Economic History Association The Development of the National Money Market, 1893-1911 Author(s): John A. James Source: The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 36, No. 4 (Dec., 1976), pp. 878-897 Published by: Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2119244 Accessed: 14/05/2010 16:36 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=cup. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Economic History Association and Cambridge University Press are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Economic History. http://www.jstor.org The Developmentof the National Money Market, 1893-1911 HE period after the Civil War in the United States witnessed a significant narrowing of interregional interest rate differentials and the gradual merger of local markets into an integrated short-term capital market. The movement toward a national money market was one of the majorfinancialdevelopments of the post-bellum period; and Lance Davis's series on gross and net returns on earning assets for national banks (which served as proxies for loan rates) has provided the principal evidence on this phenomenon.' The trend toward integration of regional markets may be seen in Figure 1, which presents the differentials between interior regions and the East of moving averages of semiannual, short-term interest rates of country national banks, 1888-1911.2 These rates, computed as the average rate of return on the loan portfolio, offer more accurate estimates of local interest rates than either Davis's series or Gene Smiley's calculated interest rates.3 More detailed data, semiannually by reserve city and by state for country banks, are available from the author on request. In spite of the fact that much of the convergence took place in the 1880's (as indicated by Davis's series) and that the rate of convergence slowed markedly after the turn of the century, Journal of Economic History, Vol. XXXVI, No. 4 (December 1976). Copyright ? The T Economic History Association. All rights reserved. I Lance E. Davis, "The Investment Market, 1870-1914: The Evolution of a National Market," JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC HISTORY,25 (Sept. 1965), 360-65. 2 East-Maine, N.H., Vt., Mass., R.I., Conn., N.J., Pa., Del., Md., D.C. South-Va., W.Va., N.C., S.C., Ga., Fla., Ala., Miss., La., Tex., Ark., Tenn., Ky. Midwest-Ohio, Ind., Ill., Mich., Wis., Minn., Iowa, Mo., Kans., Nebr., N. Dak., S. Dak. West-Colo., Wyo., Mont., Idaho, Nev., Utah, N. Mex., Ariz., Calif., Oreg., Wash., Okla. The regional interest rate series are weighted averages of the average rate on loans and discounts of country national banks by state, the weights being the relative size of the loan and discount portfolio. 3 For a discussion of the derivation of the local interest rates, see John A. James, "Banking Market Structure, Risk, and the Pattern of Local Interest Rates in the United States, 18931911," Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming. Although constructed from the sanie sources, earnings statements and balance sheets of national banks in the annual reports of the U.S. Comptroller of the Currency, the series here appear to be more accurate than those of Smiley, although the comparison is difficult since their construction is not explicitly reported. For one thing, these series are semiannual, rather than annual. The Smiley series is actually a rate of return on private earning assets, including items such as stocks and bonds, which are separated out of the series here; similarly, here losses are extracted from the reported Losses and Premiums account. Moreover, a correction is made for the growth of the loan portfolio in the derivation here, in order to avoid biasing the computed rates downward. Gene Smiley, "Interest Rate Movement in the United States, 1888-1913," JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC HISTORY, 35 (Sept. 1975), p. 595. 878 National Money Market 879 I-. 2 WlDUE51 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ \ - O~~~~~~~~~~~~ WEST = Z-2 506 A~~~~~~~~ER FIGURE INTERREGIONAL DIFFERENTIALS I SHORT-TERM WITH THE INTEREST RATE EASTERN REGION, COUNTRY BANKS there is in Figure 1 evidence of a general decline in interregional interest rate differentials and the gradual evolution of a national market. The gaps between western and eastern and between midwestern and eastern rates both fall by about one percentage point, or by about 25 and 50 percent respectively. The southern-eastern differential, on the other hand, is much slower to narrow, falling somewhat less than .5 percentage points.4 In his study of interest rate movements over this period, Smiley finds no evidence of regional interest rate convergence for nonreserve city national banks, that is, country banks. He uses the coefficient of variation as a measure of dispersion.5 The coefficient of variation is, however, an inappropriate measure of convergence here, since the focus should not be on convergence from above and below toward some mean interest rate, which has no economic meaning. 4 A similar story is found by examining interest rate movements of the more disaggregated regions reported by the Comptroller of the Currency. The gap between North Central and New England states narrows significantly over the late 1890's, being virtually eliminated by 1900. The differential between the Great Plains and Mountain states and New England narrows by almost two percentage points, or 40 percent, while that between the Mountain and Pacific states and New England falls around one percentage point, or about 25 percent. 5 Smiley, "Interest Rate Movement," p. 600. 880 James Rather, a more suitable measure is the proximity of other regional rates to those in the most developed market, the East. In Figure 1 it is clear that interregional interest rate differentials did narrow over the period and that progress was being made toward the development of a national market.6 How can we account for the interest rate convergence of the post-bellum period? What forces were at work in forming a national money market? In the following pages I examine and test two major hypotheses about this development:7 an Institutional Change hypothesis, which emphasizes the expansion of the commercial paper market in facilitating interregional transfers of funds; and a Market Power hypothesis, which stresses the lowering of legal barriers to entry in banking and the consequent erosion of local monopoly positions. Lance Davis emphasizes the role of institutional change; the westward expansion of the commercial paper market, he says, wove 6 Rather than the coefficient of variation, a more appropriate, although ad hoc, indicator of the rate of convergence would involve some measure of the diminishing differentials between other regions and the East. The square root of the average of squared differentials of other regions with the East, I/ 3 (rf - re)2 is presented here for five year intervals over the period below. 1888 1893 1898 3.737 percent 2.955 percent 3.353 percent 1903 1908 1911 2.748 percent 2.341 percent 2.451 percent The rate of convergence is not uniform, to be sure, but the trend over the period is clearly toward narrowing differentials with eastern rates. Moreover, the rate of convergence slows after 1900, as Davis also finds. 7 Richard Keehn in his study rejecting the Sylla hypothesis attributed the decline in differentials to declines in transfer costs between markets due to technological improvements in transportation and communication. Domestic exchange rates may be taken as a measure of the transfer costs of funds. Even in the 1830's, a period before significant advances in transportation and communication, the highest quoted exchange rate was lower than the western-eastern and southern-eastern differentials over 1888-1911. Those quoted in Bradstreet's in the late nineteenth century were substantially smaller yet. Consequently transfer costs could account for only a small part of the total observed differential. Jeffrey Williamson emphasizes demand rather than supply factors in explaining the movement of the differentials. A relative decline in the demand for funds in the Midwest in the late nineteenth century caused rates there to decline relative to eastern rates and after the turn of the century an increase in demand for funds there led to a relative rise in rates. Thus, the explanation for capital market integration is found in real forces exogenous to the capital market. However, this explanation is limited to the Midwest and does not account for the movement of western and southern differentials. Richard Keehn, "Federal Bank Policy, Bank Market Structure, and Bank Performance: Wisconsin, 1863-1914," Business History Review, 48 (Spring 1974), 1-27. Jeffrey G. Williamson, Late Nineteenth-Century American Development (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1975), pp. 130-32. National Money Market 881 segmented local capital markets together into a national one.8 It was an open market in which borrowers and lenders from many different locations could participate, so its geographical expansion, drawing more and more borrowers and lenders together into one market, was a force making for interest rate equality. In contrast to Davis's picture of widespread barriers to interregional flows of funds, Richard Sylla views the national banking system as a very efficient mobilizer of funds. Indeed, he argues, "It promoted industrial investment and growth with a ruthless efficiency."9 If the national banking system was so efficient, then, why were there interest rate differentials over this period? Sylla answers by pointing to legal barriers to entry established in the National Banking Acts. The tax on state bank notes left national banks in an advantageous position after the Civil War, while relatively high minimum capital requirements and the prohibition of mortgage lending severely restricted entry in rural areas. As a result, many country bankers enjoyed quasi-monopolistic positions. The observed interregional and citycountry interest rate differentials are thus evidence of local monopoly power. 10 This local power in turn is said to have been eroded by the passage of the Gold Standard Act of 1900, which lowered minimum capital requirements for national banks to $25,000 in towns of population less than 3,000. Lowering the legal barriers to entry after 1900 resulted in a rapid increase in the number of national banks in rural areas and, consequently, in a diminution of monopoly premiums and local loan rates primarily in western and southern regions." These hypotheses concerning the development of a national money market have not, however, been tested systematically in a theoretical model.12 To do so, I shall examine the forces underlying regional interest rate convergence, 1893-1911, using a model of local interest rate determination. THE MODEL In order to assess the performance of local capital markets, a model of local interest rate determination, or in other words, a model of 8 Davis, "The Investment Market, 1870-1914," pp. 370-73. 9 Richard Sylla, "The United States, 1863-1913," in Rondo Cameron, ed., Banking and Economic Development (New York: Oxford University Press, 1972), p. 258. 10 Richard Sylla, "Federal Policy, Banking Market Structure, and Capital Mobilization in the United States, 1863-1913," JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC HISTORY, 29 (Dec. 1969), p. 685. 11 Ibid., pp. 664-70. 12 Smiley has considered these two hypotheses by an inspection of the data, but not within a well-defined theoretical model. Smiley, "Interest Rate Movement," pp. 607-10. 882 James bank asset selection, is needed. I use a mean-variancemodel of nineteenth-centurybank portfolio selection based on the capitalasset-pricingmodel.'3 Since the influence of local monopolyon interest rates is to be assessed, it is assumed that the bank faces a downward sloping demand curve for loans. A portfolio selection modelwith an imperfectlycompetitiveasset market,the loan market, is developed, fromwhich it followsthat the expected returnon loans may be expressed as the sum of the standardportfoliotheory risk premiumanda monopolypremium.Transformedinto estimableform the equation may be written Rt = a,1CPt + a2LSt + a3LSt_1 + a4VARt + a5MPt + a6BCt + a7SEASt + a8 + Et (1) where Rtis the averagereal rate of returnon commercialloans, using the Warren-Pearson wholesaleprice indexas a deflator.LStis the loss rateon commercialloansin periodt. VARtis the measureof loan risk, the samplevarianceof the loss rateover the previousfive yearsor ten periods, so its sign shouldbe positive. As riskincreases,localinterest rates should increase. MPt is the monopolypower measure, a bank densityindex-the totalnumberof banks(national,state, and private) per capitain the area, so its sign shouldbe negative. As bankdensity increases, local interest rates should decrease. BCt is the business cycle index, the deviationfrom the trend of bank clearingsoutside New YorkCity. SEAStis a semiannualseasonaldummy. The equation was estimated for country banks by state and for reserve cities on semiannual data from 1893 to 1911 using the Cochrane-Orcuttiterative technique as a correctionfor autocorrelation. The majorityof the estimatedcoefficientsof majorvariablesare significant,and the fits of the regressionsare quite good. In many southern and midwesternstates over 90 percent of the varianceis explained, while on average poorer fits are found in the East and 13 For the derivation see John A. James, "Portfolio Selection with an Imperfectly Competitive Asset Market," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, forthcoming. Several features of nineteenth-century banking greatly simplified the portfolio problem. The benign influence of the real bills doctrine ensured that loans were short-term and thus eliminated the term structure problem. Moreover, liquidity constraints do not seem to have been considered. The assumption of risk aversion in the mean-variance model seems to be a reasonable one. There is no evidence of a well-developed market in bank stock, so it may be assumed that banks were generally closely held by the entrepreneur, who is usually taken to be risk-averse. The Sylla and Keehn models of bank behavior, on the other hand, portray banks as firms, equating marginal revenues and marginal costs on assets; such a characterization misses the essence of choice among varying risks in portfolio selection. John A. James, "The Evolution of the National Money Market, 1888-1911," unpublished MIT Ph.D. thesis, 1974, pp. 301-7. National Money Market 883 West. Space limitations preclude detailed presentation of the regression results, but they are available elsewhere.14 Here we shall be concerned with testing hypotheses in this framework. The formulation allows the role of risk to be taken into account explicitly. Indeed, Stigler has criticized Davis insofar as he identifies the existence of interest rate differentials with capital market imperfections.15 They might reflect, for example, real transactions and information costs. Even in a perfect capital market, rates would not be uniform if loans differed in the degree of risk attached to them across regions. In that case declining interest rate differentials would be evidence of decreases in the relative risk of western and southern loans. 16 In time series regressions of equation (1) the estimated risk coefficient, that of VAR, is significantly positive (as expected) in about one-third of the states. Moreover, my analysis of variance test on the rate of decrease of the sample variance led me to reject the hypothesis -at the 95 percent level-that there were no regional differences;most of the regional variation was provided by the western states.17 In spite of the fact that loan risk may have decreased in interior regions over this period, changes in risk alone can not account for the observed regional interest rate movements. In a cross-section time series regression of country banks across states the estimated risk coefficient was found to be quite small and not significantly positive. In addition, the monopoly power index was significant, indicating that changes in local market structure and monopoly power did have a significant influence on local interest rates.18 In brief, I could reject 14 For detailed information about the transformation of the theoretical risk-return relationship into estimable form, construction of the variables, and regression results see James, "Banking Market Structure." 15 George Stigler, "Imperfections in the Capital Market,"Journal of Political Economy, 75 (June 1967), 288. 16 Smiley suggests that his finding of no interest rate convergence over this period may have been due to an increase in risk aversion of bankers, although risk is not explicitly measured. Smiley, "Interest Rate Movement," pp. 600-5. 17 The estimated coefficients from a simple regression of the VAR series by state on a time trend were regressed in turn on regional dummies. VAR =-.00045 DEAST (-.06) R2 = .17 - .0016 DSOUTH (0.23) - .00085 DMW - .0267 DWEST (-.11) (-3.47) F(3,41) = 2.99 Even though the groupings are not significant, the magnitudes of the coefficients across regions are consistent with out expectations, the smallest decline being in the East, then the Midwest, the South, and finally the West with the largest decline. 18 In a cross-section time series regression for reserve cities, however, the estimated VAR coefficient was significantly positive and of substantial magnitude, perhaps indicating that closer 884 James the hypothesis that a perfect market existed; in order to have some degree of local monopoly power, capital markets must have been geographically separated to some extent. Decreases in risk differentials were not sufficient to explain the observed narrowing of interregional interest rate differentials, even though such changes may have been important in such areas as the West. Capital market integration was a complex process, and while declining risk played a role in that process, the national money market must have been in some degree imperfect. Barriers to capital mobility must have existed or else capital flows would have equalized rates. Consequently, we must examine the Institutional Change and Market Power hypotheses, both of which are based on the existence of an imperfect national capital market. THE INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE HYPOTHESIS According to the Institutional Change hypothesis, the westward spread of the commercial paper market broke down the barriers to capital mobility and reduced interregional interest rate differentials. But the westward expansion of the commercial paper market was not as clear-cut and easily identifiable a process as the one Davis has pictured by chronicling the westward march of commercial paper house openings.19 Interior banks were never really isolated from the commercial paper market since they could always have participated in it through the New York correspondent bank that virtually every country bank had. Travelling salesmen were also a common method of dealing with distant customers. In addition, it is very difficult to identify the influence of the commercial paper house in any particular community. Just because a house was established in a city in a given year, it does not follow that it began to exert an influence on loan rates immediately. In Minneapolis or St. Paul, a note broker was in operation as early as 1875, but it was not until 1900 that banks in moderate-sized Minnesota towns had become purchasers of commercial paper.20 The rate of dissemination of commercial paper from the city into the countryside is difficult to determine. Nevertheless, in testing this hypothesis, I rely on tests of the timing of the spread of the commercial paper market because this is market integration among cities allowed banks to reduce risk. For the complete regression results see James, "Banking Market Structure." 19 Davis, "The Investment Market, 1870-1914," p. 372. 20 Albert 0. Greef, The Commercial Paper House in the United States (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1938), p. 39. National Money Market 885 the only developmenton whichwe have information;detaileddataon the volume of commercialpaper transactionsin local marketsdo not seem to have been compiled. As a result, I employ a post hoc, ergo propterhoc analysiswhichcomparesthe timingof the introductionof a commercialpaperhouse into an areaor the date at which such paper began to be purchasedlocally in relativelysubstantialamountswith the pattern of local interest rates.21 The introductionof commercialpaperin an area might affectlocal loan ratesthroughboth demandand supplyeffects.An increasein the supply of commercialpaper meant that local firms had alternative formsof financing,enablingthem to escape a localbankingmonopoly. The spreadof commercialpaperinto an areashouldhave reducedthe monopolypower of local banks. On the demandside, the commercialpaper marketallowedbanks to diversifytheir portfoliosacrossregions. Smallcountrybankspreviously restricted to makingloans in local areas, where default risks were likely to be highly correlated,could then in effect makeloansin other regions and industries, where the risks were independent or only weakly correlatedwith those on local loans. Giving the bank a wider geographicalareaover whichto loan enabledit to avoidsome of the local risk, such as weather conditions,thereby reducingthe risk on its total portfolio.There should, as a result, have been a decrease in the loss rate and its varianceand thus in the interest rate. First let us considerthe demandside effects. I performeda Chow test on the estimated VAR coefficient in equation (1) to determine whether the introductionof the paper marketresulted in a decrease in portfoliorisk. The date at which local banks began to purchase open-marketpaper can be identified for two reserve cities; banksin both St. Louis and KansasCity did not start investing substantial sums in open-marketpaperuntil after 1897. Similarly,countrybanks in several midwesternstates-Minnesota, North Dakota, Nebraska, and Kansas-began purchasingcommercialpaper aroundthe turn of the century.22The Chow test results are reportedin Table 1. The results are inconclusive.There seems to be a definite shift in the KansasCity coefficient,but on the other hand, no effect can be seen in St. Louis. For countrybanks, there is evidence of a shift in Minnesotaand North Dakota, but not in Kansasand Nebraska. 21 Smiley suggests that the expansion of the commercial paper market over the period 1907-1909 may have led to interest rate convergence, but does not explicitly test the proposition. Smiley, "Interest Rate Movement," pp. 607-9. 22 Greef, The Commerical Paper House in the United States, p.48. 886 James TABLE 1 CHOW TEST ON VAR COEFFICIENT FOR THE EFFECTS OF PORTFOLIO DIVERSIFICATION St. Louis Kansas City Minnesota Nebraska Kansas North Dakota a b F(1,21) F(1,21) F(1,21) F(1,21) F(1,21) F(1,16) = = = = = = .966 10.054a 7.319a 3.553 2.301 4.711b Significant at 1 percent level. Significant at 5 percent level. On the supply side, the introductionof a commercialpaper dealer into an area enabled a local firm to borrowfrom thousandsof banks across the United States by selling its paper to the note broker, thereby limiting the monopoly premium which local banks could extract.There shouldhave been a smallerdegree of monopolypower after the introductionof the commercialpaper market, so there shouldbe a fall in the magnitudeof the MP coefficient.I did a Chow test to determine whether the MP coefficienthas shifted for every reservecity in whichI couldidentifythe date of the firstsales of openmarketpaper.23Those test results appearin Table 2. As the reader TABLE 2 CHOW TEST ON MP COEFFICIENT AROUND BEGINNING OF COMMERCIAL PAPER SALES Cities Year of First Sale San Francisco Portland Columbus Dallas 1900 1906 1907 1910 F statistic F(1,31) F(1,8) F(1,7) F(1,3) = 21.785a = 3.096b = 1.719 = 1.793 a Significant at 1 percent level. b Significant at 10 percent level. can see, the San Franciscoregressionclearly indicatesa shift in the MP coefficient;evidence fromthe other regressions,however, is less conclusive. Since my tests thus far have relied on the exacttimingof the introduction of the commercialpaper market(which might be measured ratherimprecisely),I also decided to use a weaker, less restrictive test. It is clear that even in cities in which the open marketwas established,there shouldhave been a decline in the monopolypower of local banks if the size of the marketwas growing. Thus, the MP 23 For identification of the starting date of commercial paper sales in various cities see Greef, p. 39. Chester A. Phillips, Bank Credit, (New York: Macmillan Co., 1920), p. 135. National Money Market 887 coefficientshouldhave become more positiveover time. To test this, equation (1) was re-estimated including a slope dummy, MPDM, which was one over the second halfof the period. The MP coefficient growsmorepositive over time if the monopolypower associatedwith a given marketstructureis decreasing;therefore, the slope dummy should be positive. This test does not depend on the exact timing of the spreadof the open market,only on the fact that a given market structureshouldresultin less marketpowerover time, if competition from commercialpaper was increasing. Table 3 presents the estimates of the slope dummy coefficients. The signs are mixed, but negative signs, the "wrong"sign, predominate. Only three cities have significantlypositive coefficients. TABLE 3 ESTIMATED MP SLOPE DUMMY COEFFICIENTS RESERVE CITY BANKS (T STATISTICS IN PARENTHESES) East BOS NYC ALB PHILA MP Dummy South NO 14.94a (2.81) 9.206 (.96) -3.815 (-1.06) 2.563 SAV HOU DAL BALT -1.539 (-.92) 3.364 BROOK 3.901 (.97) CIN -.1594 CLEV (-.13) 4.346 (.69) -2952 West SF CHI DET -1.577 (-.69) -1958 (-.31) -6.034 PORT LA -18.69 (-1.15) - 7.337a (-2.17) MP Dummy -9.166a (-2.70) - 10.77a (-2.72) -22.95 (-1.10) 15.03 (1.23) MILW ST L (-.70) (.49) WASH Midwest (-.63) (.49) PITT MP Dummy -6.132 (-.91) -11.86a (-2.07) KC OMA ST J -.2206 (-.10) _3.144a (-2.78) -1.395 (-.87) MINN -.8751 (-.20) ST P -.2465 (-.04) -1.643 DM (-.90) LINC IND COL KK 7.423a (2.92) 4.877 (.96) 23.30a (4.06) .4849 (.09) a Significant at 1 percent level. 888 James On the whole, my conclusionis that the commercialpaper market was not responsible for long-run declines in monopoly power and interest rates. Thus introductionof the commercialpaper marketin an areadoes not seem to have had a significantimpacton localinterest rateseither throughdemandinfluences (portfoliodiversificationand risk reduction)or throughsupplyinfluences(thatis, reductionin the monopoly power of local banks).To be sure, the evidence is somewhatmixed and in certain local marketscommercialpaper may have had a significanteffect. Nevertheless, there does not appearto be a systematic patternof shifts in the risk or monopolypower coefficientsafter the appearanceof a commercialpaper dealer. Furthermore,the general patternsof regionalinterest rate movementsare not consistentwith the pace of expansionof the commercial paper market.ConsiderFigure 1. The commercialpaper marketdid not reach the PacificCoast until 1900. Substantialrelative interest rate declines, however, took place in the western states before that date, and hence cannotbe accountedfor by the influenceof commercial paper.24On closerinspection,the patternof regionalinterestrate movementsis not consistentwith the timing of the expansionof the commercialpaper market. THE MARKET POWER HYPOTHESIS Cross-sectionregressionsfor selected dates indicate, however, that local bankingmarketstructureor monopolypower was quite important in accountingfor interstate variationin country bank interest rates. In addition, in the time series regressionsof equation (1) by state for country banks, the estimated MP coefficients are almost alwayssignificantfor states outside the East.25Statisticalsignificance alone revealslittle about the explanatorypower of a variable.In this case, however,the ceteris paribussimulatedeffects of changesin the MP variableover the period accountfor almost all of the observed interest rate declines of countrybanksin most states, especially for the Southand Midwest.26Decreases in local monopolypowerappear 24 This case is strengthened by examining more finely drawn regions. For example, it was noted that country banks in the Great Plains began buying paper around 1900: however, there also were substantial declines in interregional differentials before 1900. 25 In the South and Midwest, for example, virtually every state has a negatively signed and significant MP coefficient. For the complete list of estimated regression coefficients see James, "Banking Market Structure." 26 For the simulated magnitudes see James, "The Evolution of the National Money Market, 1888-1911," p. 542. 889 National Money Market to have been the most importantfactorsaccountingfor the narrowing of inter-regionalinterest rate differentials.In this section we shall examine why local monopolypower was eroded. As we have noted, the Syllahypothesisfocuseson the effectsof the Gold StandardAct of 1900; by lowering entry barriers,it brought abouta rapidincreasein the numberof nationalbanksin ruralareas. But consider Figure 1 again. Most of the decline in interregional interest rate differentialsactuallyoccurredprior to 1900. The Sylla hypothesis cannot explain the substantialnarrowingof differentials before 1900. The patternof interestrate differentialspredictedby his hypothesisis, in fact, the opposite of the patternthat can be seen in Figure 1. Whateffectsdid the Gold StandardAct have on bankingstructure? Figure 2, which is based on National MonetaryCommissionstatisFIGURE 2 N.M.C. SERIES OF PRIVATE, STATE, AND NATIONAL BANKS, 1877-1909 12,000 - - - - ~- 11, 000 Xfa 10,000W< - 9,000 - - - -- - 8,000 - - _ -- L X 7,000 6, 000 _ -07 -0 5,000 State - Private _Yl Natsonal v- ------------ Barks - - Year 1877 Banks .- 4,C000,- 3, 13 Banks 1881 1885 - -1889 .L.X 1893 11897 1901 1905 1909 Source: George E. Barnett, State Banks and Trust Companies since the Passage of the National Bank Act (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1911), p. 202. tics, presentsthe growthof national,state, and privatebanksbetween 1877 and 1909. Over the 1890's the number of nationalbanks remained quite steady, while the number of state banks almost doubled. After 1900 both state and nationalbanks grew rapidly, and nationalbankscertainlydid not have a dominantrole in the general 27 expansion. 27 The increase in the rate of formation of both state and national banks after 1900 suggests that they were affected by some common influence such as the business cycle. If lowered legal 890 James The Sylla hypothesis overstates the influence of the Gold Standard Act of 1900 on the net rate of bank formation. Many of the new national banks were merely conversions or reorganizations of existing state banks. Thornton Cooke in a 1901 article pointed out that the law had been anticipated; in the six months following the passage of the Gold Standard Act, not one new (as opposed to converted) national bank was established in North Dakota. In South Dakota and Missouri only one was added, in Nebraska and Kansas only two. In these five states the new law resulted in a net addition of six banks over the six month period; in contrast, eighty-five new state banks and ten new private banks were organized during the same months. Even though the new law had substantial effects in some states in which state bank minimum capital requirements were relatively high,28 its impact on local market structure is likely to be greatly exaggerated if one examines only the rate of national bank formation. This discussion and Figure 2 point up the fact that one of the principal difficulties with the Sylla hypothesis is its relative neglect of the role of state banks. The argument is focused on changes in the number of national banks, leaving state banks on the periphery; this is done in spite of the fact that the state institutions far out-numbered national banks and were growing more rapidly at this time. Except for 1901, national banks always totaled less than one-third of all newly created banks-despite the passage of the Gold Standard Act in 1900.29 In addition, the greatest growth in state banks was in the interior regions, the areas where monopoly was supposedly the strongest. In New England the number of state banks in 1909 was exactly the same as in 1879, and in the eastern states as a whole the number of state banks increased between 1879 and 1909 by only 105 percent; on the other hand, in the middle western and western states the increases were 1, 160 percent and 1, 198 percent, respectively.30 Banking services were becoming much more readily available than the Sylla hypothesis indicates. In 1908 it was observed, "Almost every barriers to entry in the National Banking Act had been the principal influence, no influence on the formation of state banks should be observed. If anything, the rate of state bank formation should have decreased with the lowering of national bank capital requirements. 28 For example, in Texas where state banks were still forbidden, thirty-four new national banks were organized over the same period. In Iowa, where the state minimum capital requirement was $25,000, the same as the national one, thirty-two new national banks were organized. Thornton Cooke, "The Effect of the New Currency Law on Banking in the West," QuarterlyJournal of Economics, 15 (Feb. 1901), 278-80. 29 All-Bank Statistics, p. 32. 30 George E. Barnett, State Banks and Trust Companies since the Passage of the NationalBank Act (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1911), p. 202. National Money Market 891 municipalcommunitythroughoutthe length andbreadthof our country has its bankinginstitutionand in manyof the smallaggregationsof not more than 1,000 population we find more than one banking "31 Indeed, towns as small as Battle Creek, institutionprospering. Iowa, with a population of 688 in 1915, had three banks; North Liberty, Iowa, with a populationof under 200, had two banks in 1918.32This proliferationof bankswas not looked upon favorablyby some of the bankersthemselves:"So numeroushave countrybanks become that a state of competitionexists, so excessive as seriouslyto threaten the welfare of the banks, and, to a materialdegree, demoralize the people through too cheap credit."33Another banker complainedthat "morethan a fair averageprofit cannot be realized ... It is whether... suitableamendmentsto statelawsshouldnot be interposed to prevent more than a limited number of banks to the local assessed valuation."34 How can we accountfor this impressivegrowthof statebanksin the post-bellumperiod?One possibilityis that the shiftin preferencesfor holding money in the form of deposits rather than specie, as evidenced by the rapid rise of the deposit-currencyratio, lessened the disadvantage at which the non-note-issuing banks operated immediatelyafterthe CivilWar.35In his studyof post-bellumWisconsin banking,RichardKeehn finds that the rapidspreadof deposit banking made state banks close substitutesfor nationalones.36 Table 4 presents the minimum capital requirements for state banks in 1895 and 1909. If state and nationalbankswere relatively close substitutes, the lowered national bank capital requirements should have had relativelylittle influence on bankformation.In the great majorityof states the minimumcapitalrequirementwas below $25,000.37 In New England states in which banks were incorporated 31 A. E. Padgett, "The Multiplication of Banks," Proceedings of the South Carolina Bankers' Association, 1908, p. 126. 32 Howard H. Preston, History of Banking in Iowa (Iowa City: State Historical Society of Iowa, 1922), p. 354. 33 "Country Credit Methods," Proceedings of the Maryland Bankers' Association, 1914, p. 47. 34 T. H. Hinchman, Banks and Banking in Michigan (Detroit: M. Graham, 1887), p. 170. 35 Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963), p. 122. On the other hand, state banks might not have been severely handicapped by the loss of the privilege of note issue even relatively early in the post-bellum period. In 1881, the earliest observation date, checks rather than currency constituted over 70 percent of total receipts of national banks in all rural regions except the Pacific states. U.S. Comptroller of the Currency, Annual Report, 1881 (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1881), pp. 17-19. 36 Keehn, "Federal Bank Policy," p. 27. 37 Private banks, unincorporated banks not generally subject to state regulations, should also TABLE 4 MINIMUM CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS FOR STATE BANKS 1909 1895 State Change EAST Maine New Hampshire Vermont Massachusetts Rhode Island Connecticut New York New Jersey Pennsylvania Delaware Maryland Virginia West Virginia North Carolina South Carolina Georgia Florida Alabama Mississippi Louisiana Texas Arkansas Tennessee Kentucky Ohio Indiana Illinois Michigan Wisconsin Minnesota Iowa Missouri Kansas Nebraska North Dakota South Dakota Colorado New Mexico Arizona Utah Wyoming Montana Idaho Nevada Washington Oregon California Oklahoma $ $ _-a b b b 50,000 b b b b b b b 25,000 50,000 25,000 25,000 50,000 50,000 b 0 0 -25,000 b 50,000 SOUTH 10,000 25,000 b 0 25,000 15,000 50,000 0 100,000 10,000 -40,000 10,000 25,000 5,000 0 15,000 15,000 15,000 10,000 10,000 0 0 0 -10,000 0 -35,000 + 10,000 -90,000 10,000 __a 0 b 0 15,000 0 MIDWEST 25,000 25,000 25,000 15,000 25,000 10,000 25,000 10,000 5,000 5,000 5,000 5,000 25,000 25,000 25,000 20,000 10,000 10,000 25,000 10,000 10,000 10,000 10,000 10,000 0 0 0 +5,000 WEST 30,000 30,000 10,000 30,000 -20,000 0 0 b 0 0 0 +5,000 +5,000 +5,000 +5,000 0 b 10,000 25,000 -15,000 10000 b 20,000 20,000 0 10,000 10,000 b b 10,000 25,000 -15,000 10,000 b 25,000 5,000 b +20,000 10.000 a No state banks Capital individually determined Source: U.S. Comptroller of the Currency, Annual Report, 1985 (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1896), pp. 38-60, 111-169. George E. Barnett, State Bank and Trust Companies (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1911), p. 43. b 892 National Money Market 893 by specialact, the capitalwas fixedforeach bankby the legislature.In the eastern states and the most easterly midwestern states (Ohio, Indiana, and Illinois), the minimum capital requirementwas relatively high, usuallyaround$25,000. On the other hand, in the less dense, more rural states of the South and West, the minimum requirementwas usuallymuch lower, mostly rangingbetween $10,000 and $15,000.38 On average between 1895 and 1909 there was a decreasein capitalrequirementswhere they had been relativelyhigh in 1895. On the other hand, severalstates in the GreatPlains,where requirements-$5,000-were quite low in 1895, raised them to $10,000 after finding bankswith a very small capitalunsatisfactory. Over the period there was thus a convergence toward minimum capitalrequirementsof $10,000-$15,000. Did these low minimum capital requirements, especially the $5,000 minimumin the Great Plainsstates, actuallyencouragebank formationin small towns and erode local monopolies?In North and South Dakotavirtuallyall state bankswere located in towns with a populationof 1,000 or less. In North Dakota47 out of 71 state banks had a capitalof $10,000or less; in SouthDakota,48 out of 76. In both Kansasand Nebraskathree-quartersof the state bankshad capitalsof under $25,000, the level to which the nationalbankrequirementwas loweredin 1900. Thirteentownsin Nebraskawith a populationof less than one hundredhad state banks,and there were eight such villages in Kansas.39Clearly,low minimumcapitalrequirementsdid encourage the development of banking in small towns. High capital requirements prevented the establishmentof nationalbanks in these towns, but bankingservices were provided by state institutions. To determine the effect state minimumcapitalrequirementshad on the structureof interest rates, the countrybank interest rates of be mentioned. On the whole they were quite small and provided banking facilities in very small towns which could not support a larger bank. For example, in Wisconsin in 1890 one-third of private banks had capital of less than $5,000 and two-thirds had capital of less than $15,000. How could any bank possess monopoly power as long as private banks could be established with no minimum capital? Apparently private banks were not perfect substitutes for chartered banks. The public seemed to put a premium on soundness and felt more comfortable with chartered banks as a result. Nevertheless, private banks did to some extent act as an offset to high capital requirements. In the period immediately after the Civil War private banks grew very rapidly, providing alternatives to the relatively difficult-to-establish national banks; later, in the 1880's, state banks became viable alternatives to national ones, and the growth of private banks essentially stopped. Theodore A. Andersen, A Century of Banking in Wisconsin (Madison: State Historical Society of Wisconsin, 1954), pp. 62-63. 38 In 1909 only four states had no minimum capital requirements for state banks-Arizona, Arkansas, South Carolina, and Tennessee. In these states state banks were organized under the business incorporation law and like other corporations the size of capital was at the discretion of the incorporators. Barnett, State Banks, p. 36. 39 Thornton Cooke, "Distribution of Small Banks in the West," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 12 (Oct. 1897), 71. 894 James 1909 were regressed on 1909 state minimum capital requirements (representing barriers to entry) and on the distance of the major city in the state from New York City (representing the ease of capital flow from the national to the local market). The cross section was weighted by the proportion of state loans and discounts to total loans and discounts as a correction for heteroscedasticity. The regression results appear below. R = .0892 CPTL + .00296 DIST + .01608 (11.87) (7.68) (1.92) R2 = .834 F(2,45) = 113.19 (2) The CPTL coefficient is positive and highly significant, so that lower state minimum capital requirements are associated with lower local interest rates, ceteris paribus. The DIST coefficient has a positive sign, as expected, and is also highly significant. State minimum capital requirements definitely seem to be important factors in explaining cross-sectional differences in interest rates. The effects of state bank minimum capital requirements should appear in the time series also. I regressed the change in interest rates, 1888-1911, by state, on the 1909 minimum state capital requirements; the results are: AR = .0767 CPTL (2.39) R2 = .110 - 3.097 (-5.20) F(1,46) = 5.704 (3) The CPTL coefficient is positive and significant. States in which there were lower bank capital requirements experienced a larger fall in interest rates, ceteris paribus. Lower state bank capital requirements are associated with lower interest rates in the cross section and in the time series. Clearly, lower requirements allowed more banks to be established in small towns because they lowered entry barriers; as a result, local monopoly power should have been diminished. If so, there should be a relationship between state bank capital requirements and the estimated MP coefficients from equation (1): the more negative the MP coefficient, the larger the degree of monopoly power. The estimated MP coefficients for country banks by state were regressed on 1909 minimum capital requirements for state banks and state population density (which was included to correct for differences in population structure across states). Other things being equal, a bank in a lower density region should have more monopoly power since the im- National Money Market 895 mediateareacan supportfewer banks.The regressionis weighted by the t statisticsof the MP coefficientsto emphasizethe more accurate estimates. MPC = .0810 DNS - 1.349 CPTL - .1687 (1.15) (-3.12) (-1.13) R2 = .195 F(2,45) = 5.446 (4) The lower the capital requirement, the smaller the degree of monopoly power should be and hence the more positive the MP coefficient. The CPTL coefficient is in fact significantlynegative, indicatinga definiterelationshipbetween minimumstatebankcapital requirementsand the degree of monopolypower. Lower state bank capitalrequirementsencouragedthe growth of state banks, as did an importantchange in the institutionalsetting. The passageof generalbankincorporationlaws by manystates stimulated the rapid growth of state banks after the mid-1880's. Bank incorporationin manystateshad been a difficultprocessin the period followingthe Civil War. At the extreme, the Texas constitutionof 1876 prohibitedthe charteringof state banks,a ban which remained in effectuntil 1905.As late as 1870, the specialcharterwas, with a few exceptions, the only means of incorporatinga bank.40 In Illinois between 1870 and 1888 the state legislaturegrantedno bankchartersat all becauseof the constitutionalprohibitionof special charters and the absence of a general banking law. This clearly encouragedthe establishmentof nationalbanks. A free bankinglaw was finallypassed in Illinois in 1887.41Manywestern states adopted free bankingprovisionsin their constitutionsabout this time: North Dakota,South Dakota, Montana,Wyoming, Idaho, and Washington in 1889, Utah in 1895. Most southernstates adoptedgeneralbanking rules at this time. Mississippi did so in 1890, Alabamain 1901, Virginiain 1902. The New Englandstates resisted the trend toward free state banking until after the turn of the century. By 1910, however, all eastern states except Delaware and Marylandhad adopted such laws.42The passageof these laws in most of the states greatly facilitatedstate bank formation. The Sylla hypothesis then is correct in identifyingdifferencesin local monopolypoweras a principalcause of interregionaldifferences 40 Barnett, State Banks, pp. 23, 32. Dan M. Dailey, "The Development of Banking in Chicago before 1890," (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Northwestern University, 1934), pp. 309, 355. 42 Barnett, State Banks, p. 31. Leonard C. Helderman, National and State Banks (Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co., 1931) pp. 161-62. 41 896 James in interestrates. It is also correctin attributingthe narrowingof those differentialsto the erosion of that power. The hypothesis does not, however, correctlyanalyzethe mechanismwhich broughtaboutthat erosion. The lowering of nationalbank capital requirementsby the Gold StandardAct of 1900 could not have produced the observed patternof differentials.The mistakewas in concentratingon national banksand neglectingthe role of state banks,which were much more numerousand growing more rapidlyat this time. High minimumcapitalrequirementsfor nationalbanksrestricted entry in small towns, but state banksdeveloped as substitutes. Differencesin state bankminimumcapitalrequirementswere important in accounting for cross-sectionaldifferences in interest rates and stateswith lower capitalrequirementsalso showedgreaterdeclines in interestratesover time. The erosionof localmonopolypowerwas due primarilyto the growth of state rather than of nationalbanks. The organizationof statebankswas encouragedby lower minimumcapital requirementsand alsoby the passageof generalbankinglawsin many states in the late nineteenth century.43 CONCLUSIONS Over the post-bellum period in the United States interregional interest rate differentialsnarrowedsubstantially.In this paper two majorhypothesesconcerningthe forcesbehind this trend have been examinedand tested in a model of local interest rate determination with an imperfectlycompetitiveloan market.Thus the effects of risk andlocalbankmarketstructureon the courseof averagelocal interest rates could be assessed. Even though risk on loans declined and may have had significant effects on local interest rates in some areas (such as the western states),changesin riskdifferentialscouldaccountfor only a smallpart of the observed changes in interest rate differentials.The national money marketin the post-bellumperiod had achieved only partial integration,since in most stateslocal marketstructureand monopoly power had a significantinfluenceon local interest rates, a conclusion supportedby both time series and cross-sectiontime series regressions. The short-termcapitalmarketwas segmented to some extent, but 43 This conclusion is consistent with Rockoff's suggestion that free banking laws improved the allocation of bank capital in the antebellum period. Hugh Rockoff, "The Free Banking Era: A Reexamination," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 6 (May 1974), 157-63. National Money Market 897 it does not appearthat the expansionof the commercialpapermarket had much to do with weakeningthe barriersto capitalmobility. In only a few areasdid the introductionof commercialpaper appearto have significanteffects. The pattern of the narrowinginterregional interest rate differentialsdoes not fit well with the timing of the spreadof the commercialpaper market. The Sylla hypothesis, which emphasizedmarketimperfectionsin the nationalbankingsystem and the role of the Gold StandardAct of 1900, does not fit the observed patternof interest rate differentials. The erosion of local monopoly power was the principalreason for narrowinginterest rate differentials,but, contra Sylla, this resulted from the growth of state banks. Lower capital requirements,more liberalregulations,and, afterthe 1880's,the passageof generalbanking laws which made incorporationmuch easier encouragedthe formation of state banks rather than of nationalbanks. These institutionswere primarilyresponsibleforbreakingdownlocal monopolies. Both the InstitutionalChange and the MarketPower hypotheses are based on the assumptionthat local monopolypower existed. In the formercase it was diminishedby the introductionof commercial paper and the resultantcapitalinflowfrom East to West. Decreased barriersto capitalmobilityallowed a larger flow of capitalinto high interest rate areas, thereby promotinginterest rate convergence.On the other hand, the MarketPower hypothesis focuses on the local marketstructureratherthan on increasesin the supply of funds. If state bankswere establishedwith localfunds, then there would have been a decline in localinterest rateswithoutany capitalinflow.44My analysis indicates that reductions in the barriers to interregional capital mobility were much less significantthan were changes the states made in the legal frameworkof banking;these latter changes encouragedthe growthof state banksand were, apparently,the most importantfactorsaccountingfor the decreasesin interest rate differentials. JOHN A. JAMES, University of Virginia " The Davis hypothesis emphasizing the spread of the commercial paper market postulates a net flow of funds from East to West, while, on the other hand, Sylla emphasizes the flow from the countryside to the cities through the mechanism of bankers' balances. It can be shown that unless the eastern interregional balance of trade surplus was enormous, close to $1 billion per year over the period 1900-1910, the direction of short-term capital flow must have been from West to East, a result consistent with the observations of contemporaries concerning the concentration of funds in New York through the system of bankers' balances and also consistent with the function of New York as a financial intermediary. The Market Power hypothesis fits quite well with this picture of capital flows, but the Institutional Change hypothesis does not. James. "The Evolution of the National Money Market, 1888-1911," pp. 200-12.
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz