effectively' demystified, 'denationalised' and cut their own industrial revolution down to size. They offer undergraduates and the media (if and when the episode enters the public arena) a more realistic, nuanced, illuminating, and altogether less chauvanistic 'First Industrial Revolution' and 'First Industrial Nation'. Nevertheless, historical interpretations really are cyclical in character. Scholars have been writing economic histories of the British Islands for more than a century. Their new story was anticipated in several respects (save theoretical rigour and quantification), in the writings of yesteryear by Ashley, Clapham, Redford, Lipson and Musson. Indeed we might depict this recent version as the renaissance of gradualism; the re-emergence of good fortune and the reintegration of coal into and political power into modern economic history. From the plethora of texts on the shelves of university libraries quotations can be cited to draw contrasts between older and modern stories of the First Industrial Revolution. For example in the 1960's Professor Gill told undergraduates at Harvard that 'The modern economic world can be said to have been born in England in the second half of the eighteenth century'. While David Landes taught them that 'the technological changes we denote as the industrial revolution implied a far more general breach ,with the past than anything since the invention of the wheel'. In Oxford round about the same time, Max Hartwell told us, 'on any historical accounting the industrial revolution is one of the great discontinuities in history, and it would not be implausible to claim it has been the greatest'. This kind of hyperbole is still commonplace and can no longer be substantiated with reference to discontinuities as currently measured for industrial ' output let alone for national output on a whole. It is now recognised that\ the British industrial revolution is among the slowest and evolutionary of 5 'transitions' to an industrial economy. The statistical exercises conducted by Crafts and Harley slowed the Revolution down, but some acceleration in growth is still discernible and their numbers are contested by Hoppit, Berg and Hudson, Jackson and latterly by Cuenca. Yet there will be no need to treat readers to another disquisition about the range and quality of the data, let alone to the arcane ramifications of index number theory, because few British economic historians would now rest a case for 'revolution', 'take off', 'fundamental chasm', 'great spurt', 'watershed' or any such l 124 -.TRICK KARL O'BRIEN THE BRITISH tnUUSTRIAL REVOLUTION AS A CONJUNCTURE IN GLOBAL HISTORY label on the data available for the measurement of cycles and trends in industrial output, agricultural production or gross domestic product. Nevertheless, the curves plotted on graphs expose discernible discontinuities in output coming on stream sometime over the second half of the eighteenth century. They are neither 'dramatic' nor the only acceleration in rates of change in per capita incomes that occurred in the economic history of Britain. Long cycles of slower and faster economic growth have been traced over several centuries. Medieval, Tudor and Stuart times were not periods of stasis. Average real income were probably clearly higher by the time of the Glorious Revolution than they had been at the Norman Conquest. In this chronology and perspective the Industrial Revolution appears as just another, but more sustained, upswing, and certainly not as an escape from immobilisme or a Malthusian trap. Slow, cyclical, long run evolutionary change followed by some 'discernible degree' of acceleration into sustained growth occurred during the eighteenth century. In tempo (at least for Britain) no great divide occurred between modern and premodern growth. Something occurred and there is no case (as Rondo Cameron, jonathan Clark and others advised) to abandon labels like industrial revolution. Their correct observation that many famous contemporaries (including Jane Austen, Shelley, Keats, Wordsworth) along with classical economists (such as Adam Smith and David Ricardo) were apparently unaware they were living through an era of profound transition seems neither here nor there.Joel Mokyr points out that some other equally well known economists, literary figures, and scientists (Lauderdale, Colquhoun, Owen, Babbage, Elizabeth Gaskell, Porter) marked the changes. Christians did not recognise they were alive at the birth of Christianity. Abelard and Heloise did not appreciate they resided in the Middle Ages. Historians (not contemporaries) select events, episodes, and coJ:Uunctures that mattered. The British Industrial Revolution is a post-hoc imposition, but so is the Florentine Renaissance and the Dutch Reformation. Another mode of 'representation' (pioneered by Clapham and followed up by Lipson, Redford and other academics writing in the 1930s and who retained the congenital suspicions of their craft to 'discontinuities' in history) was to consider the British economy at the time of the Great Exhibition and to ask: what had changed? They then proceeded to underline features 1 frJI of production and work that had remained largely untouched by events of the previous century (1751-1851). This style of painting was imitated in an vinfluential article published by Rafael Samuel in 1977, and the genre brings to the foreground elements of continuity in: • • • • • food processing, finished metallurgy, clothing, etcetera) which had not altered their modes of production for decades transportation: where a canal system was in place but where railways only really began to take over the delivery of freight in the 1840s and 1850s occupation after occupation, where ratios of capital to labour, the tools and techniques used to perform manual and skilled work were the same as they had been in 1700 or even when Charles I went to the scaffold the prevalence of small scale units of production which demonstrated that factories and corporations were untypical, not modal forms of organisation in numerous rural counties untouched by industrialisation the widespread use of traditional forms of energy - provided by wind, water, animals and human toil compared to the celebrated, but slow, diffusion of steam power. Historians are professionally adept at marking survivals, antecedents and continuities. Nevertheless (and despite their valid reminders) several important features of the realm's system of production had changed by 1851. Most Europeans (attending the great Exhibition) recognised Britain as an advanced economy. They observed structural changes that historians later measured and which included: !) /'{\,~ I) , &P JJl'' • agriculture - the largest and still unmechanised sector of the economy: where units of production, tenurial arrangements and techniques of cultivation had hardly changed since the Restoration (1660) • major industries: (such as glass, bricks, mining, furniture, shipbuilding, 125 • a low proportion of the national workforce engaged in agriculture, compared to industry and services (• the use of coal as the dominant source of energy • the concentration of manufacturing activity in large new towns such as Manchester, Liverpool, Glasgow, Birmingham and Bradford • factories as places of work, concentrated production and as efficient organisational forms for the supervision and control of labour • the mechanisation of textile production, basic metallurgy and transportation by rail • high and rising ratios of capital to labour • high average incomes per capita • large British proportions of European textile, cast iron and pottery production and shipbuilding • the Victorian kingdom's extraordinary share of world trade in manufactured goods and services. In short (and no surprise) continuities and discontinuities existed side by side within and across regions, sectors, industries, operating in symbiotic connexion. ,..--126 .ATRICK KARL O'BRIEN Smithian Growth Even (i) if some features of the British economy had clearly progressed in scale and efficiency; (ii) if the pace of change had accelerated somewhat, and (iii) if we wish to continue using the term 'industrial revolution', for purposes of global history we need to enquire: what exactly had been transformed from 1750-1850. Where did the impetus come from? What was 'quintessentially British' about this celebrated Revolution? Economic historians have devoted academic careers to investigating major and minor 'inputs', as well as the institutional and legal frameworks, political conditions, cultural and religious predispositions which interacted to carry the British economy forward and upward through centuries of time to a plateau of possibilities from whence higher and sustainable growth appeared and became irreversible. These 'preconditions' used to be analysed as the transition or evolution to 'capitalism'. That term (or '-ism') went underground during the Cold War and was replaced by the 'rise of commercial society', and latterly by an American label 'Smithian Growth'. Smith ian growth allows for limited inputs of new technology, but basically encapsulates the notion of long run economic development emanating from: the integration of markets for commodities, capital, labour and useful knowledge within national boundaries and through international trade. Its central idea is that the creation of efficient institutions, legal frameworks, law and order, the protection of property rights, the mobility of capital and labour can lower transaction costs, promote commerce and exchange and thereby lead (without fundamental transformations in production functions) to an accumulation of capital and population growth with gradual rises in real incomes per capita. Merchants were harbingers of this early modern process, particularly grand merchants, engaged in European and pan-European trade. Merchants (Braudelian heroes) integrate markets; coordinate proto-industrial production; supply credit; pressure governments for security of contract and for protection for commerce. Merchants create and manage the institutions required to promote capital formation, commerce, urbanisation and manufacturing. In the fullness of time (in regions and states where conditions are favourable), the national economy matures or 'grows up' into an industrial revolution based upon accelerated technological change. In his perception the industrial revolution emerges out of a very long prior process of Smithian Growth in Western Europe. For at least a century (1651-1756) Britain enjoyed somewhat more widespread and sustained patterns and rates of Smith ian growth and thus moved more rapidly than other regions of Europe (and East Asia) up to that plateau from where technological progress and an Industrial Revolution became potentially likely (and with hind-sight) all too probable. In short, the industrial revolution has been represented as the culmination or 'final stage' of very long and gradual processes of European commercialisation. It is this kind of cyclical, slow growth punctuated by Malthusian problems THE BRITISH t1~DUSTRJAL REVOLUTION AS A CONJUNCTURE IN GLOBAL HISTORY 127 and Boserupian upswings that Schmoller, Weber, Lipson, Braude!, Tilly, Jones, Snooks, Komlos, Jones, De Vries and Van Zanden seem drawn to. That is why they accord limited space in their narratives to the industrial revolution as a conjuncture. They decline to present that transition either as a structural break, or as a peculiarly British episode. Yet the evolutionary approach to the history of modern industrialisation cannot evade the fact that growth accelerated in Britain before many regions of Europe (Holland, Rhineland, Saxony, Switzerland, Southern Netherlands, Bohemia, Northern France). Furthermore (and as we now appreciate), from the last five decades of serious post colonial research on the economies of China, South India, Japan, Southeast Asia and the Ottoman Empire it moved ahead of Asian regions as well. Furthermore, the evidence is now overwhelming that all these regions possessed the range of prerequisites and preconditions for Smithian growth and in some places (e.g. Lingnan, Coromandel, Holland, Bohemia) capabilities were in place for centuries, and certainly several decades, before the networks of communication, property rights, credit systems, legal frameworks, law and order etcetera were there to support British trade, commerce and industrialisation. Did Britain then appear as a latecomer and experience an intensive and more pervasive phase of Smithian growth before the rest, a phase which in some crucial respects carried the economy up to that plateau of possibilities for technological breakthroughs to occur? If so, why? What was there on the off shore islands which differentiated Britain from its rivals and led on to an Industrial Revolution? It is becoming more and more difficult to find 'peculiarly British' preconditions for the encouragement of trade and commerce (comp..ared to that observed for several regions of Europe and Asia), and impossible to substantiate the case that the matrix of laws, institutions and good order for commerce and exchange was discernibly superior in Britain, compared to other parts of Western Europe or even to maritime China, and Tokugawa Japan. Yet it remains the case that industrial growth accelerated in Britain over the late eighteenth century; and that a cluster of inventions for the manufacture of textiles, the smelting and puddling of iron, the generation of energy appeared and diffused first in the British Isles before elsewhere in Europe, let alone Asia. Was there not after all something particularly 'hospitable' about British institutions or especially conducive in British culture that made it 'probable' that accelerated rates of growth and technical progress would occur first in the Hanoverian realm? Only detailed comparative history can settle this kind of question. Meanwhile, it is no longer clear to historians that in Britain the environment for business was clearly superior to frameworks found elsewhere in Europe or in parts of Asia. Unless we are willing to fall back on the unconvincing elaboration of differences in 'cultures' or 'mentalities', the search for clearly 128 \TRICK KARL O'BRIEN 'specified contrasts' which might have made the difference must continue. That search will bring this discussion up-to-date and move us on to the recent and illuminating debate about British economic growth between Crafts and Harley, from the diametric camp on the one side, and Berg, Hudson, Hoppit and Cuenca from a main stream Anglo-centric tradition on the other. The latter will welcome Ken Pomeranz, Jack Goldstone and the Californian School to their ranks because they have been concerned to rehabilitate the industrial revolution from the depredations and denegations of diometricians who, they rightly perceive, have diminished the scale, scope and significance, of that event as a seminal conjuncture in British, European and World History. Rehabilitation is built upon several reaffirmations. First by an unresolved attempt to argue that the discontinuity in growth rates is more pronounced than their opponents suggest. Secondly by repeating traditional views that the technological and organisational changes of the long eighteenth century were more pervasive and in the long run (allowing for lags and time to mature) more significant than econometricians could possible see or take into account in exercises designed to measure shares of the growth rates (of industrial production, agricultural output or for national income as an aggregate) attributable to technological change. In short Berg eta! reject the methodological bases, and theoretical assumption required to measure changes in total factor productivities. They also pour scorn on the range and quality of data. available for such exercises and fall back on examples - case studies of regions, and particular, industries- to revitalise the old story that technological progress was pervasive over time, and that led the economy ever upward and onward through an industrial revolution. The rehabilitatorsinsist that the Industrial Revolution displayed balanced growth, induced by widespread technological, cultural and organisational change, rooted in commercial and scientific culture. It was a macro-economic event and, in all its essentials, British. Their diametric antagonists stand on the numbers which do suggest that technological change emerged gradually; took a long time to impact upon rates of industrial growth and was confined, until the second and third quarters of the nineteenth century, to just a few key sectors of the British economy. But if the Rehabilitation School are correct, then by implication, there must have been something special or 'British' about that economy's long run traJectory of Smithian growth. Landes is prepared to assert that British institutions and culture became superior to other national frameworks for economic activity and at promoting that kind of growth. That is why, in his view, Britain experienced the First Industrial Revolution and why that British conjuncture remains as a paradigm episode in the global history of material progress. Controversy continues, but ifthe diometricians and their numbers are THE BRITISh USTRIAL REVOLUTION AS A CONJUNCTURE IN GLOBAL HISTORY 129 convincing and whole swathes of British industry were not transformed until later in the nineteenth century and technological progress was for decades confined in its over all impact to iron smelting and to cotton textiles, and the precocious release oflabour from agriculture, then a meta problem remains on our agenda for both British and global history. What was it that transformed those particular sectors of the British economy and generated unbalanced growth and competitive advantages in world trade as early as the late eighteenth century? For the sake of drawing endlessly recycled debates to a provisional conclusion, I propose to accept the cliometric representation of Britain's industrialisation, as a case of slow transformation; confined for several decades to iron and to cotton textiles and little else, except for the release of labour from agriculture into proto ('low productivity'), industry and to urban services. Four features of this 'British case' then requires further elaboration and firmer connexion to this contested narrative. All four can be grouped under the heading of 'power'. Power refers to: (a) energy, derived from coal; (b) to coercion, flowing from massive and sustained investments by the Hanoverian state in the Royal Navy; (c) to the deployment of state and monopoly power behind the establishment of a cotton textile industry in England and (d) to geopolitical and geo-economic outcomes of nearly a quarter of a century of warfare, flowing from the French Revolution. Power in its kinetic and political forms has been restored to a place of prominence in recent representations of the First Industrial Revolution which thereby derogate and downgrade older stories, based upon the peculiarities of British culture, the superiority of its liberal institutions, the triumph of private enterprise, and artisanal ingenuity. They emphasise endowments (fecund soils as well as coal) and bring public inyesunent in coercion by an aggressive state backed by jingoistic self-interested populace into the golden triangle of the most up-to-date paintings of the Industrial Revolution. For example, good fortune, or God, provided Britain with an abundant source of energy in the form of accessible supplies of coal. Coal not only supplied a range of heat intensive industries with cheaper fuel, it was a land and labour saving resource and substituted for trees and for the reafforestation of agricultural land. The warmth provided by coal meant labour required fewer calories of basic food to perform manual and other tasks. Feedbacks, spin-offs and externalities from coal were all highly significant. For example, the transportation of coal required ships and seamen (available as a reserve army of sailors in time of war). Coal stimulated massive corporate invesunent in the network of canals (and later railways) which carried the home market and the capital market to higher levels of integration. Connexions from the mining of coal to the development and perfection of steam power are familiar and perhaps the most important spin off to flow from the possession and use of coal. 130 '>ATRJCK KARL O'BRJEN THE BRITISH 131 public investment (as a late comer and free rider), in the violence and protection required to emerge as the lead power and economy in a universe of competing mercantilist states. One way or another - at the beginning of a new century- the heroic quintessentially British industrial revolution as a seminal episode in world history has been reconfigured. The industrial revolution 'aint what it used to be'. Even David Landes now accepts that the British example 'was not a model for the rest of the world given its originality and particular circumstances, it could not be that. But it was both a stimulus and a source of knowledge and experience both negative and positive'. Amenl But how long will it take for other historians (let alone communicators of national myths) to recognise that most of the originality and circumstances behind a long cycle of accelerated growth in the history of just another Eurasian region rested ultimately on kinetic energy and geopolitical power? How and why Britain rather than Holland, France, Switzerland, Flanders, Saxony established Europe's large scale mechanised cotton industry requires geopolitical rather than economic answers. (Although historians must recognise that Britain possessed considerable capacity to manufacture woollen and linen textiles before cotton came on the scene.) The geopolitical story of cotton is one of Asian trade, conducted by a quasi public corporation (the East India Company) and of serious military and naval rivalry with Holland and France. Indeed the matrix within which the cotton textiles evolved into a large scale mechanised industry involved trade with India, the infamous traffic in slaves, import substitution, the pacification of Ireland and the crucial invention of roller spinning by the son of a Huguenot refugee - Monsieur Louis Paul of London. In short the history of the establishment of the paradigm case of large scale reorganised textile production in Britain remains inseparable from mercantilism, imperialism, and connexions with the rest of Europe. The connexion to geopolitical rivalry would be totally unsurprising to the generations of Europeans who lived through the Age of Revolution 1789-1815. During these years of disturbance, havoc and destruction flowing from the French Revolution, 'convergence' in productivity levels across European economies became unusually difficult to achieve. As an island, Britain and its foreign trade was spared the disruption that afflicted its rivals and its economy prospered at their expense. Conclusion At stake in current and unresolved debates about the First Industrial Revolution is how to reconfigure an 'episode' or 'conjuncture' in British history that Anglo-American historians (and many canonical social scientists) have long considered to be a if not the seminal discontinuity in the history of civilisation. By representing Britain's Industrial Revolution as slow growth; as a case of unbalanced and strictly confined technological change and innovation, cliometricians and other revisionists accept: that it was a' discontinuity'; that the first industrial revolution was proceeded by an evolutionary process of Smithian growth and that several important mechanical inventions appeared first in Britain. They reject traditional views which held that the discontinuity was abrupt. They proclaim that the political, legal, cultural and entrepreneurial conditions for Smithian growth were commonplace across several regions on the Eurasian landmass and that Britain had not been proceeding along some unique or exceptional historical trajectory all of its own since the Middle Ages. They demonstrate that several of the technological breakthroughs (macro inventions) that occurred were European, if not Eurasian in origin. The new story maintains that Britain's early start and sustained lead towards the status of the worlds ftrst successful industrial market economy, depended to a very large degree up<m natural endowments and timely USTRlAL REVOLUTION AS A CONJUNCTURE IN GLOBAL HISTORY I I ,~-J......_ 132 \TRJCK KARL O'BRIEN Note * I am grateful to the Editors of Itinerario for publishing this unreferenced lecture in roughly the form I delivered it to their Conference on the European Miracle. I have appended a select bibliography of references (including my own published work) that I consulted and used for purposes of constructing that lecture. I apologise to any scholar whose work has been inadvertently missed from a hurriedly composed bibliography. Bibliography Richard Adams, Paradoxical Harvest: Energy and Explanation in British History-1870-1914 (Cambridge 1982). Derek Aldcroft and Anthony Sutcliffe eds, Europe in the International Economy 1500-2000 (Cheltenham I999). Hans Arndt, Economic Development: The History of an Idea (Chicago 1987). Thomas Ashton, The Industrial Revolution 1760-1830 (Oxford 1948). Paul Bairoch and Maurice Levy-Leboyer eds, Disparities in Economic Development since the Industrial Revolution ( 198I ) . Paul Bairoch, 'International Industrialisation Levels from 1750-1980',journal ofEuropean Economic History 2 (1982) 269-333. Paul Bairoch, Victoires et deboi1·es: Histoire economique et sociale du monde du xvie siecle a nos jours I-III (Paris I998). Jerry Bentley, Old World Encounters (Oxford I993). Maxine Berg and Pat Hudson, 'Rehabilitating the Industrial Revolution', Economic History Review 45 (I992) 24-50. Jim Blaut, The Colonizers Model of the World (New York 1993) and Eight Eurocentn:c Historians (New York 2000). Fernand Braude!, Civilisation and Capitalism, 15th-18th Centuries 1-Ill (London 1984). Ernst Breisach, Historiography. Ancient, Medieval and Modem (Chicago 1983). Kristine Bruland ed., Technology Transfer and Scandinavian Industrialisation (Oxford 1991). David Cannadine, 'The Present and the Past in the English Industrial Revolution l880-I900', Past and Present I03 (1984) I3I-I72. Kirti Chaudhuri, Asia Before Europe (Cambridge 1990). Jonathon Clark, English Society 1688-1932 (Cambridge 1987). Phillip Costello, World Historians and their Goals (Illinois 1993). Nicholas Crafts, British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution (Oxford 1985). Nicholas Crafts, 'British Industrialisation in an International Context',journal ofInterdisciplinary History I9 (I989) 4I5-428. · Nick Crafts and Knick Harley, 'Cotton Textiles and Industrial Output Growth during the Industrial Revolution', Economic History Review 51 (1998) 49-83. Fran~ois Crouzet, 'Wars, Blockades and Economic Change in Europe, 1782-18I5', journal of Economic History 24 ( I964) 98-I25 and Histoire de l'Economie Europeenne 1000-2000 (Paris 2000). Martin Daunton, Progress and Poverty: An Economic and Social History ofBritain I 700-1850 (Oxford I995). Jan de Vries, 'The Industrial Revolution and the Industrious Revolution', Journal of Economic History 54 (1994) 249-270. Jan de Vries and Adriaan van der Woude, The First Modem Economy (Cambridge 1997). Stepan Epstein, Freedom and Growth: The Rise of States and Marhets in Europe 1300-1750 (London 2000). Javier Cuenca Esteban, 'The Rising Share of British Industrial Exports in Industrial Output', journal of Economic History 57 (1997) 879-906. Javier Cuenca Esteban, 'Factory Costs, Market Prices and Indian Calicos Textile Prices Revisited, l779-I831 ',Economic History Review 52 (1999) 749-755. Roderick Floud and Deirdre McCloskey eds, T¥_ Economic History of Britain since 1700 I (Cam- THE BRITISH JSTRIAL REVOLUTION AS A CONJUNCTURE JN GLOBAL HISTORY 133 bridge 1994) . Andre Gunder Frank, ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age (London 1998). Jack Goldstone, 'The Problem of the Early Modern World', journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 41 (1998) 249-284. Knick Harley and Nick Crafts, 'Simulating the Two Views of the Industrial Revolution', Journal of Economic History 60 (2000) 819-841. Max Hartwell, The Industrial Revolution and Economic Growth (London 1971). Max Hartwell, The Industrial Revolution (Oxford 1967). Herodotus, The Histories (London 1983). Marshal Hodgson, Rethinking World History (Cambridge 1993). Julian Hoppit, 'Counting the Industrial Revolution', Economic History Review 42 ( 1990) 173-193. Julian Hoppit and Anthony Wrigley eds, The Industrial Revolution in Britain I-II (Oxford 1994). Bert Hoselitz, Theories of Economic Growth (New York 1960). Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London I992). Robert Jackson, 'Rates of Industrial Growth during the Industrial Revolution', Economic History Review 45 (1992) 1-23. Eric Jones, The European Miracle: Environments, Economies and Geopolitics in the History of Europe and Asia (Cambridge I981) and Growth Recurring: Economic Change in World History (Oxford 1988). Charles Kindleberger, World Economic Primacy 1500-1990 (Oxford 1996). Simon Kuznets, Modem Economic Growth: Ro-te, Structure, and Spread (New Haven 1966) and The Economic Growth of Nations (Cambridge, MA 1971). David Landes, The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present (Cambridge 1970) and The Wealth and Poverty of Nations (London 1998). Alan Macfarlane, The Riddle of the Modern World: OJ Liberty, Wealth, and Equality (London 2000). W. McNeill, The Rise of the West (Chicago 1963) and The Human Condition: An Ecological and Historical View (Princeton 1980). Peter Mathias, The First Industrial Nation (London l 983). Peter Mathias and Munia Postan eds, Cambridge Economic History of Europe Vll, Parts 1 and 2 (Cambridge 1978). Peter Mathias and Davis John eds, The Nature of Industrialisation 1-VI (Oxford 1990-1998). Joel Mokyr ed., The British Industrial Revolution (Oxford 1993) and The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress (Oxford 1990). Karen O'Brien, Narratives of Enlightenment (Cambridge I997). Patrick O'Brien, 'Do we have a typology for the Study of European Industrialisation in the Nineteenth Century?', Journal of European Economic History ( 1986) 291-333. Patrick O'Brien, 'The Political Economy of British Taxation, 1660-1815', Economic History Review 4I (1988) 1-32. Patrick O'Brien and Roland Quinault eds, The Industrial Revolution and British Society (Cambridge 1993). Patrick O'Brien ed., The Industrial Revolution in Europe 2 volumes (Oxford 1994). Patrick O'Brien, 'Global Warfare and Long-Term Economic Development, 1789-1939', War in History 3 (1996). Patrick O'Brien, 'Path Dependency, or Why Britain became an Industrialised and Urbanised Economy long before France', Economic History Review 49 (1996) 213-249. Patrick O'Brien, 'The Britishness of the First Industrial Revolution and the British Contribution for the Industrialisation of "Follower Countries" on the Mainland', Diplomacy and Statecraft (1997) 48-68. Patrick O'Brien and Leandro Prados De La Escosura eds, The Costs and Benefits of European Imperialism from the Conquest of Ceuta (1415) to the Treaty of Lusaka (1974) (special issue of Revista de Historia Economica, Madrid 1998). Sydney Pollard, Peaceful Conquest: The Industrialisation of Europe, 1760-1970 (Oxford 1981) and Typology of Industrialisation Processes in the Nineteenth Century (Chur 1990). Ken Pomeranz., The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Malting of the Modem World Economy 134 PATRICK KARL O'BRIEN (Princeton 2000). Barry M. Radcliffe ed., &eat Britain and her World, 175().1914 (Manchester 1975). Walt Rostow, Theorists of Economic &owth from David Hume to the Present (Oxford 1990). Rafael Samuel, 'The Workshop of the World: Stearn Power and Hand Technology in Victorian Britain', Histury Workshop Joumal3 (1977) 6-72. W. Sewell, 'Marc Bloch and the Logic of Comparative History', Histury and Theury 6 (1967) 208-218. Graham Snooks, The Dynamic Society: Exploring the Sources of Global Change (London 1996). ·Lawrence Stone ed., An Imperial State at War: Britain from 1689 to 1815 (London 1994). K. Sugihara, 'The European Miracle and the East Asian Miracle: Towards a New Global History', Osaka University Economic Review 12 (1996) 16-41. Richard Sylla and Gianni Toniolo eds, Patterns of European Industrialisation in the Nineteenth Century (1991). James Thompson, A History of Historical Writing (London 1942). William Thompson, The Emergence of Global Political Economy (London 2000). Mikulas Teich and R. Porter eds, The Industrial Revolution in National Context (Cambridge 1996). James Tracy ed., The Rise of Merchant Empires 1350.1750 (Cambridge 1990). Nick von Tunzelman, Steam Power and British Industrialisation to 1860 (Oxford 1978). Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System I-III (New York 1974, 1980 and 1988). Max Weber, General Economic Histury (New York 1961). Roy Bin Wong, China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits ofEuropean Experience (Ithaca 1997). Anthony Wrigley, Continuity, Chance, and Change: The Character of the Industrial Revolution in England (Cambridge 1988).
© Copyright 2024 Paperzz