ABSTRACT RELATING LEVERAGE TO BANKING MARKET STRUCTURE: THE CASE OF RAILROADS IN ANTEBELLUM AMERICA by Nathan Andrew Klyn The free-banking era provides a unique time period to study bank market structure. Using data from historical maps and the Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research Censuses of the United States, I build upon previous research to investigate the relationship between railroads and antebellum banks from 1854-60. I first use simple ordinary least squares models to estimate the equilibrium relationships between railroads and balance sheet composition. I then estimate an endogenous market structure model that relates railroads to unobserved bank profitability through the number of observed banks. I find that railroads increased bank lending but reduced bank leverage (as related to banknotes), suggesting that railroads caused banks to shift their business emphases. My results further indicate that railroads had a net negative effect on banking profitability. I conclude that reduced bank leverage, as opposed to increased banking activity through lending, increased antebellum bank stability. Relating Leverage to Banking Market Structure: The Case of Railroads in Antebellum America A Thesis Submitted to the Faculty of Miami University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts Department of Economics by Nathan A. Klyn Miami University Oxford, Ohio 2014 Advisor Dr. Charles Moul Reader Dr. William Even Reader Dr. Gregory Niemesh Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Literature Review 2.1 Free Banking Era . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.2 Endogenous Market Structure Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 3 6 3 Bank Balance Sheet 3.1 Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.2 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.3 Estimation Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 7 7 8 4 Endogenous Market Structure 4.1 Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.2 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.3 Estimation Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 11 14 16 5 Appendicies 5.1 Appendix A: Drought Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.2 Appendix B: Railroad Map Sources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 20 21 6 References 23 7 Tables 26 8 Figures 40 ii List of Tables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 Bank Data Description . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Bank Data Summary Statistics . . . . . . . . . . Levels of Asset, Loan and Specie Models . . . . . Level of Banknote Circulation Model . . . . . . . Specie-to-Assets Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Loan-to-Assets Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Circulation-to-Specie Model . . . . . . . . . . . . Endogenous Market Structure Data Description . Endogenous Market Structure Summary Statistics Duopoly-Plus Ordered Probit Models . . . . . . . Triopoly-Plus Ordered Probit Models . . . . . . . Cross Section Threshold Estimates . . . . . . . . Pooled Ordered Probit Models . . . . . . . . . . . Pooled Cross Section Threshold Estimates . . . . iii . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 List of Figures 1 2 Spread of Railroads Across the United States . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Spread of Railroads and Banks Across the United States . . . . . . . iv 40 41 1 Introduction Large bank leverage ratios, such as debt-to-equity, prior to the last recession had disastrous effects on the global economy. Regulators are consequently working to find a way to increase stability in the banking sector. A difficult and important question regarding contemporary banking regulation is: Would added bank regulation lead to a less competitive banking structure and less competitive banking behavior? Banks seek high leverage ratios to maximize profits during economic expansions. Some regulators believe that lower leverage ratios will lead to a more stable banking industry but United States banks are disinclined to accept lower leverage ratios. Globally, the fall in domestic profits due to lower leverage ratios may lead to competitively disadvantaged United States banks. The lower profits may lead to fewer banks with higher interest rates and less investment. There is a societal trade off between bank stability and interest rates. All else equal, a highly leveraged banking sector has higher profits, more banks, and lower interest rates with consequent increased economy-wide investment. Conversely a highly leveraged banking sector, though, is exposed to major boom and bust cycles. A less leveraged banking sector has lower bank profits, fewer banks, higher interest rates, and lower investment, and is not as susceptible to the booms and busts1 . A study on contemporary banking leverage ratios, regulation and bank stability would be quite difficult due to the globalization of banking. To perform such a study on the relationship between leverage and bank stability, I turn back the clock to the free banking era. During the free banking era state, not federal, laws governed banking. States were either free-banking states or charter-only states. In free-banking states, laws required bankers to meet capital requirements, but banks could enter and exit markets as they wished. By contrast state legislatures granted charters on a bank-by-bank basis in charter-only states. During the antebellum time period, railroads also began to spread westward. Railroads lowered transportation costs and connected the country in a never-before seen way. Railroads allowed for an increasingly connected society, increasing population and bringing economic activity to an area (Atack et al., 2009). The spread of railroads presents an opportunity to study a shock to the banking sector. Similarly to contemporary banks, antebellum banks relied on leverage to drive profits. In this research I build upon previous antebellum bank literature. In a forthcoming book chapter Atack et al. (2014) look at the impact of railroads on antebellum bank stability. Controlling for other means of transportation and bank financial measures they find railroads decreased bank failures, where a failure is defined as a bank being unable to redeem notes at par. Atack et al. (2014) also attempt to explain how railroads increased antebellum bank stability, claiming (through Atack et al. (2009)),but with little evidence, that the most obvious answer is railroads brought 1 See Aspinwall (1970), Berger and Hannan (1989), Corvoisier and Gropp (2002), Edwards (1964), Smirlock, Michael, T. Gilligan, and William Marshall (1984), and Stevens (1990) for good discussions on the relationship between bank market structure and interest rates. 1 about greater urbanization, which led to greater bank scrutiny and activity. To control for urbanization they include total population and the fraction of population living in an urban area. They find that the fraction of people living in an urban area reduces bank failures only if bank financial measures are excluded.2 They also find that higher banknote circulation levels increase the probability of bank failures and increased lending decreased the probability of bank failure. Finding that bank financial measures affected antebellum bank failure rates, Atack et al. (2014) look into the relationship between railroads and financial measures, finding railroads lowered a bank’s specie-to-asset ratio, lowered a bank’s banknote-circulation-to-assets ratio and increased lending as a percent of assets. They also find that banks diversified their assets away from bonds to loans and diversified their liabilities away from note circulation to equity and debt due to railroads. Railroads increased the probability of banknote redemption, thus making the practice of circulation less profitable. Atack et al. (2014) claim that railroads increased a bank’s market size, and increased the demand for loanable funds. On the liability side of the balance sheet, Atack et al. (2014) note that the decrease in banknote circulation is offset by an increase in interbank lending. Interbank lending became attractive for liquidity reasons. In a similar paper Jaremski (2010) looks at balance sheet ratios and bank stability, finding that both increased lending and reduced banknote circulation decreased the probability of free bank failures during the antebellum era.3 On a similar note, Chabot and Moul (2014) research government guarantees and bank failures in Indiana. Using data from 1854 and 1860, they use an endogenous market structure model to relate the banking panics of 1854 and 1857 to the number of banks in a given market. Chabot and Moul use access to railroads as a secondary control variable in their model, finding that railroads may have decreased bank profitability. Chabot and Moul’s results only hint at railroads decreasing bank profitability due to a small data set. This result superficially clashes with Atack, et al.’s (2014) results that railroads increased bank lending as a percent of assets. Atack et al.’s lack of explanation of how railroads increased bank stability leaves the door open to more research. From Atack et al. (2014), railroads increased bank lending, reduced bond holdings, decreased banknote circulation and increased interbank lending. Atack et al. did not to look at bank’s ratio of banknote circulation-tospecie, which I refer to as leverage. Increased banking stability could have come from increased banking activity and profitability or through deceased leverage ratios. In this thesis I attempt to answer how railroads made antebellum banks more stable and how railroads affected banking profitability. Lower leverage ratios imply less severe boom-bust cycles while increased banking activity implies a larger banking sector. A larger banking sector further exposes an economy to danger through boom-bust cycles. 2 An urban area is defined as a city with a population over 2,500. Balance sheet ratios include capital-to-assets, specie-to-assets, deposits-to-assets, loans-to-assets, bonds-to-assets, and banknote circulation-to-assets. 3 2 First, I aim to replicate some of the findings in Atack et al. (2014). I then construct an antebellum banknote leverage ratio and find the effect of railroads on bank leverage. Following Chabot and Moul (2014) I then use an endogenous market structure model to find the net effect of railroads on antebellum bank profits. From the results in the endogenous market structure model, I draw conclusions on how railroads increased bank stability. I find that railroads increased the level of antebellum bank lending, decreased the level banknote circulation, and decreased banknote circulation-to-specie ratios (leverage). I find railroads decreased antebellum bank profits, increasing the market size needed to support a given number of market banks by thirty percent. I conclude that lower leverage ratios increased bank stability. The paper is organized as follows. First I briefly describe antebellum banking and the relevant literature. Second I attempt to qualitatively replicate the findings in Atack et al. (2014). Third I build upon the findings of Chabot and Moul (2014) by using a endogenous market structure model and relate the number of banks in a market to bank profitability. 2 Literature Review 2.1 Free Banking Era During the free banking era (1837-1865), banks in the United States were governed by state laws. Prior to the free banking era, state legislatures chartered banks on a bank-by-bank basis. The free banking era began after the Second Bank of the United States’ charter expired in 1836. In 1837, Michigan became the first state to adopt free banking laws, and other states followed. Entry was relatively easy during the time period. In order to open a bank, potential bank owners needed a minimum level of capital. Once a bank was set up with the state, the bank began to circulate banknotes. Banknotes served two of the main functions of money: store of value and a medium of exchange. Banknotes had a specified par value and operate like checks do today. State laws required banks to make a security deposit with the state banking authority before banks could issue notes. State laws specified acceptable assets that could be used as collateral. Generally, allowable assets included state bonds and U.S. government bonds.4 Both traded on the New York and Philadelphia Stock Exchanges, making it easier to value the security deposit. States often required the security deposit bonds be valued at the lesser of par or market value. Some states required banks to issue notes at a fraction of the bond’s par or market value (e.g., 90 percent). Once the bankers made the security deposit, the state banking authority signed the banknotes. Banknotes circulated just as paper currency does today. As long as the security deposit’s value was at least as great as the value of the notes, banks received interest 4 Other assets were occasionally allowed. Examples include real estate in Michigan and slaves in Georgia. 3 on the bonds posted as collateral. Notes would trade outside their city of origin at a discount as long as the discount was smaller than the transaction cost of returning the notes to the bank for redemption (Chabot and Moul, 2014). The law required banks to convert their banknotes into specie at face value on demand. If a bank failed to convert notes into specie on demand, the noteholder could protest to the state banking authority. The state banking authority would then sell some of the bank’s collateral to fulfill the request. If word spread that the bank failed to convert banknotes into specie on demand, the banknotes would trade below par value and could trigger a bank run as noteholders realized the bank was not in sound financial condition. The free banking system was a fractional reserve system and may have led to highly leveraged banks. If a bank’s notes circulated near par value, the bank could use the banknotes to buy more bonds to post as collateral. With the additional notes gained from posting more collateral, the bank could buy more bonds and profit from the bonds’ coupon payments. This process could be repeated as long as markets believed the bank was in sound financial condition. As the circulation of banknotes increased, bank’s faced the increasing risk that noteholders would redeem the notes for specie. A way to circumvent this problem was for banks to circulate their notes at places far from their place of operations, which would decrease the likelihood note redemption. If the security deposit’s value fell below the outstanding notes’ value, banks were required to remedy the situation. Banks could either increase their deposit with the state or decrease the amount of notes outstanding. If a bank failed to make these adjustments in a timely manner, the banking authority closed the bank. The bank’s security deposit with the state was then used to pay noteholders on a pro rated basis. If the proceeds from selling the bank’s security deposit were less than the notes’ par value, noteholders could file suit against the bank’s stockholders for the difference. Dwyer (1996) notes the amount of bank entry and exit during the free banking era. While some banks certainly failed due to poor operations, some historians believe that reckless banking pervaded the free banking era. The term “wildcat banking” is often used to describe reckless banking during this era but an exact definition of a wildcat bank is elusive. Rockoff (1974) identified a wildcat banking state by five criteria: (1) the short life span of the free banks-generally less than one year; (2) the large number of entrants; (3) low liquidity ratios; (4) large number of bank failures; and (5) large noteholder losses. Rolnick and Weber (1984) and Economopoulous (1988) have shown that wildcat banking was not as pervasive as many thought during the free banking era. Free banking succeeded in some states more than others. New York was one of the first to adopt free banking laws. New York’s banking system was so successful that it was imitated by other states. While Ohio also had a successful free banking system, Michigan’s banking system was a failure. Wildcat banking was rampant during the free banking era in Michigan. Michigan laws were less stringent than other 4 banks, particularly with regard to collateral requirements. These lax laws encouraged a banking system that was highly susceptible to fraud, and Michigan banks often intentionally circulated notes that could not be redeemed. These wildcat banks failed, leaving noteholders with nothing (Rockhoff and Walton, 2004). There are other important events that occurred during the free banking era. In 1854 Ohio passed a law prohibiting state residents from holding out-of-state notes resulting in the Indiana Banking Panic of 1854. Many Ohio residents at the time held Indiana banknotes, and a run on Indiana banks followed. This run on Indiana banks led to many failures across Indiana (Chabot and Moul, 2014). A national bank panic occurred in 1857. The exact cause of the panic of 1857 is unclear. The panic did however cause widespread financial collapse and bank failures (Calomiris and Schweikart, 1991). Calomiris and Schweikart (1991) research potential causes of the 1857 panic and favor the Dred Scott decision which ruled that no person of African decent could claim United States citizenship. The court ruling affected expectations by increasing the tensions of the North and South and made war more likely. Railroads from the eastern seaboard to the middle of the country provided a cheaper means of transportation and paved way for easier migration. Given their advantage over canals and waterways railroads quickly rose to dominance. By 1840, there were about as many miles of rail as canals (Atack et al., 2009). By 1850, railroads mileage exceeded canal mileage by two to one, and by 1860 the United States had more railway miles than the rest of the world combined (Atack et al., 2009). Much of the railroad construction focused on the Midwest. Between 1853 and 1856, more than half the railway building in the United States took place in the Midwest (Atack et al., 2009). Railroads reduced travel time and expanded bank markets. Weber (2002) notes the relationship between banknote discounts and transportation costs. Weber contends that transportation routes played a major role in banknote discount rates and redemption. Weber also finds that, compared to locations with no railway access but close proximity to the city of redemption, banknotes will trade at higher discount relative to cities farther way from the redemption city that have railway access. Atack et al. (2009) look at the impact of railroads on population density and urbanization. Atack et al. (2009) find railroads had little impact on population density but had a large impact on urbanization. Atack et al.’s (2009) estimates suggest railroads increased the fraction of people living in urban areas by three to four percentage points and may account for more than half of the increased urbanization in the Midwest during the 1850’s. The increased urbanization in the Midwest may have also led to increased investment in infrastructure. In another paper, Atack, Jaremski, and Rousseau (2013) consider how railroads spread across the country. Atack, Jaremski, and Rousseau (2013) find that railroad tracks were laid in counties where at least one bank was already present. Once tracks were laid in a county, new banks generally followed within two to three years (Atack, Jaremski, and Rousseau, 2013). 5 2.2 Endogenous Market Structure Review Drawing conclusions about firm profitability would seem to require firm profits, margins, and costs to be observed. Bresnahan and Reiss (1990, 1991) make it easier to draw conclusions about firm profitability without observing profits, margins, or costs. Bresnahan and Reiss infer market competition by looking at endogenous market structure directly. Bresnahan and Reiss assume that all markets are in long-run equilibrium, i.e., N firms observed in a market earn positive economic profits but N + 1 would not. Bresnahan and Reiss estimate profit functions using expressions for revenue and costs that depend on observable market characteristics and allows them to link easily observed market characteristic to firm profitability. The Bresnahan and Reiss approach treats profits as a latent variable. Using an ordered probit with the number of firms as the dependent variable, they are able to infer how revenue and costs are linked to observable market characteristics. Bresnahan and Reiss’s approach allows for the derivation of entry thresholds for markets. Entry thresholds are the market size needed for a given number of firms to breakeven. An entry threshold is derived from a zero profit condition and is equal to unobservable fixed costs over variable profits per customer (Bresnahan and Reiss, 1991). Entry thresholds then can be used to measure the level of competition in a market. Most models of imperfect competition predict that variable profit margins will decline with the number of firms in a market, and entry thresholds will rise. If firms engage in collusive behavior though, variable profits will not change and entry thresholds will stay the same. Bresnahan and Reiss (1990) use their model to study entry in isolated markets in the retail automobile industry. They find that the entry of the second firm did not lower variable profit margins compared to a monopoly. Bresnahan and Reiss (1991) also research entry in numerous other markets. They find the entry of the second and third firms both increased competition for markets with doctors, dentists, druggists, plumbers, and tire dealers. The Bresnahan and Reiss method is identified by market characteristics affecting variable profit margins or fixed costs, but not both. In reality many observable market characteristics are likely to affect both. To address this issue, Abraham, Gaynor, and Vogt (2007) (henceforth AGV) extend Bresnahan and Reiss’s model. AGV use an exponential specification instead of Bresnahan and Reiss’s linear specification. AGV’s exponential specification directly incorporates the identification issue into the model so that the impacts on variable profit margins and fixed costs cannot be distinguished. AGV incorporate quantity data into their research to separate the effect on fixed costs from changes in competition. AGV applies their exponential specification to local hospital markets and reject that fixed costs can explain the high observed threshold ratios, concluding that the higher ratios were due to increased competition. 6 3 Bank Balance Sheet 3.1 Model Railroads may alter bank balance sheet composition and bank behavior. To describe these equilibrium relationships, I estimate simple OLS models. Specifically I estimate: Balance Sheet Itemi,t = β0 + α1 RRi,t + βXi,t + i,t (1) where Balance Sheet Item includes bank i’s assets, banknote circulation, loans and specie at time t. Also included as dependent variables are the ratios of specie-to-assets, loan-to-assets, and a bank’s leverage ratio (defined below). Assets, circulation, loans, and specie are examined to better understand how railroads changed absolute levels of bank assets. I attempt to replicate Atack et al’s. (2014) findings looking at specie to assets and loan to asset ratio. I define leverage to be a bank’s value of notes in circulation over specie. Banknote circulation was important to antebellum banks, but not only from a profitability point of view. Banks faced recourse if the public was unable to redeem notes for specie. Facing the risk of closure, banks had to hold enough specie to mitigate closure risk. My measure for leverage is therefore highly pertinent to the time period. RR is a binary variable indicating if a railroad was present in a bank’s county of operations.5 X is a vector of control variables that includes a bank’s age, assets, town population, state fixed effects and year fixed effects. State fixed effects are included to capture regulatory differences between states. Log linear and linear models were considered for each separate model. Using goodness-of-fit tests, the model with the best fit is presented in the tables. 3.2 Data I combine existing data sets to provide bank, county and town level information for 1854-1860. Table one provides a brief description of the variables. Table two provides summary statistics. Warren Weber’s antebellum balance sheet database provided the balance sheet variables (Weber, 2011). Weber’s database is impressive, as he provides a detailed source of bank information. Balance sheet data may appear multiple times during a year for a given bank, and balance sheet data was not available in every year for every bank. Railroad information was gathered using eighteen historical maps. The maps contained the location of railroads across states. If a railroad was present in a bank’s county of operation, the railroad binary takes a value of one.6 Forty seven percent of sample bank observations have a railroad in their county, but only five percent gain access to a railroad over the time period. The average amount 5 Atack et al. (2013) results indicate that railroads may not be an exogenous variable. The results that follow in the rest of this paper should be interpreted with this in mind. 6 See appendix for details. 7 of leverage for the sample is 12.84 and railroad banks have lower average leverage (banknote circulation-to-specie) at 5.77, compared to 19 for non-railroad banks. This is a priori evidence that railroads were associated with lower bank leverage. Mean asset values for sample banks is $501,310 with railroad banks being bigger from an asset point of view. The average amount of loans outstanding for sample banks is $274,010. Railroad banks have a higher mean value of loans outstanding by a large margin. The average level of specie on hand is $49,690. The average level of bank note circulation is $132,354, with railroads banks displaying a much higher average level of note circulation. I assume the first available date for which balance sheet data were available was the first day of bank operation. The mean age for sample banks is 8.64 years, with a wide range. Railroad banks tend to be older banks, with an average age of 10.82 years. The difference in average age supports the findings of Atack et al. (2009) that railroads followed established banks. Town population data were taken from the InterUniversity Consortium for Political and Social Research (ICPSR) machine-readable 1850 and 1860 Censuses of the United States. Population data is only available for 1850 and 1860. Population data for 1854-1859 were linearly interpolated. Average town population for sample banks is 47,430. Railroad banks have a larger town population compared to non-railroad banks. I follow Zhang et al.’s (2004) paper and use the Palmer Drought Severity Index (PDSI) to control for weather. Zhang et al. make use of large-scale and nonlocal covariance information to reconstruct patterns of continental drought from tree-ring records in the conterminous Unites States. They specifically look at the ‘Dust Bowl’. Following Zhang et al. I use town latitude and longitude to assign PDSI values to each town by year. A more positive PDSI value indicates wet conditions.7 I restrict my sample to banks in Illinois, Indiana, Iowa, Missouri, Ohio, Pennsylvania, and Wisconsin due to the availability of data.8 Observations with no assets, negative balance sheet ratios, and a value of zero for age are dropped from the sample9 . After all criteria are applied, 1,726 bank observations are left for the sample. The sample includes 201 unique city/town observations and 320 unique banks. 3.3 Estimation Results Table three displays results for models with a bank’s balance sheet level of assets, loans, and specie as the dependent variables. State fixed effects are included. I am interested in how railroads affected bank balance sheet behavior. Railroads are associated with higher asset levels only if railroad access is the only control variable, 7 See appendix for details. Michigan is excluded from sample because of its wildcat banking history. 9 Some cities have changed names since the 19th century. If latitude and longitude could not be identified, the bank observations were dropped. Some banks had two town names for their location. Under these circumstances, midpoint coordinate were used. Balance sheet ratios include banknote circulation-to-specie, specie-to-assets and loans-to-assets. 8 8 but railroads have little effect on a bank’s level of assets once other control variables are included. A bank’s age and town population are significant and have the expected sign. Older banks have higher asset levels and banks in larger towns have higher asset levels. The loan specification provides evidence consistent with bank behavior changing due to railroads. If a railroad was present in a bank’s county banks increased lending. This increase in lending was offset by a decrease in bond holdings(Atack et al., 2014). Railroads presumably increased the size of a bank’s lending market through lower transportation costs. The other variables show their expected signs in the loan specification. Older banks, banks in higher population towns, and banks in more wet areas all display higher lending levels. The effect of drought decreases with town population and lending decreases as time passes. I recognize that assets is an endogenous regressor. Assets as an explanatory variable is included as a proxy for bank size and bank financial condition. The results in table three are robust to the exclusion of assets with regard to the railroad coefficient. If assets are excluded in the specie specification the coefficient on age becomes significant and the size of the coefficients on age and population increase. If assets are excluded in the loan specification the coefficient on drought becomes significant and the coefficients on railroads, age, and population increase. Railroads also have little effect on a bank’s level of specie. As I will show later, railroads decreased bank leverage through a decrease in note circulation, not through an increase in specie levels. Table four presents eight different specifications with banknote circulation as the dependent variable. Once state fixed effects are added, the coefficient on railroads becomes negative and significant. Railroads were associated with lower banknote circulation, presumably due to the increased probability of a large number of noteholders redeeming their notes. Previously, I showed that railroads were associated with greater bank lending. An increase in stability through lower bank leverage ratios is also plausible. A bank’s age has a positive significant relationship with banknote circulation, but the relationship goes away once state fixed effects are added. The coefficient on town population displays a curious negative sign once state fixed effects are added. While intuition may lead to the belief that banks in higher populated towns will have a higher level of banknote circulation(due to increased demand), it is not difficult to imagine scenarios in which banks in higher populated areas face higher probabilities of banknote redemption. Assets is again included as a measure of bank size and health. The positive and significant coefficient on the railroad binary variable is robust to the exclusion of assets. Year fixed effects are also included to capture explanatory elements specific to certain years. The reference group is 1854. Circulation in subsequent years is below circulation in 1854 and displays a decreasing then increasing pattern, relative to banknote circulation in 1854. Table five displays the results from seven models with a bank’s specie-to-asset ratio as the dependent variable. Atack, et al. (2014) find that railways lowered a bank’s specie-to-asset ratio and believe a banks specie-to-assets ratio measures a bank’s ability to withstand a bank run. I replicate their findings qualitatively once 9 state fixed effects are added. Presumably, the decrease in a bank’s specie-to-asset ratio is due to the increase in bank lending. Recall that I find no significant relationship between railways and a bank’s level of assets or specie. I do find a positive relationship between bank lending and railroads. Log of age is significantly positive with a banks specie-to-asset ratio in all specifications besides specification five and seven. While the results in table three show a negative relationship between years and loans, banks may have reorganized their asset portfolios to include other assets not examined in this research. Examples include bonds, real estate and stocks. I am unable to replicate Atack, Jaremski, and Rousseau (2014) finding that railroads increased a bank’s loan-to-asset ratio in table six. This is surprising due to my earlier finding that railroads increased a banks level of loans but not assets. Atack et al, have a larger data set and use different dependent variables, including a more precise railroad variable. I do find the same positive relationship with regard to the log of a bank’s age. I also find a negatively significant relationship with the log of population, but the relationship goes away once state fixed effects are added. Neither precipitation nor the precipitation interaction term is significant. I do find that as time passes in years, the ratio of loans to assets declines which goes along with my findings in table three that the level of bank lending decreases as time passes. Table seven displays results from eight models with the note circulation-to-specie ratio as the dependent variable. Recall I have defined leverage as banknote circulation over specie, and state laws required banks to redeem banknotes at par value on demand. This definition of leverage explains how banks changed the ratio of banknote circulation to specie which is more in line with the time period. I do find that railroads are associated with different bank banknote circulation-to-specie ratios across all specifications. Banks with access to railroads in their county of operation had lower leverage ratios, consistent with the increased probability of note redemption, a reasonable decision. Leverage ratios decline with log of age, but the effect goes away if log of assets is omitted. Log of assets is positively significant. Banks in towns with higher populations have lower leverage ratios, perhaps due to the increased possibility of note redemption. Banks located in drier areas have higher leverage ratios, and leverage ratios decline with the interaction term.10 As time goes on, banks decreased their banknote circulation-to-specie ratios.11 So far I have shed light on changing bank behavior due to the expansion of railroads. Banks had more lending and lower leverage. Railroads made note circulation more risky. The increase in population due to railroads also may have increased the 10 To control for a non-linear relationship between a bank’s note circulation-to-specie ratio and weather, a quadratic PDSI term was added in a model not included in this paper. The coefficient on the quadratic palmer variable was negative and significant indicating that extreme rainfall has a large negative effect on note circulation-to-specie levels. 11 The note circulation-to-specie model was also estimated with town fixed effects. When town fixed effects were added, the coefficient on the railroad variable becomes insignificant. This result is most likely due to a lack of variation in railroad access. Only five percent of sample banks gain railroad access from 1854 to 1860. 10 demand for loanable funds, raising the returns on loans, and have increased the liquid funds a bank could access. Presumably, all else equal, banks enjoyed an increase in their profits through increased lending. But what is the net effect on bank profits with the two opposite effects of railways? Recall that Atack et al. (2014) find that railroads are associated with lower bank failure rates. The next step is to find how railroads affect antebellum bank profitability. Antebellum banks either experienced increased stability through rising activity or through lower leverage ratios. To answer this question, I will use an endogenous market structure model relating bank profitability to the number of banks in a market. If railroads made banks more stable through increased bank activity, railroads will have a positive effect on banking profits. If railroads made banks more stable through lower banknote circulation-to-specie ratios, railroads will have a negative effect on banking profits. 4 4.1 Endogenous Market Structure Model Since profits, prices and cost data are unavailable, I use an alternative method to measure the net impact of railroads on antebellum bank profitability. I employ techniques similar to Bresnahan and Reiss (1990, 1991) and extended by AGV to examine the determinants of bank market structure and profitability. In particular, I employ a discrete dependent variable model that relates the number of banks in a market to characteristics of that market. Although bank profits, prices, and costs are unavailable, this estimation technique allows for the estimation of the impact of market characteristics on bank profitability. The inclusion of market size as an explanatory variable allows for the derivation of more readily understandable market thresholds. Comparisons of market thresholds when a railroad is/is not present in a market’s county allow me to draw conclusions about the relationship among bank market structure, profitability and railroads. A bank’s entry decision depends upon expected profits given entry. I assume that long-run bank profits can be expressed as a function of the number of active banks in the market and characteristics of the market. In other words, bank i’s profit in market k is given by: Πi (Nk , yk , xk ) (2) where Nk is the number of banks in a given market, yk is the total population of consumers in market k, and xk is a vector of variables that can affect both costs and demand. Equation two can be interpreted as a reduced form discounted long-run profit function reflecting the outcome of competition between the banks in market k. If Nk equals one, this function describes the equilibrium profits of a monopolist. If Nk equals two, equation two function describes the equilibrium profits of a duopolist and so on. I view banks’ equilibrium post-entry profits as unobserved random variables. I 11 also impose strong restrictions on bank profits in a given market. I do not allow for heterogeneous banks. I assume equilibrium profits for bank i in market k are given by Πi (Nk , yk , xk ) = πi (Nk , yk , xk ) + k (3) Notice the components of the bank i’s profits only depend on characteristics of market k. Several useful implication follow from the aforementioned assumptions. If expected profits decline in the number of banks in a market, the equilibrium number of banks in a market is the maximum number of sustainable banks. Second, the assumption that there are no unique variables to bank i in market k allows for the derivation of thresholds that characterize the equilibrium number of firms in a market. The equilibrium number of firms in a market, denoted Nk∗ , can be characterized as Nk∗ = 0 if πk1 + εk < 0 Nk∗ = N if πkN + εk ≥ 0 and πkN +1 + εk < 0 There will be N banks in market k if it is profitable for N banks to enter given market conditions and unprofitable for additional banks to enter. I further assume that the random error term is i.i.d. normal across markets. Thus the probabilities of observing N banks in market k are P (Nk∗ = 0) = 1 − Φ(πk1 ) P (Nk∗ = 1) = Φ(πk1 ) − Φ(πk2 ) P (Nk∗ = 2) = Φ(πk2 ) − Φ(πk3 ) P (Nk∗ ≥ 3) = Φ(πk3 ) where Φ(•) is the cumulative density function of a standard normal random variable with the variance of the error term standardized to one. My strong restrictions on bank heterogeneity are not harmless. The restrictions imply that the variation in market outcomes is based solely on differences in market characteristics. Without this restrictive assumption, it would be difficult to discern the effect of unobserved heterogeneity from market characteristics. The ease of entry during the free banking era makes the homogeneity restriction less bothersome. I assume expected bank profits can be broken down into variable profits and fixed costs. I additionally allow fixed costs to vary across markets due to endogenous barriers to entry. Formally, expected bank profits for a single bank in a market with N banks is ΠN = 1 SdN VN − FN N (4) where ΠN denotes long-run profits per bank, S denotes market size, dN denotes percapita demand for banking services, VN is average variable profit per transaction and FN denotes fixed costs. I assume, as AGV do, that variable profits and fixed costs 12 can be represented using exponential functions of N and variables that affect demand and costs: (5) v(N, yk , xk ) = exp(yk λ + xk δx + δN + εvk ) F (N, xk ) = exp(xk γx + γN + εfk ) (6) where δN and γN are coefficients on binary variables for market structure. δN and γN capture differences in variable profits and fixed costs in markets with 1 to N banks. The errors εv and εF are assumed to be normally distributed with zero mean and constant variance. The exponential specification alleviates the identification problems that occur when estimating a linear profit function12 . Following AGV I use the log of population, so variable profits can be written as v(N, yk , xk ) = P OPkλ exp(xk δx + δN + εvk ) (7) Substituting the exponential specification of variable profits and fixed costs into the inequalities that determine market structure yields that the N th bank enters when its variable profits exceed fixed costs: 1 exp(yk λ + xk δx + δN + εvk ) − exp(xk γx + γN + εfk ) > 0 N (8) and rearranging and taking logs yields yk λ + xk δx + δN + εvk − ln(N ) > xk γx + γN + εFk (9) Let µx = δx − γx , µN = γN − δN , and εΠ = εv − εF . εΠ is distributed N (0, σ 2 ). Then 0 1 N= 2 3+ if if if if yk λ + xk µx + Π k < µ1 µ1 ≤ yk λ + xk µx + εΠ k < µ1 + µ2 + ln(2) µ2 + ln(2) ≤ yk λ + xk µx + εΠ k < µ1 + µ3 + ln(3) µ3 + ln(3) ≤ yk λ + xk µx + εΠ k The normality assumption of εΠ allows for an ordered probit model where µn are the threshold values that can be estimated using maximum likelihood techniques. The dependent variable of the ordered probit is the number of banks in market k. All parameters are rescaled by σ, which I normalize to one. Different model specifications can be estimated. There is a tradeoff between tighter parameter estimates and information obtained from the model. Estimating more specific market structures (such as triopoly-plus) places more restrictions on the model, but yields more information such as market thresholds (discussed later). The information gained from added threshold estimates is useful, and this thesis focuses 12 See Abraham, Gaynor and Vogt (2007) for details. 13 on the duopoly-plus and triopoly plus specifications. All of the above derivations work well for cross sectional analysis. I am mainly interested in the net effect of railroads on bank market structure and profitability to illuminate the causes of on bank stability. Recall that Chabot and Moul (2014) hint at the possibility that railroads decreased bank profits but do not have enough observations to draw a solid conclusion. My data consists of market observations from 1854-1860. I estimate a pooled cross section to better estimate the effect of railroads. In order to pool the cross sections, I impose that the parameters are identical across 1854-1860, and allow the scalars that represent the distribution variance to differ. I normalize σ54 to one, and estimate σ55 , σ56 , σ57 , σ58 , σ59 , σ60 as free parameters. During the free banking era, state-charter-only banks still operated. The model I have outlined implicitly assumes that all markets are subject to free entry. I resolve this issue by estimating a probit model for state chartered banks, where the dependent variable is dichotomous representing markets with zero banks or at least one bank. Little information is lost since there are few market observations where more than one state chartered bank is observed. The ordered profit model can be difficult to interpret. I use the parameter estimates to derive easier to understand market thresholds. Specifically, the market sizes for a monopoly Y M , duopoly Y D , and triopoly Y T can be formed from the zero profit conditions. For example: µ1 − xµx ) (11) Y M = exp( λ µ1 + µ2 + ln(2) − xµx ) (12) Y D = exp( λ µ1 + µ3 + ln(3) − xµx Y T = exp( ) (13) λ where the estimated parameters from the endogenous market structure model are used. The thresholds of Y M , Y D , and Y T provide estimates for their respective market population required to support the long-run equilibrium number of firms. I also construct market thresholds ratios. A more readily understandable estimate of how railroads altered bank profitability is the percentage change in the market population needed to support a given number of firms if a railroad entered the county. This change is given by: θ = exp( 4.2 −βRR )−1 λ (14) Data Data were compiled from 1854-1860 cross sections. Potential markets consist of places found in the Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research (ICPSR) machine-readable 1850 and 1860 Censuses of the United States. Included in the ICPSR are cities, towns and villages. The ICPSR data are not complete, and this 14 study focuses on states for which population data appear to be complete. States included in the analysis are Iowa, Illinois, Missouri, Ohio, Western Pennsylvania and Wisconsin. The endogenous market structure model assumes that markets are isolated. Relying on the 1860 census, markets are assumed to be isolated if the market satisfies either of two criteria. First, observations that are at least ten miles from the nearest neighboring observation are included. Second, observation pairs that are near one another but far away from other observations are included. To satisfy this requirement, two observations must be within five miles of each other and at least ten miles away from the next closest observation. If the second requirement is met, a new observation is created that combines all features of the two observations. Similar conditions are used to construct the other cross sections if both 1850 and 1860 populations are observed. Applying these criteria reduces the sample to 154 market observations for the 1854-1857 cross sections, 277 market observations for the 1858-1859 cross sections, and 362 for the 1860 cross sections.13 Henceforth these observations are referred to as markets. Once the market is identified, relevant variables can be constructed. The 1850 and 1860 censuses provide population data. Population data are linearly interpolated for 1854-1860. Many markets suffered drought conditions in the years 1854-1860. Weather shocks are controlled for using an annual rainfall index derived from tree-ring records. This weather information is compiled using the annual time series of the PDSI by taking a weighted average of the nearest grid points’ values from Zhang, Mann, and Cook (2004) and is different from the precipitation measurement used in the bank regressions in previous sections14 . The measure considers past data, ignores higher than average rainfall, puts more weight on recent time periods and exhibits a convex relation with the PDSI. The variable of concern to this research is of course railway access. The railroad binary takes on a value of one if a railroad was operating in the bank’s county during the observation year. Railroad data was taken from eighteen historical maps, as was done in the previous bank model data set. Recall that if railroads bank failures through increased activity, railroads will have a positive effect on bank profitability. If railroads increased bank stability through lower leverage ratios, the coefficient on railroads will be negative. Following Chabot and Moul’s research on Indiana banking I include various iterations of Indiana control variables as binary variables. Chabot and Moul (2014) and Calomiris and Schweikart (1991) note that the antebellum banking situation in Indiana differed than the rest of the country. The panics of 1854 and 1857 had large effects on Indiana banking. I run different pooled regressions to look at the effect of those panics on Indiana banking. Table eight reports definitions for variables used in the endogenous market structure model. Table nine reports summary statistics. Market data is from December, 13 St. Louis and Cincinati are excluded due to their size and easy transportation access. Iowa did not have free banking laws until 1858 and so are excluded until that year. 14 See appendix for details. 15 31 from 1854-1860. Chabot and Moul’s (2014) data is from August 1, 1854 and December, 31 1860. Overall, the data shows an increase in banking and railroad access from 1854-1860. In 1954 58 percent of all sample markets had railroad access. In 1860 60 percent of sample markets had railroad access. The number of markets with at least one bank increases from 1854-1860, as does the number of markets with railroad access and at least one bank. Also, the number railroad markets with at least one bank increases over time. The average population of markets in the sample increases from 1854 to 1859 and drops in 1860. This drop is most likely due to the increase in number of observed markets. For a given market structure the number of consumers in a market increases if a railroad is present. There are no market observations with three or more banks that do not have a railroad present in the county. 4.3 Estimation Results Recall the purpose of the endogenous market structure model is to infer the net effect of railroads on banking profitability. From the sign of the effect of railroads on banking profitability, I then can draw conclusions on the effect of increased lending and decreased leverage ratios on antebellum bank profitability and stability. Table 10 provides the results for the duopoly-plus cross section models. Population is a significant determinant of the number of banks in a market. A positive relationship is exactly what theory suggests. Railroads are significant for the 1855 and 1860 cross sections, displaying a negative relationship with the number of banks in a market. The negative effect of railroads in the 1855 and 1860 cross sections is evidence that railroads were associated with lower bank profits; the drop in profits due to lower leverage ratios is greater than the increase in profits from lending. The drought measurement is negative and significant. Drier areas have fewer banks. Charter-only states display significantly lower levels of banking, as is expected. Indiana displays a higher level of banking compared to other states in the sample in 1854, but Indiana has a lower level of banking in 1860, compared to other states. This finding is consistent with Chabot and Moul (2014). Table 12 displays the estimated market thresholds implied by equations (11)-(13) for the duopoly-plus and triopoly-plus cross sections. The market thresholds represent the market size needed to sustain a given number of banks. Also listed are the ratios of market thresholds relating the market size needed to support a duopolists to the market size needed to support a monopolist. If an additional firm in a market has no effect on the competitiveness of the market, the ratio for a duopolist to a monopolist will be equal to two. The last row displays the percentage change in market size needed to support a given market structure. Percentage changes are given by equation (14). The null hypothesis is the percentage change is equal to zero. To obtain any threshold or ratios if there is a railroad operating a market’s county, multiply by the number listed in the percentage change row. For example, a monopolist in a railroad county needs 10,608 (6310·1.681) people to break even in the duopoly plus model. Table 11 presents cross section model results for the triopoly-plus specification. 16 The triopoly-plus specification places added restrictions on the model by estimating the triopoly-plus cutoff, µ3 . The added parameter estimate increases the amount of information that can be inferred from the model, specifically the triopoly-plus market threshold and its ratio to a duopoly’s market threshold. The triopoly-plus model is the focus of this thesis since there are 18 markets with at least three banks. Even though the parameter estimates in the triopoly-plus model are less exact, the parameter estimates are significant. Higher population levels lead to higher levels of banking, and population’s estimated coefficient is similar across cross sections. Railroads display the same negative relationship with the number of banks in 1854 and 1860. Again drier areas have fewer banks. State-charter-only states have fewer banks, but there is no effect of state-charter-only laws in 1860. Indiana also has a higher level of banking in 1854 relative to other sample states. In the 1855-1859 cross sections no such effect is significant. Indiana has a lower banking level compared to other states in 1860. Added in table 11 are the p-values from a Wald Test with the null hypothesis being µ3 = µ2 . This form of the test is a conservative way to see if a triopoly plus market structure significantly differs from a duopoly market structure. I am able to reject the null in the 1855-1859 cross sections. Again, the threshold and percentage change information is presented below the parameter estimates. In 1854 4,326 people were needed to support a monopolist, compared to 1,990 in 1860. The threshold estimates appear realistic. The standard errors of the threshold estimates are large due to a small number of observations. Table 13 presents six different pooled cross section estimates. Specifications one through three estimate parameters for the triopoly-plus model. Specifications four through six provide estimates for a duopoly-plus model. All specifications provide evidence that railroads lowered bank profitability through lowering the number of equilibrium banks in an isolated markets. The finding that railroads lowered bank profitability says that while railroads increased bank lending, the lowering of leverage ratios dominated the increased profits from lending. My findings imply that it was lowered leverage ratios, not increased banking activity, that provided greater stability by way of lower failure rates. At the bottom of table 14 is the percentage increase in market size needed to sustain a given market structure due to railroad access. My estimates suggest that railroads increase the market size needed to support a given market structure by 30 percent.15 Population is also significant across all specifications. The population parameter estimates show that population was a big factor in determining a bank’s location in antebellum United States. Drier markets also experienced less banking, and the drought parameter estimate is significant across specifications. The focus should be on the tripoly plus model, as the results indicate that market structure under a triopoly 15 Since the 1860 cross section adds market observations that were not available in 1854-59, pooled cross sections for 1854-1859 were estimated. The significance of the coefficient on the railroad binary variable does not change but the magnitude of the coefficient estimate does fall. The estimated increase in market size needed due to railroad access is still thirty percent and significant if the 1860 cross section was dropped from the pooled cross section. 17 plus is significantly different than a duopoly-plus market structure. The last three control variables are included due to the fact that banking in Indiana differed from the rest of the sample states (Calomiris and Schweikart, 1991 and Chabot and Moul, 2014). I estimate three different models describing how Indiana banking changed over time. Indiana bank guarantees were not honored in 1854, and Chabot and Moul show that banking in Indiana changed due to the failure of the state to honor those guarantees. Another bank panic hit the United States in 1857, with Indiana sustaining a large majority of bank failures (Calomiris and Schweikart, 1991). I estimate three models for Indiana banking in 1855-1860, Indiana banking in 1857-1860 and a time trend model. All models show a decline in the level of banking in Indiana. Specifications one and four show that the Indiana banking panic of 1854 significantly reduces Indiana banking levels. Specifications two and five show that the national banking panic in 1857 also significantly reduced Indiana banking level, supporting Calomiris and Schweikart’s finding. Both banking panics had a lasting effect on Indiana banking levels. Specifications three and six show that banking levels in Indiana declined overtime with Indiana banking levels below other sample state’s banking levels by 1858. The time trend model fits the data best for the triopoly plus model, while the Indiana banking after 1857 specification fits the best in the duopoly plus model. Table 14 displays the threshold estimates for the pooled cross section models. For all specifications about 2,800 people are needed to support a monopolist, with roughly 3,600 needed to support a monopolist if a railroad is present in the county. It is unlikely that bank fixed costs(Collateral requirement and building costs) changed drastically over the free banking era, so the increase in market thresholds can be interpreted as a fall in variable profit margins. About 8,800 people are needed to support a duopolist with no railroad is present, with about 11,600 people needed if a railroad is present. For a triopoly plus market structure, roughly 25,500 people are needed with no railroad present, and about 33,500 are needed if a railroad is present. The threshold ratios are significant as well. Recall that, if the competitive conduct of firms in a market does not change when a market goes from a monopolist to a duopolist, the threshold ratio should equal two. The ratio of a triopoly market threshold to duopoly market threshold should be equal to one and a half if the market is perfectly competitive. There are other possible interpretations of the effect of railroads on the number of banks in a market. One explanation is that the presence of railroads altered they type of loans made by banks. Railroad tracks were built in high population areas with developed cities. If a bank is in a more industrialized area, banks may specialize in manufacturing loans instead of agricultural loans. Bank specialization may have increased the returns to scale, and my railroad control variable may be picking up the effect of such specialization. 18 Conclusion The free banking era was a much simpler environment compared to contemporary banking. Railroads provided a shock to antebellum banking. My results provide evidence that railroads increased bank lending and decreased banknote circulationto-specie ratios. The net effect lowered antebellum bank profits. The decrease in banknote circulation-to-specie ratios led to an increase in banking stability. My results suggest a possible way to increase the stability of contemporary banks would be to pass legislation requiring banks to lower leverage ratios. As antebellum banking profits declined and stability increased, interest rates may have increased. Further research should be done regarding antebellum bank stability and interest rates. A more stable banking sector is less open to the boom and bust cycles but may have higher interest rates. Regulators face a trade off between stability and national investment. This is not an easy choice, and investment is a large component of a national economy. Regulators face a choice between a stable banking system and a steady level of investment or periods of high investment followed by periods of low investment. Neither choice is a clear favorite. 19 5 5.1 Appendicies Appendix A: Drought Index The Palmer Drought Seversity Index is used to construct the drought variable in the endogenous market structure models. The PDSI is standardized to local climate and standardized to zero. Negative numbers indicate drought conditions, with -2 indicating moderate, -3 indicating severe, and -4 indicating extreme drought. I use the reconstructed measures of the PDSI provided by Zhang, Mann and Cook (2004). Zhang, Mann and Cook (2004) study employs tree-ring data over the conterminous United States to estimate PDSI measures for a system of latitude-longitude grid points back to the year 1700. My market appropriate PDSI measure then use market latitude-longitude coordinates to construct a weighted average of the gridpoints. My market-level measure is constructed for the 1854-1860 cross sections. Given the cumulative impact of yearly precipication, the measure more heavily weights recent years. The measure also builds on the intuition that droughts are worse for agriculture than overly wet seasons and that agricultural costs of drought are non linear Chabot and Moul (2014). Each market-year’s drought measure is (P DSIj,t−k | P DSIj,t−k < 0)2 (15) so that a market-year’s drought measure is positive if there as any degree of drought, and zero otherwise. The weight applied to k years ago follows the formula for a look back of L years k−1 (16) wk = 1 − L and the full drought measure for market j at time t is DROU GHTj,t = L X wk ((P DSIj,t−k | P DSIj,t−k < 0)2 ) (17) k=1 While a different measure of drought is used in the balance sheet models, the above drought measure fits the endogenous market structure models best. This measure is also used in Chabot and Moul (2014). 20 5.2 Appendix B: Railroad Map Sources Atack, Jeremy and Robert A. Margo. ‘‘The Impact of Access to Rail Transportation on Agricultural Improvement: The American Midwest as a test case, 1850-1860. Journal of Transport and Land Use 4.2 (2011): 5-18. Print. Brockman, Paul. ‘‘Evansville & Illinois Railroad Records, 1850: Collection Information.’’ Indiana Historical Society-Manuscripts and Archives. Posted: 3 April 1997. Accessed : 14 May 2013, from: http://www.indi anahistory.org/our-collections/collection-guides/evansville-illinois -railroad- records-1850.pdf Colton, George Woolworth. ‘‘Coltons Railroad & Township Map of the State of Ohio.’’ Map. Library of Congress. H. H. Colton, 1854. Web. 14 May 2013, from: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.gmd/g4081p.rr002790. Colton, George Woolworth. ‘‘Indiana, Illinois, Missouri & Iowa with Parts of Adjoining States.’’ Map. Library of Congress. G. Woolworth Colton, 1858. Web. 14 May 2013,from: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.gmd/g4061p.rr001210. Duncan, Jacob M. ‘‘Barringtons New and Reliable Railroad Map and Shippers & Travelers Guide of Pennsylvania, Engrd. By Ths. Leonhardt.’’ Map. Library of Congress. Barringtons, 1860. Web. 14 May 2013, from: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.gmd/g3821p.rr002950. King, S. D. ‘‘Map of the state of Indiana Compiled from the United Surveys’’ Map. Library of Congress. J. H. Colton, 1852. Web. 14 May 2013, from: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.gmd/g4090.rr002090. ‘‘Map of a Railroad Route from Phenixville to Pinegrove.’’ Map. Library of Congress. Unknown, 1852. Web. 14 May 2013, from: http://hdl.loc. gov/loc.gmd/g3821p.rr005320. ‘‘Map of the Williamsport and Elmira Railroad with its connections.’’ Map. Library of Congress. P.S. Duval & Company, 185-. Web. 14 May 20 13, from: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.gmd/g3791p.rr006180. ‘‘Map Showing the Location of the Chicago & Northwestern Railway with its Branches and Connections through Illinois, Iowa, Nebraska, Wisconsin, Minnesota, Michigan’’ Map. Library of Congress. Chicago & N orthwestern Railway, 1862. Web. 14 May 2013, from: http://hdl.loc. gov/loc.gmd/g4061p.rr003690. 21 ‘‘Railroad and County Map of Illinois Showing the Internal Improvements.’’ Map. Library of Congress. Ensign, Bridgman & Fanning, 1854. Web. 14 May 2013, from: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.gmd/g4100.rr002020. McLellan, David and Bill Warrick. The Lake Shore and Michigan Southern Railway, Transportation Trails, 1989, pp.208. Print. Mendenhall, Edward. ‘‘Map of Iowa Exhibiting the Townships, Cities, Villages, Post Offices, Railroads, Common Roads & other Improvements.’’ Map. Library of Congress. E. Mendenhall, 1855. Web. 14 May 2013, from: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.gmd/g4150.rr002170. Morris, Thomas A. ‘‘Railroad Map of Indian.’’ Map. Library of Congress. Unknown Publisher, 1850. Web. 14 May 2013, from: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.gmd/ g4091p.rr002080. Rodewald, John W. Railroad Development in Wisconsin 18501865. M.A. Thesis. University of Wisconsin, Madison, 1911. Google Books. Web. May 3, 2014, from: http://books.google.com/books/about/Railroad Development in Wisconsin 1850 1. html?id=ocg7AAAAMAAJ. Rose, L. New York Central Timeline. Historical Collection at the Lane Libraries. Scheafer, Peter Wenrick. A Map Showing the Rail Road Connection between Pottsville & Sunbury through the Schuylkill Mahanoy and Shamokin Coal Fields. Map. Library of Congress. Steam Lith Press, 1852. Web. May 14, 2013, from: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.gmd/g3821p.rr002920. Tranfield, Pamela. New Albany and Salem Railroad Company Payroll Ledger, 18551865: Collection Information. Indiana Historical Society Manuscript and Visual Collections Department. Posted: April 1, 2004. Accessed: May 14, 2013, from: http://www.indianahistory.org/our-collections/collection-guides/new-albanysalem-rr-co-payroll-ledger-1855-65.pdf. 22 6 References Abraham, J. M., M. Gaynor, and William B. Vogt (2007, May). Entry and Competition in Local Hospital Markets. Journal of Industrial Economics 2, 265–288. Aspinwall, R. C. (1970, April). Market Structure and Commercial Bank Mortgage Interest Rates. Southern Economic Journal 36 (4), 376–384. Atack, J., F. Bateman, M. Haines, and R. Margo (2009, January). Did Railroads Induce or Follow Economic Growth? Urbanization and Population Growth in the American Midwest, 1850-60. National Bureau of Economic Research, 1071–1085. Working Paper 14640. Atack, J., M. Jaremski, and P. Rousseau (2013). American Banking and the Transportation Revolution Before the Civil War. Working Paper. Atack, J., M. Jaremski, and P. Rousseau (2014). Did Railroads Make Antebellum U.S. Banks More Sound? Linking Rail Locations With Bank Balance Sheets and Survival Rates. In Enterprising America: Business, Banks, and Credit Markets in Historical Perspective. Beighley, H. P. and A. S. McCall (1975, November). Market Power and Structure and Commercial Bank Installment Lending. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 7 (4), 449–467. Berger, A. N. and T. H. Hannan (1989, May). The Price-Concentration Relationship in Banking. The Review of Economics and Statistics 71 (2), 291–299. Bresnahan, T. and P. Reiss (1990, October). Entry in Monopoly Markets. Review of Economic Studies 57 (4), 531–553. Bresnahan, T. and P. Reiss (1991, October). Entry and Competition in Concentrated Markets. The Journal of Political Economy 99 (5), 977–1009. Calomiris, C. and L. Schweikart (1991, December). The Panic of 1857: Origins, Transmission, and Containment. The Journal of Economic History 51 (4). Chabot, B. and C. Moul (2014, August). Bank Panics, Government Guarantees, and Long-Run Size of the Financial Sector: Evidence from Free-Banking America. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46 (5). Cohen, A. M. and J. Mazzeo (2007, February). Market Structure and Competition Among Retail Depository Institutions. The Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (1), 60–74. 23 Corvoisier, S. and R. Gropp (2002, December). Bank Concentration and Retail Interest Rates. Journal of Banking and Finance 26, 2155–2189. Dwyer, G. (1996, December). Wildcat Bankings, Banking Panics, and Free Banking in the United States. Economic Review , 1–20. Economopoulous, A. and H. O’Neil (1995, November). Bank Entry during the Antebellum Period. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 27 (4), 1071–1085. Economopoulous, A. J. (1988, May). Illinois Free Banking Experience. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20 (2), 249–264. Edwards, F. (1964, August). Concentration in Banking and It’s Effect on Business Loan Rates. The Review of Economics and Statistics 46 (3), 294–300. Goldberg, L. and A. Rai (1996). The Structure-Performance Relationship for European Banking. Journal of Banking Finance 20, 745–771. Gorton, G. (1989, July). An Introduction to Van Court’s Bank Note Reporter and Counterfit Detector. Hannan, T. (1991, December). Bank Commercial Loan Markets and the role of Market Structure: Evidence from Surveys of Commercial Lending. Journal of Banking and Finance 15, 133–149. Heitfield, E. (1999, Summer). What do Interest Rate Data say about the Geography of Retail Banking Markets? The Antitrust Bulletin. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC. Jaremski, M. (2010, December). Free Bank Failures: Risky Bonds versus Undiversified Portfolios. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42 (8). Jenks, L. (1944, May). Railroads as an Economic Force in American Development. Journal of Economic History 4 (4), 1–20. Ng, K. (1988, December). Free Banking Laws and Barriers to Entry in Banking, 1838-1860. The Journal of Economic History 4. Rockhoff, H. and G. Walton (2004). History of the American Economy. Mason, OH: Cenage Learning. Rockoff, H. (1974, May). The Free Banking Era: A Reexamination. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 6 (2), 141–167. Rockoff, H. (1989, December). Lessons from the American Experience with Free Banking. NBER Working Paper Series on Historical Factors in Long-Run Growth. Working Paper Number Nine. 24 Rolnick, A. and W. Weber (1982, May). The Free Banking Era: New Evidence on Laissez-Faire Banking. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 80. Rolnick, A. and W. Weber (1984, November). The Causes of Free Bank Failures: A Detailed Examination. Journal of Monetary Economics, 269291. Shepherd, W. G. (1986, December). Tobin’s q and the Structure-Performance Relationship: Comment. The American Economic Review 76 (5), 1205–1210. Smirlock, M. (1985, February). Evidence of the (Non) Relationship between Concentration and Profitability in Banking. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 17 (1), 69–83. Smirlock, Michael, T. Gilligan, and William Marshall (1984, December). Tobin’s q and the Structure-Performance Relationship. The American Economic Review 74 (5), 1051–1060. Stevens, J. L. (1990, June). Tobin’s q and the Structure-Performance Relationship: Comment. The American Economic Review 80 (3), 618–623. Weber, W. (2002). Banknote Exchange Rates in the Antebellum United States. Paper provided by Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis in its series Working Papers with number 623. Weber, W. (2011). Balance sheets for U.S. Antebellum State Banks. Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/economists/wewproj.html. Zhang, Z., M. E. Mann and Edward R. Cook (2004). Alternative Methods of Proxy Based Climate Field Reconstruction: Application to Summer Drought Over the Conterminious United States Back toAD 1700 from Tree-Ring Data. The Holocene 14 (4), 502–516. 25 7 Tables Variable Name LEVERAGE RR ASSETS CIRCULATION LOAN SPECIE AGE POP PALMER PALPOP YEAR Y1854 Y1855 Y1856 Y1857 Y1858 Y1859 Y1860 WI IL OH IA MO PA IN Table 1: Bank Data Description Description Bank leverage ratio defined as value of notes in circulation over specie Dummy variable indicating railroad access within county Value of bank assets Value of banknote circulation Value of bank loans Value of bank specie on hand Age of bank in years Total (free and slave) population from U.S. Census: linear interpolation for years 1854-1859 Palmer Drought Severity Index Interaction of PALMER and population Observation year Dummy variable indicating observation year was 1854 Dummy variable indicating observation year was 1855 Dummy variable indicating observation year was 1856 Dummy variable indicating observation year was 1857 Dummy variable indicating observation year was 1858 Dummy variable indicating observation year was 1859 Dummy variable indicating observation year was 1860 Dummy variable indicating observation is in Wisconsin Dummy variable indicating observation in in Illinois Dummy variable indicating observation is in Ohio Dummy variable indicating observation is in Iowa Dummy variable indicating observation is in Missouri Dummy variable indicating observation in in Pennsylvania Dummy variable indicating observation is in Indiana 26 27 Whole Sample (1,726) RR=1 (804) Std. Dev. Min Max Mean Std. Dev. Min 61.53 0.04 1647.99 5.77 12.41 0.04 0.50 0 1 1 0 0 903.94 9.89 8,822.45 718.28 1,103.96 9.89 183,914 216 2,805,660 152,902 232,264 216 479.53 0 4,444.52 421.33 644.99 9.89 116.42 0.08 1,384.96 79.81 160.99 0.25 10.43 0.08 46 10.82 10.55 0.34 132.80 0.26 565.53 97.62 182.09 0.41 0.70 -2.79 1.15 -0.43 0.70 -2.79 5.89 -32.80 9.18 -3.95 6.28 -32.80 2.07 1854 1860 1858 2.07 1854 0.33 0 1 0.14 0.35 0 0.20 0 1 0.05 0.21 0 0.37 0 1 0.18 0.38 0 0.24 0 1 0.07 0.25 0 0.37 0 1 0.18 0.38 0 0.37 0 1 0.16 0.36 0 0.45 0 1 0.24 0.43 0 0.30 0 1 0.09 0.28 0 0.31 0 1 0.11 0.31 0 0.30 0 1 0.10 0.29 0 0.41 0 1 0.23 0.42 0 0.11 0 1 0.03 0.16 0 0.42 0 1 0.30 0.46 0 0.42 0 1 0.16 0.37 0 RR=0 (922) Max Mean Std. Dev. Min Max 202.35 19.00 82.92 0.06 1647.99 1 0 0 0 0 8,822.45 312.11 625.20 32.65 8,237.07 2,805,660 114,436 125,008 1,197 1,357,605 4,444.52 145.54 180.28 0 995.76 1,384.96 23.42 36.13 0.08 713.50 45.98 6.74 9.94 0.08 46 565.53 3.66 2.81 0.26 14.05 0.98 -0.48 0.71 -2.52 1.15 8.16 -3.77 5.53 -21.15 9.18 1860 1858 2.06 1854 1860 1 0.12 0.32 0 1 1 0.03 0.18 0 1 1 0.16 0.37 0 1 1 0.05 0.22 0 1 1 0.15 0.36 0 1 1 0.18 0.38 0 1 1 0.31 0.46 0 1 1 0.11 0.32 0 1 1 0.11 0.32 0 1 1 0.11 0.31 0 1 1 0.19 0.39 0 1 1 0.00 0.05 0 1 1 0.17 0.38 0 1 1 0.29 0.45 0 1 Assets, circulation, loans and specie are in thousands of dollars. Palmer is Palmer Drought Severity Index. LEVERAGE RR ASSETS CIRCULATION LOANS SPECIE AGE POP PALMER PALPOP YEAR Y1854 Y1855 Y1856 Y1857 Y1858 Y1859 Y1860 IA IL IND OH MO PA WI Mean 12.84 0.47 501.31 132,354 274.01 49.69 8.64 47.43 -0.46 -3.85 1858 0.13 0.04 0.17 0.06 0.16 0.17 0.28 0.10 0.11 0.10 0.21 0.01 0.23 0.23 Table 2: Bank Data Summary Statistics Table 3: Asset, Loan and Specie Models Dependent Variable Assets Loans Specie RR State Fixed Effects 28.100*** 0.133 (10.330) (2.513) 3.226*** 0.073 (0.663) (0.155) 0.824*** 0.172*** (0.153) (0.0376) 0.310*** 0.068*** (0.051) (0.013) 258.600 116.000* 16.080 (188.900) (61.870) (21.980) -29.790 -15.290** -2.533 (22.630) (7.624) (2.820) -12.220 -14.510*** -1.250 (8.610) (3.771) (0.867) Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.430 AGE POP ASSETS PALMER PALPOP YEAR 8.908 (29.130) 6.385*** (1.363) 2.750*** (0.280) 0.760 0.690 Notes: The dependent variable is described in the column heading. Results from OLS Models. (N=1,726). Assets, loans and specie are in thousands of dollars. Robust standard errors are listed below the coefficients in parentheses. * denotes significance at 10%; ** at 5% level; and *** at 1% level. 28 Table 4: Banknote Circulation Model Specification (1) RR 38.470*** 9.091 (9.167) (7.605) 6.559*** (0.498) 0.027 (0.034) AGE POP (2) ASSETS PALMER PALMERPOP (3) (4) 0.503 (6.835) 4.484*** (0.553) -0.350*** (0.089) 0.123*** (0.027) 33.610 (80.310) -5.123 (10.350) -3.443 -15.100*** (6.688) (5.553) 4.266*** 0.685 (0.526) (0.491) -0.344*** -0.319*** (0.088) (0.06) 0.123*** 0.097*** (0.027) (0.019) 54.070 39.070 (78.020) (60.460) -8.183 -5.762 (10.550) (7.828) -2.853 (31.000) -58.080*** (22.180) -107.800*** (20.020) -66.880*** (12.650) -86.910*** (12.370) -74.260*** (13.820) y1855 Y1856 Y1857 Y1858 Y1859 Y1860 (5) (6) (7) (8) -16.440*** (5.453) 0.723 (0.465) -0.318*** (0.058) 0.095*** (0.019) 56.220 (58.740) -8.148 (8.107) 22.940 (26.130) -41.180** (19.690) -63.070*** (17.140) -68.880*** (12.640) -59.710*** (12.540) -52.510*** (12.640) -15.530*** (5.590) 1.304** (0.529) -0.058* (0.033) -17.190*** (5.493) 0.771* (0.467) -0.321*** (0.059) 0.097*** (0.019) 51.72(60.460) -6.607 (7.786) 86.200 (70.190) -11.06 (9.704) 40.770 (33.440) -30.150 (22.450) -63.960*** (20.200) -75.720*** (15.060) -65.660*** (14.180) -51.770*** (14.080) YEAR State Fixed Effects No No No No Yes Yes Yes -10.170*** (1.845) Yes R-squared 0.150 0.397 0.423 0.601 0.618 0.494 0.611 0.011 Notes: The dependent variable is described in the column heading. Results of an OLS Model. (N=1,726). Assets and loans are in thousands of dollars. Robust standard errors are listed below the coefficients in parentheses. * denotes significance at 10%; ** at 5% level; and *** at 1% level. 29 Table 5: Specie-to-Assets Model Specification (1) RR 0.0028 -0.0002 (0.0052) (0.0060) 0.0122*** (0.0025) -0.0025 (0.0018) LAGE LPOP (2) PALMER PALPOP (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) -0.0010 (0.0060) 0.0128*** (0.0025) -0.0012 (0.0018) -0.0299 (0.0218) 0.0016 (0.0026) -0.0048 (0.0057) 0.0154*** (0.0025) -0.00012 (0.0017) -0.0433** (0.0220) -0.0002 (0.0026) -0.0879*** (0.0115) -0.1130*** (0.0130) -0.1440*** (0.0108) -0.0575*** (0.0115) -0.0616*** (0.0114) -0.0858*** (0.0109) -0.0131*** (0.0048) 0.0003 (0.0026) 0.0031* (0.0016) -0.0133 (0.0201) 0.0021 (0.0025) -0.0139*** (0.0047) 0.0049** (0.0025) 0.0012 (0.0017) -0.0096 (0.0201) 0.0020 (0.0025) -0.0226** (0.0114) -0.0109 (0.0123) -0.0348*** (0.0107) -0.0208* (0.0116) -0.0242** (0.0107) -0.0460*** (0.0110) -0.0136*** (0.0047) 0.0038 (0.0025) 0.0019 (0.0017) -0.0062 (0.0200) 0.0017 (0.0025) Y1855 Y1856 Y1857 Y1858 Y1859 Y1860 YEAR State Fixed Effects No No No No Yes Yes -0.0065*** (0.0016) Yes R-squared 0.000 0.017 0.029 0.112 0.372 0.388 0.383 Notes: The dependent variable is described in the column heading. Results of an OLS Model. (N=1,726). Assets and specie are in thousands of dollars. Robust standard errors are listed below the coefficients in parentheses. * denotes significance at 10%; ** at 5% level; and *** at 1% level. 30 Table 6: Loan-to-Assets Model Specification (1) RR 0.057** 0.041 0.039 (0.027) (0.029) (0.029) 0.192*** 0.194*** (0.011) (0.011) -0.058*** -0.055*** (0.009) (0.010) -0.065 (0.130) 0.002 (0.016) LAGE LPOP PALMER PALPOP (2) (3) Y1855 Y1856 Y1857 Y1858 Y1859 Y1860 (4) (5) (6) (7) 0.015 (0.027) 0.197*** (0.011) -0.053*** (0.010) -0.008 (0.131) -0.012 (0.016) -0.496*** (0.059) -0.442*** (0.079) -0.607*** (0.064) -0.463*** (0.061) -0.451*** (0.052) -0.53*** (0.058) -0.020 (0.021) 0.057*** (0.012) -0.0026 (0.008) 0.0312 (0.080) -0.003 (0.010) -0.021 (0.021) 0.075*** (0.013) -0.008 (0.008) 0.071 (0.078) -0.006 (0.010) -0.143*** (0.043) -0.074 (0.067) -0.124** (0.051) -0.215*** (0.049) -0.144*** (0.041) -0.177*** (0.048) -0.022 (0.021) 0.072*** (0.013) -0.008 (0.008) 0.062 (0.080) -0.005 YEAR -0.143*** State Fixed Effects No No No No Yes Yes -0.028*** (0.006) Yes R-squared 0.003 0.150 0.154 0.240 0.565 0.577 0.573 Notes: The dependent variable is described in the column heading. Results from an OLS Model. (N=1,726). Assets and loans are in thousands of dollars. Robust standard errors are listed below the coefficients in parentheses. * denotes significance at 10%; ** at 5% level; and *** at 1% level. 31 Table 7: Circulation-to Specie Model Specification (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) RR -13.230*** (2.766) -6.037*** (1.679) -2.577*** (0.887) 6.633** (3.375) -5.624*** (1.571) -5.962*** (1.703) -3.306*** (1.058) 7.247** (3.506) -7.342*** (2.076) 43.280*** (14.830) -4.327*** (1.563) -5.783*** (1.832) -4.402*** (1.264) 7.904** (3.649) -6.921*** (1.949) 42.790*** (14.710) -3.662** (1.428) 4.148* (2.314) 19.500*** (4.462) 9.799*** (2.594) 19.160*** (6.973) 1.023 (1.309) 21.000*** (4.343) -7.263*** (2.029) -1.837* (1.038) 11.470** (5.403) -8.071*** (2.172) 50.970*** (15.230) -5.257*** (1.598) -6.941*** (2.058) -4.111*** (1.260) 12.190** (5.447) -7.593*** (2.113) 48.510*** (15.070) -5.232*** (1.529) 9.364*** (3.277) 4.321 (3.709) 11.910*** (3.976) 11.550** (5.830) 12.620*** (2.864) 21.840*** (4.696) -6.293*** (1.868) -2.318 (1.472) No 0.012 No 0.030 No 0.041 No 0.059 Yes 0.125 Yes 0.136 LAGE LASSETS LPOP PALMER PALMERPOP Y1855 Y1856 Y1857 Y1858 Y1859 Y1860 YEAR State Fixed Effects R-squared -7.090*** (2.015) -3.760*** (1.209) 12.380** (5.461) -5.380*** -7.608*** (1.330) (2.114) 44.130*** 47.770*** (13.930) (14.720) -4.703*** -5.092*** (1.400) (1.561) 10.31*** (3.391) 4.896 (3.812) 11.860*** (3.966) 10.190* (5.616) 9.981*** (2.331) 19.960*** (4.459) 3.274*** (0.607) Yes Yes 0.120 0.134 Notes: Assets are in thousands of dollars. Results from an OLS Model. (N=1,726). Dependent variable is banknote circulation-to-specie. Robust standard errors are listed below the coefficients in parenthesis. * denotes significance at 10%; ** at 5% level and *** at 1% level. 32 (8) Table 8: Endogenous Market Structure Data Description Variable Name Description N Number of state banks registered in market RR Dummy variable indicating railroad access within county LPOP Log of total (free and slave) population from U.S. Census: linear interpolation for years 1854-1859 Measure of drought severity, constructed from Palmer Drought Severity Index DROUGHT DRPOP Interaction of drought and population Binary variable indicating that market is in state of Indiana IN SCO Binary variable indicating that market in state that requires banks to have charter from state legislature IN55-60 Binary variable indicating that market is in Indiana, but not in 1854 Indiana time trend variable INTT IN58-60 Binary variable indicating market is in Indiana and 1857-1860 33 34 #Mkts #Mkts| N = 0 #Mkts| N = 1 #Mkts| N = 2 #Mkts | N ≥ 3 AvgPop AvgPop| N = 0 AvgPop| N = 1 AvgPop| N = 2 AvgPop| N ≥ 3 Drought DRPOP 1855 1856 RR=0 RR=1 RR=0 RR=1 97 157 90 164 85 125 75 128 9 23 12 28 3 6 3 6 0 3 0 2 1,264 2,300 1,334 2,333 1,248 1,457 1,333 1,512 1,495 4,011 1,414 3,769 1,016 7,978 1,056 8,122 NA 12,976 NA 17,362 0.23 -0.06 0.57 -0.22 1.70 2.26 6.43 8.70 1857 RR=0 RR=1 77 177 66 131 9 35 2 10 0 1 1,391 2,341 1,393 1,556 1,532 3,216 692 7,972 NA 18,352 1.19 -0.42 9.11 11.26 1858 1859 RR=0 RR=1 RR=0 RR=1 88 189 86 191 77 140 73 140 9 39 10 41 2 9 3 9 0 1 0 1 1,470 2,473 1,510 2,565 1,476 1,600 1,452 1,617 1,583 3,751 2,194 3,982 715 8,749 628 9,092 NA 18,420 NA 18,487 0.57 -0.27 0.41 -0.19 7.04 9.34 5.14 6.83 Table 9: Endogenous Market Structure Summary Statistics 1854 RR=0 RR=1 107 147 94 117 12 19 1 6 0 5 1,296 2,219 1,206 1,420 1,970 3,856 1,685 7,555 NA 8,291 0.05 0.02 0.54 1.00 1860 RR=0 RR=1 143 219 113 162 20 46 6 10 4 1 997 2,241 832 1,475 1,813 3,541 1,584 8,118 683 7,822 0.82 -0.53 3.12 4.13 Table 10: Duopoly-Plus Ordered Probit Models. Number of Banks as Dependent Variable. µ1 /σ54 µ2 /σ54 LP OP/σ54 RR/σ54 DR/σ54 DRP OP/σ54 SCO/σ54 IN/σ54 1854 5.812*** (2.319) 0.643*** (.247) 0.664** (.317) -0.345 (.267) -2.574*** (.944) 0.942*** (.361) -1.231*** (.401) 1.015*** (.295) | LogLikelihood | 80.504 Observations 254 1855 5.814*** (1.903) 0.394 (.203) 0.702*** (.263) -0.400 (.244) 0.376 (.279) 0.215** (.103) -0.849*** (.324) 0.342 (.260) 1856 1857 1858 6.723*** 5.962*** 6.305*** (1.773) (1.456) (1.462) 0.515*** 0.383** 0.438** (.193) (.170) (.177) 0.862*** 0.738*** 0.772*** (.247) (.202) (.201) -0.508** -0.120 -0.129 (.229) (.231) (.225) -0.076 -0.110** -0.152** (.070) (.050) (.061) 0.017 0.005 0.007 (.017) (.010) (.012) -1.239*** -0.790*** -0.686*** (.328) (.273) (.247) 0.2912 0.213 0.112 (.248) (.237) (.233) 1859 6.747*** (1.465) 0.349** (.164) 0.839*** (.20) -0.204 (.219) -0.176** (.081) 0.006 (.016) -0.488** (.233) -0.059 (.235) 1860 4.886*** (1.039) 0.315** (.127) 0.641*** (.149) -0.501*** (.179) -0.151** (.071) 0.017 (.022) 0.291 (.196) -0.488*** (.218) 96.288 254 112.993 131.891 254 254 143.149 277 201.570 362 137.248 277 Notes: Table presents the estimates of an Ordered Probit Maximum Likelihood Model. Standard errors are listed below the coefficients in parentheses. Thresholds and ratios shown are if no railroad is present in the county. * denotes significance at 10%; ** at 5% level; and *** at 1% level. 35 Table 11: Triopoly-Plus Ordered Probit Models. Number of Banks as Dependent Variable. µ1 /σ54 µ2 /σ54 µ3 /σ54 LP OP/σ54 RR/σ54 DR/σ54 DRP OP/σ54 SCO/σ54 IN/σ54 1854 8.210*** (1.940) 0.584** (.234) 1.133*** (.375) 0.981*** (.265) -0.225 (.259) -1.591** (.716) 0.379** (.183) -1.143*** (.395) 1.095*** (.286) P V alue H0 : µ3 = µ2 0.096 | LogLikelihood | 89.833 Observations 254 1855 6.712*** (1.672) 0.370 (.197) 1.906** (.789) 0.820*** (.233) -0.395 (.245) -0.238 0.228** 0.150 (.067) -0.828*** (.326) 0.432 (.252) 1856 6.464*** (1.697) 0.521*** (.193) 1.675** (.598) 0.829*** (.236) -0.510*** (.229) -0.089 (.068) 0.022 (.016) -1.259*** (.327) 0.238 (.246) 1857 1858 5.697*** 6.071*** (1.427) (1.434) 0.389** 0.444** (.171) (.178) 1.554*** 1.589*** (.548) (.563) 0.702*** 0.740*** (.198) (.197) -0.208 -0.134 (.231) (.225) -0.118** -0.161*** (.049) (.061) 0.008 0.010 (.009) (.011) -0.793*** 0.688*** (.273) (.247) 0.205 0.108 (.237) (.233) 1859 6.535*** (1.441) 0.353** (.165) 1.556*** (.563) 0.811*** (.197) -0.208 (.219) -0.187** (.081) 0.010 (.016) -0.490** (.233) -0.0641 (.235) 1860 4.857*** (1.011) 0.316** (.127) 0.543*** (.198) 0.640*** (.145) -0.527*** (.178) -0.145** (.070) 0.012 (.020) -0.285 (.195) -0.470** (.217) 0.047 100.450 254 0.047 115.953 254 0.021 134.087 254 0.030 145.339 277 0.179 213.696 362 0.037 139.388 277 Notes: Table presents the results of an Ordered Probit Maximum Likelihood Model. Standard errors are listed below the coefficients in parentheses. Thresholds and ratios shown are if no railroad is present in the county. * denotes significance at 10%; ** at 5% level; and *** at 1% level. 36 Table 12: Cross Section Threshold Estimates 1854 Duopoly-Plus Model Thresholds Y M 6,310 (4,920) Y D 47,210 (80,580) Ratios Y D /Y M 7.479 (7.552) RR Percentage Percent Change 0.681 (.807) Triopoly-Plus Model Thresholds Y M 4,326 (1,631) Y D 15,911 (10,936) Y T 42,093 (41,768) Ratios Y D /Y M 3.678 (1.450) Y T /Y D 2.646 (2.493) RR Percentage Percent Change 0.258 (.354) 1855 1856 1857 1858 1859 1860 3,947 (1,957) 18,553 (19,467) 2,444 (692) 9,926 (6,312) 3,243 (1,246) 13,941 (10,038) 3,540 (1,314) 15,332 (10,696) 3,108 (968) 10,759 (5,969) 2,037 (557) 9,809 (5,641) 4.701 (3.046) 4.062 (1.815) 4.299 (1.911) 4.332 (1.869) 3.462 (1.202) 4.815 (1.956) 0.789 (.798) 0.803 (.640) 0.311 (.441) 0.182 (.358) 0.275 (.355) 1.183 (.811) 3,610 (1,390) 13,200 (9,510) 141,050 (255,610) 2,440 3,330 3,640 3,160 1,990 (710) (1,350) (1,420) (1,020) (536) 10,540 15,540 16,890 11,480 9,642 (6,860) (11,990) (12,470) (6,660) (5,423) 69,200 145,480 137,120 83,490 25,916 (99,790) (228,050) (201,870) (102,910) (20,660) 3.661 (1.564) 10.686 (21.603) 4.327 (1.993) 6.565 (9.406) 4.665 (2.230) 9.362 (11.679) 4.643 (2.125) 8.118 (10.071) 3.633 (1.321) 7.273 (10.724) 4.844 (1.935) 2.689 (1.758) 0.619 (.594) 0.851 (.685) 0.345 (.479) 0.199 (.379) 0.292 (.374) 1.279 (.857) Standard errors are in parentheses. The null hypothesis for the threshold ratios are Y D /Y M = 2 and Y T /Y D = 1.5. 37 Table 13: Pooled Ordered Probit Models. Number of Banks as Dependent Variable. µ1 /σ54 µ2 /σ54 µ3 /σ54 LP OP/σ54 RR/σ54 DR/σ54 DRP OP/σ54 SCO/σ54 IN/σ54 IN N 54 − 60/σ54 (1) 9.292*** (1.001) 0.649*** (.136) 1.472*** (.250) 1.169*** (.131) -0.312*** (.105) -0.104*** (.033) 0.002 (.006) -0.903*** (.149) 0.760*** (.227) -0.706*** (.248) IN 58 − 60/σ54 IN T T /σ54 P V alue : H0 µ3 = µ2 0.000 | LogLikelihood | 978.538 Observations 1,847 (2) 8.877*** (.945) 0.597*** (.129) 1.386*** (.238) 1.118*** (.124) -0.303*** (.10) -0.103*** (.031) 0.002 (.006) -0.878*** (.143) 0.490*** (.145) (3) (4) (5) (6) 9.279*** 10.210*** 9.601*** 10.067*** (.984) (1.131) (1.051) (1.104) 0.648*** 0.793*** 0.723*** 0.744*** (.135) (.158) (.148) (.151) 1.486*** (.248) 1.169*** 1.287*** 1.209*** 1.258*** (.129) (.148) (.138) (.144) -0.310*** -0.349*** -0.332*** -0.298*** (.104) (.116) (.111) (.112) -0.110*** -0.122*** -0.121*** -0.093*** (.033) (.038) (.036) (.035) 0.002 0.003 0.005 0.002 (.006) (.007) (.007) (.007) -0.919*** -1.023*** -0.977*** -0.920*** (.149) (.171) (.161) (.166) 0.731*** 0.793*** 0.510*** 0.783*** (.176) (.236) (.158) (.190) -0.775*** (.265) -0.628*** -0.704*** (.202) (.226) -0.207*** -0.218*** (.054) (.059) 0.000 977.059 1,847 0.000 973.669 1,847 935.917 1,847 934.424 1,847 938.572 1,847 Notes: Specifications (1)-(3) are for triopoly-plus. Specifications (4)-(6) are for duopoly-plus. Standard errors are listed below the coefficients in parentheses. σ55 − σ60 estimated but not shown. The null hypothesis for percentage change is that percentage change is equal to zero (e.g. 1.258=1). * denotes significance at 10%; ** at 5% level; and *** at 1% level. 38 Table 14: Pooled Specification (1) Thresholds Y M 2,823 (268) D Y 8,890 (1,381) T Y 25,422 (6,027) Ratios Y D /Y M 3.150 (.304) Y T /Y D 2.860 (.936) RR Percentage Percent Change 0.306 (.136) Cross Section Threshold Estimates (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) 2,816 2,808 2,797 (268) (264) (265) 8,932 8,851 8,884 (1,398) (1,363) (1,397) 26,005 25,649 (6,256) (6,067) 2,993 2,817 (288) (271) 9,381 9,088 (1,503) (1,465) 3.172 (.309) 2.911 (.965) 3.152 (.302) 2.898 (.955) 3.176 (.313) 3.134 (.307) 3.226 (.326) 0.311 (.137) 0.303 (.134) 0.312 (.139) 0.267 (.129) 0.316 (.141) Standard errors are in parentheses. The null hypothesis for the threshold ratios are Y D /Y M = 2 and Y T /Y D = 1.5. 39 8 Figures Figure 1: Spread of Railroads Across the United States. Taken from Atack et al. (2009) 40 Figure 2: Spread of Railroads and Banks Across the United States. Taken from Atack et al. (2014) 41
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz