Is There an Implicit Contract between Government and Business? The Disclosure Regulation of Corporate Political Spending through the Nexus of Contract Lenses1 Wei Feng Abstract There is a tendency in the theory of the firm to justify corporate political donations in terms of its personhood or citizenship — the complexity of rights and responsibilities corporations may hold as individuals under the common law. Corporations now are required more frequently than the past years to make information disclosures regarding this particular expenditure as a fulfilment of accountability under the law. One of the aims of this paper is to reframe the nature of corporate political spending as an implicit contract between the government and the corporation, and from that develop the optimal disclosure policy required in this implicit contract. The corporation’s political activities are redefined in order to recognize potential obstacles as well as consequences of the legislative procedure of this mandatory disclosure. Based on reframing the theoretical analysis of corporate political spending, this paper discusses a concrete set of problem surrounding the optimal disclosure policy, which aims at balancing efficiency and sustainability of the binary implicit contract between government and business. This theoretical analysis is expected to enhance the understanding of the mechanism of government-business relationships and corresponding disclosure policies. Key Words: Corporate Political Spending, Implicit Contract, Disclosure Regulation 1 For their thoughtful comments and suggestions, I would like to thank my supervisors, Prof Susan Watson and Prof David Mayes. All errors that remain are mine. 1 I. Introduction Whether the disclosure of corporate political spending should be mandated has been a disputed issue2. With stakeholders becoming aware of the significantly increase amount of corporate political spending, public listed companies have been put under the spotlight and asked to explain their relationships with the government or government officials, in particular those involving financial transactions. The obscurity of this information — whether the amount as well as the recipient is disclosed by corporations leads to concerns not only about the potential problem of corruption or the appearance of bribery, but also about the abuse of corporate funds invested by shareholders. Therefore it has been suggested that the political spending of corporations should be added to the mandatory disclosure list. This is to protect shareholders’ right to know, more importantly, potentially to require the consent from shareholders for this particular spending. However, for pending regulation, it is crucial to embark first on the analysis of potential regulatory impact and risk assessment related to creating, amending or repealing primary legislation or regulations before reaching any conclusions. Instead of focusing on the transparency, which is also essential to the issue, this paper traces back to the nature of the corporation and further the discussion from the perspective of the nexus of contract theory. In this paper, the argument will be placed in the context of the firm’s existence as a nexus of contracts3, where the de facto corporate expenditures spent on political issues without much public awareness will be considered as the fulfilment of implicit contracts between the government and corporations. In addition to the terms of the terms of contract between government and business, the optimal disclosure policy of the undeclared contract is also a question deserving further analysis. To be more specific, whether the effect of declaration of inferred clauses will be the initiative for legal evolution and how contracting parties interact to form the mechanism, will be important questions to answer, not only for the understanding of disclosure 2 Bebchuk, L. A., & Jackson Jr, R. J. (2013). Shining light on corporate political spending. 101 Geo. L.J. 923967. 3 Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of financial economics, 3(4), 305-360. 2 regulations of corporate political spending, but also for the understanding of the necessity and conditions for implicit contracts to become explicit. II. Review the Corporate Political Spending Disclosure The nexus of contract theory considers the company as a single contracting party coordinating different parties, internal stakeholders and external stakeholders, via a nexus of contracts which governs the rights and obligations of all contracting parties within in the entity4. From the perspective of this theory, a company’s legal personality is defined by and also comprised of a nexus of contracts. Among all the binary contractual relations, the contract between company and government is the one less explored, especially when compared with other contractual relations within the nexus. The relationship between government and business has been a long standing research question, though there are fewer studies investigating the connection as a contractual relationship, and even fewer regarding the contents of the contract between government and business. By considering information disclosed by corporations and the political parties/candidates or required by the market, the rights and obligations of the binary parities in this contractual relationship are likely to observe, even the implicit contract and its contents. Furthermore, to look at this pending regulation in the long term, the dynamics of contractual relations and the clarity of the contracts are happening in the changing context of the economic, social and political environment. Following the analytical framework set by Christopher M Bruner5, the influence of the implicit contracts and the disclosure on the inner structure of the corporation is examined on the political foundation of corporate governance. A. The Beginning of the Story: Firms as Nexus of Contracts 4 Kraakman, R. (2009). The anatomy of corporate law: a comparative and functional approach. Oxford University Press. 5 Bruner, C. M. (2013). Corporate Governance in the Common-law World: The Political Foundations of Shareholder Power. Cambridge University Press. 3 In 1976 Michael Jensen and William Meckling first developed the conception of the corporation as a nexus of contracts6, which had been embraced in the prior new institutional economics, Ronald Coase (Coase, 1937). Coase suggested that firms exist as more efficient organizations than the market because they endogenize and miniaturize transaction costs7. Contracts reduce the cost of bargaining by making it frequent, while also specifying mutually agreed – contingencies that might otherwise cause the deal to break down. His followers (such as Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Myers, 19778) have elaborated Coase’s notion that the firm as a “nexus of contracting relationships”. (See Figure 1) Figure 1. The Firm as a Nexus of Contracting Relationship Figure 1. Nexus of Contracts, source: Butler, H. N. (1988). Contractual theory of the corporation, The. Geo. Mason UL Rev., 11, 99. Among all relationships in the nexus, parties in binary contracts may have different objectives as well as behaviour. Bonded by the contract, contracting parties will perform as the contract stipulates, 6 See Supra 2. Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. economica, 4(16), 386-405. 8 Myers, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of financial economics, 5(2), 147-175; 7 4 knowing that otherwise they will face penalties for breaking it. Nevertheless, they will still be motivated to advance their interests within the framework of contract by taking full advantage of every chance that is explicitly allowed or implicitly not forbidden in the contract. Such opportunities to advance the individual interest, which may conflict with or minimize the common interest of all stakeholders, are more likely to emerge in complex and uncertain environments. In such environments, according to the nexus of contract theory, it is usually the case that the information possessed by the parties involved is asymmetrical and will be used by the advantageous parties to improve their own interests. The business environment with political participation can make an applicable example. Given the uncertainty and complexity of the external environment, the public relationship, especially relationship with the government, can serve the mutual goals of all stakeholders as it claims, or can be used to better the chances of politically engaging individuals for their own future careers. As the advantaged party with private information, executives in charge of political affairs may be able to use the asymmetry to favourably interpret (or even to misrepresent) their actions to the principals. The nexus of contract theory also suggest that this kind of information asymmetry can be reduced by several corporate governance mechanisms, among which more elaborative contracts, more effective supervision and more ex ante precautionary measure provided by the principals are usually suggested9. Generally, the principle of all these governance mechanism is to limit opportunistic behaviour and align shared goals. In the nexus, the binary contract between the government and the corporations remains more obscure then the others. One possible reason is to avoid a quick and thoughtless classification as bribery, nepotism and cronyism. Other potential explanations may argue that the contractual relationship is invalid due to the dominant position of the government. The inequality between the two contractual parties has the chance to alter the nature of the contract. However, from the perspective of rights and obligations, agreements between the two parties still can be established. The 9 Bukspan, E. (2005). The Notion of Trust as a Comprehensive Theory of Contract and Corporate Law: A New Approach to the Conception that the Corporation Is a Nexus of Contract. bepress Legal Series, 493. 5 explicit contracts can be understood as laws govern corporations and their business activities, yet between the government and the business organizations, the contractual relationship can be discovered more than above. B. Corporate Political Spending: the Implicit Contract between the Government and Corporations The contents of government-business relationship apart from what the law states is constituted by a set of acquiescent agreement, which can be understood as an implicit contract. Based on the definition, the implicit contract infers the informal contract based on the future values of relations among the contracting parties. The major characteristic of implicit contract is self-enforcement, which means transactions established by the contract are mainly accomplished by the self-coordination of the contracting parties. For corporations from all industries, the achievement of objectives requires the support from well-designed corporate governance. According to Zingales (1997)10, corporate governance is a complex of constraints built by implicit contracts regarding bargaining around the quasi-rent ex post, when corporate governance is a mechanism to resolve the problem of creation and allocation of the rent. From this perspective , discussions under the framework of complete contract theory appears to be unreasonable, because the complete contract theory assumes that all arrangement can be made ex ante, which leaves no room for negotiations afterwards and hence no necessity for corporate governance. In practice, explicit contracts under the framework of complete contracts are not able to incorporate every detail of daily operations. Even if it could at a certain point, the executory cost will keep increasing as contracts becoming more complicated. Yet explicit contracts in practice are frequently formulated in vague expressions, which is partly because sometimes selfenforcement is more efficient than court-enforcement. As the objectives of corporate governance, the effectual way to improve efficiency is to allocate resources effectively. Industrial characteristics of the efficient allocation of resources require coordination from the inner power of firms. Especially when the source of the power is coming from 10 Kaplan, S. N., & Zingales, L. (1997). Do investment-cash flow sensitivities provide useful measures of financing constraints?. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1), 169-215. 6 the core resources attached to the managerial personnel, drafting a contract will engender the interest of shareholders and cause more information asymmetry. Explicit contracts in corporate governance, such as remuneration contracts, are hardly able to cover all possibilities. Therefore more discretionary power is given to managerial personnel. On one hand, shareholders expect the enforcement of this part of the power will bring more profit to the firm; on the other hand, they have concerns that this power will cause failures in operations. The conflict between the efficiency and stability is reflected on the design of corporate governance as the supervision and control of this discretionary power. This role can be fulfilled by an implicit contract, the theoretical inference is based on the core resources. First it enhances the bargaining power of the managerial staff with shareholders. Second, the fear of loss of control over the key resource can effectively prevent their impulsion for opportunism. The stability of the mechanism maintained by implicit contracts is depicted and realized by embedding networks built by various games, while the corporate governance objectives can be achieved by the influence exerted during the corporate contract design which involves the entire network. From the perspective of the theory of nexus of contracts, corporations are the nexus of contracts among all parties possessing productive factors: that is to say, a set of comprehensive societal contracts coordinate all elemental capitals under the framework of sustainable objectives. On the condition of investing capitals into the corporation, stakeholders assume that they have contingent claims for corporate properties. These relationships are viewed from the firm as obligations to all owners of productive factors, and it is not due to the firm’s generosity or enlightenment to undertake such responsibilities, but the endogenous legal principle embedded in the contractual relationship. To figure out the contents of the implicit contracts, it is also important to recognize that the scope of productive factors, the content, formality and characteristics of corporate contracts are evolving with the passage of time. Currently, the contracting elements of the firm include: financial capital, human resources, social capital and ecological capital. First, financial capital is the most traditional form of capital, such as equity and debt capital. Second, human resources incorporate physical, intellectual, technical and emotional input of employees. Third, social capital includes legal environment and social infrastructure provided by the government, mutual trust and relationship 7 among communities. Fourth, ecological capital covers natural environment and dynamic relationships among species. Among all the nexus of contracts, there are dominant and implicit contracts, as well as complete and incomplete contracts. For example, financial capital and the initial financial contract on the establishment of the firm determine the capital structure and initial ownership, which is a dominant as well as a complete contract. Meanwhile, the contracts between corporations and government as well as the contracts between corporations and employees contain dominant and implicit contents at the same time. Specifically, the authoritativeness of the government and the compulsory feature of law enforcement determine the dominant power of the government in the contracts between corporations and the government. The government requires corporations to observe rules and obey the law, which are the contents of the contract between corporations and the government. In this process, there is less room for corporations to negotiate. Terms of the contracts stipulate explicitly that corporations shall abide by the law and deliver taxes as required, which are complete and dominant for the contracts. Only when corporations fulfil their responsibilities for the government, do they have the legitimate ground of existence, which is one of the premises of the firm. However, as time has passed, the political system as well as organizational structure of the business has also changed. According to a recent Harris poll, many American citizens believe that big companies (88%), Political Action Committees (PACs) (87%), banks (85%), financial institutions (85%), political lobbyists (84%) and the new media (72%) are having excessive influence and power in Washington D. C.11. The widespread public perception appears to be that business is now exerting a significant influence on politics through campaign finance and lobbying activities. The role of money on the form of campaign contribution is implicit. Seemingly, political contribution is considered necessary for access to the political process, hence the exercise of effective influence on the political dynamics. 11 The Harris Poll, April, 2011, http://www.harrisinteractive.com/NewsRoom/HarrisPolls/tabid/447/mid/1508/articleId/790/ctl/ReadCustom%2 0Default/Default.aspx 8 Moreover, this latent de facto contract has not become explicit yet. There are numerous arguments about the ethics regarding the political contributions from corporations, concerning this conduct become a virtual quid pro quo. With the increasing uncertainty of external environment, corporations have been making every possible effort to maximize the outcome expectations, including participating in policy making process to ensure of favourable conditions for future development. C. A Closer Look: The contents of the implicit contract between the business and the government Although the contents of the implicit contract between business and government seem discretionary, it is still possible to grasp some beneficiary outcomes for the corporation from the literature, which are “exchanged” by the efforts of developing political connections, including corporate political spendings. 1. Profit monopolization As commonly accepted in the dominant neoclassic framework, rent-seeking activities are considered as one way to increase value under the firm’s objective of profit maximization. Companies with better connections with politician in power obtain benefits through these rent-seeking activities, which enable well-connected firms to derive competitive advantages via monopoly control of industry, accessibility to funding and easy access to profitable projects subsidized by government budgets which are under the control of a connected politician. Before the World War II, the economic model of developing markets, such as Brazil, Mexico, India and few others depended heavily on politically connected firms or state funded schemes for boost its economic development, yet few had succeeded (see Woo 199812). Economic structures were malformed by such state intervention, especially where its private sector was absent in the early stages. Most modern societies impose strict rules to prevent conglomeration and also rules to promote fair trading practices as antidotes to rent-seeking behaviour. In a purely competitive market, where 12 Woo, W.P. 1998. State Supported Programmes and Their Costs. Singapore: Mimeo Presented at the National University of Singapore. 9 there is less ownership concentration in a firm and slight distortions in the economy, a firm that is highly efficient with the lowest cost of production will sell its product at a market price and will earn a normal profit13. In Krueger’s (1974)14 model, firms seeking rent try to create a market barrier, which will create an artificial and monopoly market price for a product and hence earn a high profit margin. In this way the firm can produce at levels that reduce consumer surplus and abnormal profits. Meanwhile, governments, which are the regulators to ensure fair competition, could create firms under their control or establish both legal (e.g., Golden, 1994) or related party connection to a firm aimed at preventing fuller competition for a government-linked or political-group-controlled firm. Hence, promotion of rent-seeking is a tunnel to create extra value by connected firms. An answer for why such firms differ in terms of agency costs, ownership structure and control mechanisms such firms use differ: Zingales and Dyck (2001)15 found controlling owners would keep all benefits while costs are shared with other shareholders. Various means of control such as concentration of ownership in the hands of the major shareholders, proxies and/or managers aligned to the owners are becoming prevalent to control these benefits among politically connected firms. 2. Preferential Financing Access A number of studies show firms connected to politicians have easier access to financing through relationship-based connections to financial institutions, although the access has higher risk of default during economic downturns. La Porta et al. (1999)16 and Rajan and Zingales (1998)17 documented that well-connected firms can access to preferential financial conditions more easily. Related lending is on more favourable terms than arms-length lending. 13 See supra 4. Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. The American Economic Review, vol(issue), 291-303. 15 Dyck, A., & Zingales, L. (2004). Private benefits of control: An international comparison. The Journal of Finance, 59(2), 537-600. 16 La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (2000). Investor protection and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1), 3-27. 17 Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (1998). Which capitalism? Lessons from the East Asian crisis. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 11(3), 40-48. 14 10 Election circle also affect the financing channel, for example, government banks increase lending in election years compared to private banks, which reduces the political intervention costs before elections. According to Khwaja and Mian (2004)18, Pakistani firms connected to politicians received twice as much loans from government banks compared to unconnected firms. Irresponsible lending weakens the lending banks, and increase transfer of wealth from debt-holders to shareholders. Claessens, Djankov, and Lang (2000)19 trace this behaviour to politically connected financial institutions being less prudent in loans. Another issue regarding preferential financial aid is that government tend to bail out firms when these firms are in financial distress (Ito, 1998)20. Malaysia bailed out 94 such firms in 1999. Nonfinancial and financial firms being rescued for reasons of political connections introduces moral hazard. Political connections play an important role in bail outs: an example is Silverado Finance in the USA during the Credit Union debacle under Reagan presidency. Firms received sizeable loans from the World Bank (1996)21 were mainly politically connected. The continued practice of a relationship-based system will further entrench incumbent firms at the expense of new entrants: Kali, Wiwattanakantang, and Charumilind (2001)22. According to Ariff and Khalid (2005)23 banks in Thailand inclined to provide preferential access of long-term credits for firms that are connected politically. Such banks were provided with implicit guarantee from government, even the politically connected firms were included in the rescue plan, while the rescue of such finance companies in May 1997 was the key reason for the following financial crisis. 3. Public images and market confidence 18 Khwaja, A. I., & Mian, A. (2005). Do lenders favor politically connected firms? Rent provision in an emerging financial market. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(4), 1371-1411. 19 Claessens, S., Djankov, S., & Xu, L. C. (2000). Corporate performance in the East Asian financial crisis. The World Bank Research Observer, 15(1), 23-46. 20 Ito, T. (1998). Bail-Out, Moral Hazard, and Credibility. In Wharton conference on Asian Twin Financial Crises, Tokyo (10 March). 21 Wang, Y., & Shilling, J. D. (1995). Managing capital flows in East Asia. Office of the Vice President, East Asia and Pacific Region, the World Bank. 22 Charumilind, C., Kali, R., & Wiwattanakantang, Y. (2006). Connected Lending: Thailand before the Financial Crisis. The Journal of Business, 79(1), 181-218. 23 Ariff, M., & Khalid, A. M. (2005). Liberalization and growth in Asia. Elgar: Town?. 11 If a firm is controlled by a political group, then it follows that corporate affairs of such firms are more likely to be impacted by the influence of the political group(s) in control of the government. Using Porta, Lopez-De-Silanes, and Shleifer (1999)24 argument that property rights or the law matters, Claessens, Djankov, and Lang (2000)25 maintain that dissimilarity in result of behaviours from the quality of investor protection due to the differences of legal environments. Politicians are perhaps the best among influential groups who could provide greater degree of property protection to investor. Recent literature suggests political connectedness of a firm provides value-enhancing benefits to firms. It seems corporate decisions derive from different motivations, which are directly related to controls exercised by large or other controlling shareholder(s) such as government nominees. 4. Job creations and elections Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan (2004)26 found that in France, CEOs of large publicly listed firms with political connections make corporate decisions that potentially beneficial to politicians in increasing the politicians’ re-election chances, while firms aim to strengthen political connections. Aggregate cooperation conditions are of great importance to voters when making decisions whether to elect an incumbent official. The economic favours extended by connected CEOs to politicians are reciprocated in terms of average lower tax payments and increase in subsidies received. Incumbent governments using economic policy tools could affect election outcomes (Ito 1998)27. The above listed preferential conditions usually do not come in vain. To be well-connected with government, firms have to either give up certain part of ownership (e.g. SOEs) or make financial endeavour to develop such tie, which potentially will bring the additional benefit for the firms. The provision of this implicit contract are well accepted yet not specified, for which the establishment and effectuation of the contract is separated. It is assumed that the implicit contract is established once the 24 Porta, R., Lopez‐de‐Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate ownership around the world. The Journal of Finance, 54(2), 471-517. 25 Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J. P., & Lang, L. H. (2002). Disentangling the incentive and entrenchment effects of large shareholdings. The Journal of Finance, 57(6), 2741-2771. 26 Bertrand, M., Duflo, E., & Mullainathan, S. (2004). How much should we trust differences-in-differences estimates?. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1), 249-275. 27 Supra 19. 12 corporation is committed to “exchange clauses”, which can be between the corporation and government or corporate executives and government officials. However, the effectuation of the contract is subjected to various conditions. As implicit contracts are not court-enforced and sustained mainly through the threat of future retaliation by the government. Corporations making efforts to be connected with government or government officials are facing the risk that government will not fulfil the contract, and the risk is further magnified by linking the initial risk the corporation faces to political risks. Furthermore, if the information regarding corporate political spending is released to the market, the corporation will not just need to pay attention to market confidence but also political opinions. D. Explicate the Implicit Contract: Disclosure of Corporate Political Spending Currently the responsibilities for disclosure of corporate political spending mainly falls on recipients, candidates and parties is disclosing the amount and the source of their funding as required by the campaign finance law. The potential problem for this information disclosure arrangement is that this unilateral disclosure by recipients has the risk of misrepresentation through concealment of the actual amount28. The other significant reason that the public petitioned the rule making agencies is that the lack of corporation-centred information supply costs interested stakeholder a great amount of time to gather it from the campaign finance disclosures, and there is also no guarantee that they will collect the full set of information. Academics argue for the rationale of corporate political disclosure: their main arguments come in two layers: 1) regarding to the spending itself, it is suggested that a growing number of shareholders are showing interest in learning about the spending. The scope, amount through all channels, frequency and timing are all considered useful information for stakeholders to develop their investment decisions29. Moreover, it is not just about the right to know, but more importantly about 28 Citizens for Responsibility and Ethics in Washington, The Myth of Corporate Disclosure Exposed, 2014, http://www.citizensforethics.org/page//PDFs/Reports/4_15_2014_Myth_of_Corporate_Disclosure_Exposed_The_Problem_with_Political_Spending_ Reports_CREW.pdf?nocdn=1 29 Bebchuck, Shining Light on Corporate Political Spending, 2012. 101 Geo. L.J. 923 (2012-2013) 13 gaining the consent of this non market strategy; 2) regarding disclosure, one of its effective ways of increasing the accountability of the firm. The solution of this question comes down to the right legal strategies and the effect of the chosen strategy. Legal strategies in the corporate law context usually refer to “a generic method of deploying substantive law to mitigate the vulnerability of principals to the opportunism of their agents”30. To achieve this goal, the most common methods can be found in the following table 1: Table 1 Legal Strategies Deployed in the Corporate Law Context Regulatory strategies Governance Strategies Agent Affiliation Appointment Decision Agent Constraint Terms Rights Rights Incentives EX ANTE RULES ENTRY SELECTION INITIATION TRUSTEESHIP EX POST STANDARDS EXIT REMOVAL VETO REWARD Source: Hansmann, H., & Kraakman, R. (2004). Agency problems and legal strategies, P23. Whether to choose ex ante rules or ex post standards to regulate corporate political spending disclosure depends on the regulatory goals. Lawmakers have employed information as a regulatory tool since the insurance disclosure31, for its political neutrality and less interference in the market operation and individual choice. When comes to opposing regulation, mandatory disclosure has become one of the regulators’ favourites. However, before any regulation being implemented, it is supposed to have a goal to accomplish, and it is expected to consider the mechanism through which the goal will be accomplished. Disclosure-based regulation often states the purpose such as “improving transparency” or “providing 30 31 Hansmann, H., & Kraakman, R. (2004). Agency problems and legal strategies. Miller, F. H. (1979). Truth in Lending Act. The Business Lawyer, 1405-1422. 14 information to consumers,” but it is less explained why the additional information will be valuable, to whom it will be valuable and how it leads to behavioural changes as desired to32. The mechanism by which information affects behaviour is complex. The information must be directed at the appropriate decision-maker and the appropriate decision. Furthermore, it must be provided in a form accessible to and usable by the appropriate decision-maker, and the decisionmaker must be able to respond to the information. Moreover, disclosure can have significant costs beyond the costs of creating and disseminating the information within the context of nexus of contracts. III. Political Foundations in Change: The Contract of Dynamics Christopher Bruner33 has developed the political theory of corporate governance in the commonlaw world by arguing that the diversified degree of managerial power structure can be explained not just by how the corporate governance systems varies among countries, but it also needed to be considered in the broader social and political context. Based on this theoretical framework, the implicit contract between government and business is set to the context of environmental changes. When it comes to changes along timeline, industry policy or government regulations over business activities commonly only can come into being after the industry or business developed to certain salient degree. When the formal institution, i.e. legal system is behind the practical need, the substantial mechanism will fill in the blank and meet the actual demand of the parties involved. Specifically, for most industries, only when the sector has developed into certain level, would government implement specific regulation. For example, only when the monopolies emerged, would antitrust laws come into shape; government only considered environmental protection laws and regulations after seeing social problems caused by environmental pollution. Few government will take 32 Ripken, S. K. (2006). The dangers and drawbacks of the disclosure antidote: toward a more substantive approach to securities regulation. Baylor Law Review, 58(1), 139-204. 33 See Supra 2. 15 precautions before an industry or an issue coming into being. Which is to say, when the government began to regulate an industry, the industry generally has been relatively mature, where the main big players in the industry are already in place. At this time, any implementation of laws and regulations will no doubt affect those enterprises have already occupied a dominant position in the market. Moreover, it are those leading industries or corporations who have the capacity to make their voice in the legislative process. For them, getting involved in the political activities are mainly for the corresponding power, which potentially can act as an insurance for the vested interest. In an ideal world, each corporation would want politicians who can offer more support come into power. However, there are numerous players rather than just one firm, and they all have their own favourite candidates. For the corporation, it is too risky to “bet” on a single candidate or a single party, which will turn into a disadvantage if the others came into power. Even if the candidate/party was elected, due the common feature of campaign finance, the candidate/party must have accepted donations from more than one single Political Activity Commission (PAC). Under the influence of diversified PACs, it is unrealistic for the candidate/party to make any individual promise. Meanwhile, what concerns the leading corporations behind those PACs is not how to develop themselves based on some newly introduced laws or regulations. For the most of the time, these corporations are concerned about their vested interests from a market which was originally lack of supervision will decrease due to the new laws or regulations, which will give opponents a better chance to challenge their market position. Therefore, for most corporations, they realized that the most important thing is not to elect a candidate/party who can help implementing laws and policies fit their interest best to expand the vested interests, but to elect one candidate/party will maintain the stability of regulatory environment. Regardless which political power is in the office, as long as existing policies and laws continues, the vested interests will be well protected. Corporate political expenditure seems a tacit understanding between government and corporations. Viewed in this way, it is not difficult to understand that why currently US Democratic Party are receiving more donations. Because back to 1970s, the US 16 Congress was under the charge of Democrats. It is assumed that corporations make political contributions to the incumbent party for re-election to ensure the continuity of regulatory environment. Accordingly, from the perspective of risk hedging, the most of corporations will not make donations to a single recipient, but donate to several political candidates/ parties at the same time. For example, Tobacco company Phillip Morris donated 1.6 million to Republican and 0.4 million to Democrats in 1996 election, while Association of Trial Lawyers donated 0.36 million and 0.16 million to Democrats and Republican separately34. This pattern of political donations is not due to the support for the party, but more closer to a way of encouragement for the incumbent. As for the contribution made for the “unfriendly party”, it is more like a hedge, which would possibly prevent they make a decision against their favour. By contrast, groups without any vested interest, such as trade unions have less concerns in donating. In the 2008 election, 55 percent of corporate donations went to Democrats, and 92 percent of union donations went to the Democratic Party35. With the emergence of thousands of PACs, candidates/ parties will be subject to donors when comes to either campaign advocates or afterwards policy proposals for the purpose of the financial support as well as potential voters. Therefore, implicit contract between government and business is the result of a repeated game containing changes of corporate governance structures and market positions of multiple players. VI. The Usefulness of the Disclosure The disclosure-based regulation is supposed to reduce information asymmetry in the market, from the perspective of effective communication, the goal can only be achieved on the condition that the targeted audience have got the essential information in a perceivable form. Moreover, the recipients must care enough about the information and have the ability to make influential decisions. 34 35 Data source: www. opensecret.org See id. 17 More importantly, the corporation is willing and able to make adjustment according to the market pressure36. However, from the analysis above, given the disclosure regulation is viewed as the development result of the implicit contract, the regulatory disclosure scheme will be implemented when the content of contractual relations become explicate and stable. Instead of the policy aiming at producing certain result in the market, disclosure regulation is the outcome of the interaction of market participants. From this point of view, the effectiveness and therefore usefulness of disclosure as regulation in corporate political spending becomes will not be the only issue that matters in the discussion. When the disclosure of implicate contract between government and business become optimal for the regulator or the corporation, the information, i.e. the explicate provision will be offered to the market. Implicit contracts can be taken as the early stage of formal contracts. Whether this informal institution can become formal and being accepted by government and business depends on the cost and benefit of this disclosure for the dominant market participant. Therefore, regardless of whether there is too much information in the market or whether the regular market participants have the capability to process the information, the disclosure of corporate political spending will come into being when this part of content of implicit contract between government and corporation becomes explicit. V. Conclusion and Further Discussions Through lenses of the nexus of contracts theory, disclosure regulations of corporate political spending is reframed as implicit contract between government and business in this paper, followed by the discussion of the terms of the binary contract. Corporations develop political connections at the cost of financial donations or deduction in ownership and control, in return, they incline to get easier access to profit monopoly power, preferential financing access, and positive public image. Moreover, 36 See Dalley, P. J. (2007). The Use and Misuse of Disclosure as a Regulatory System. 34 Florida State University Law Review 1089-1131. 18 the candidate/party receiving donations have been benefited from increasing odds of getting elected or re-elected due to the financial contributions. Through the analysis of the interaction of government and corporation in the contractual relation in dynamics, a hypothesis can be deducted that government as a contractual party with regulatory power will also pursue the maximum of its welfare. Whether to pass a pending regulation mostly depends on to how much degree it will serve its comprehensive goals. In this case, if the income from corporate political spending is part of the government concerns, the disclosure regulation appears not the current best choice due to the potential adverse effect. The timing of implicit contract become explicit is still subjected to the benefit-cost evaluation result of the dominant contractual party. Although the disclosure regulation of corporate political spending can be affected by many other factors, the conceptual framework developed in this paper can be a start of analysing how implicit become explicit and hence the legislative dynamics. 19 Reference: Ajayi, R.A., and M. Mehdian. 1994. “Test of Investors Reactions to Major Surprises.” Journal of International Financial Markets, Institution and Money 4 (1–2): 115–128. Alesina, A., and H. Rosenthal. 1995. Partisan Politics, Divided Government and the Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Amihud, Y., and A. Wohl. 2003. “Political News and Stock Prices: The Case of Sadam Hussein Contracts.” Working Paper. Stern School of Business, New York University. Accessed April 4, 2004. http://ssrn.com/papers.cfm?abstract=425640. Annuar, M.N., and M. Shamsher. 1994. The Efficiency of the Kuala Lumpur Stock Exchange: A Collection of Empirical Findings. Kuala Lumpur: University Putra Malaysia. Aoki, M., Kim, H., Okuno-Fujiwara, M., 1997. The Role of Government in East Asian Economic Development: Comparative Institutional Analysis. Oxford University Press, New York. Ariff, M., and L. Johnson. 1994. Securities Markets and Stock Pricing: Evidence from a Developing Capital Market in Asia. International edition. Singapore: Longman Professional Books. Ariff, M., and A. Khalid. 2005. Financial Liberalization and Economic Growth in Asia: 21st Century Challenges. Cheltenham/Northampton, NJ: Edward Elgar Publishing. Asquith, P., and D.W. Mullins. 1986. “Equity Issues and Offering Dilution.” Journal of Financial Economics 15 (1–2): 61–89. Azariadis, C., 1975. Implicit contracts and underemployment equilibria. Journal of Political Economy 83 (6), 1183–1202. Azariadis, C., Stiglitz, J., 1983. Implicit contracts and fixed price equilibria. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98, 2–22. 20 Baily, M., 1974. Wages and employment under uncertain demand. Review of Economic Studies 41 (1), 37–50. Ball, R., and P. Brown. 1968. “An Empirical Evaluation of Accounting Income Numbers.” Accounting Research 6: 444–454. Beatty, R.P., Ritter, J.R., 1986. Investment banking, reputation, and the underpricing of initial public offerings. Journal of Financial Economics 15 (1–2), 213–232. Beatty, R.P., Bunsis, H., Hand, J.R.M., 1998. The indirect economic penalties in SEC investigations of underwriters. Journal of Financial Economics 50 (2), 151–186. Becker, G., 1968. Crime and punishment: an economic approach. Journal of Political Economy 76 (2), 169–217. Berle, A.A., and G.G.C. Means. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York, NY: Transaction Books. Bertrand, M., E. Duflo, and S. Mullainathan. 2004. “How Much Should We Trust Differences-inDifferences Estimates?” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (1): 249–275. Blume, L., D. Easley, and M. O’Hara. 1994. “Market Statistics and Technical Analysis: The Role of Volume.” The Journal of Finance 49: 153–181. Bongini, P., S. Claessens, and G. Ferri. 2000. “The Political Economy of Distress in East Asian Financial Institutions.” Paper 2263, World Bank Country Economic Department. Booth, J., Smith, R., 1986. Capital raising, underwriting and the certification hypothesis. Journal of Financial Economics 15 (1–2), 261–281. Brown, S., and J. Warner. 1985. “Using Daily Stock Returns: The Case of Event Studies.” Journal of Financial Economics 14: 3–31. 21 Bruner, C. M. (2013). Corporate Governance in the Common-law World: The Political Foundations of Shareholder Power. Cambridge University Press. Carter, R., Manaster, S., 1990. Initial public offerings and underwriter reputation. Journal of Finance 45 (4), 1045–1067. Carter, R.B., Dark, F.H., Singh, A.K., 1998. Underwriter reputation, initial returns, and the longrun performance of IPO stocks. Journal of Finance 53 (1), 285–311. Chan, Y.C., A. Chui, and C. Kwok. 2001. “The Impact of Salient Political and Economic News on the Trading Activity.” Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 9: 195–217.Chari, V.V., 1983. Involuntary unemployment and implicit contracts. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98, 107–122. Chemmanur, T.J., Fulghieri, P., 1994. Investment bank reputation, information production, and financial intermediation. Journal of Finance 49 (1), 57–79. Chen, C. M., Ariff, M., Hassan, T., & Mohamad, S. (2014). Does a firm's political connection to government have economic value?. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy, 19(1), 1-24. Chen, D., Zhang, T., Xiang, L., 2008. Law environment, government regulation and implicit contract: empirical evidence from the scandals of Chinese listed companies. Economic Research Journal 3, 60–72 (in Chinese). Chen, G., Firth, M., Kim, J., 2004. IPO underpricing in China’s new stock markets. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 14 (3), 283–302. Chen, X., Ye, P., Chen, D., 2003. Opportunistic restructuring and regulation rigidity. Economic Research Journal 5, 13–22 (in Chinese). Cheng, F.F. 2000. The impact of accounting information on share prices in an emerging market, Proceedings of the PACAP/FMA conference, Melbourne, July 2000. 22 Cheng, Y. 2005. “Portfolios and Policies: the 2004 Presidential Election.” Accessed June 21, 2005. http://ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=664047. Chowdhry, B., Sherman, A., 1996. International differences in oversubscription and underpricing of IPOs. Journal of Corporate Finance 2 (4), 359–381. Claessens, S., S. Djankov, and L. Lang. 2000. Corporate Performance in the East Asian Financial Crisis. Washington, DC: World Bank, Country Economic Department.Glaeser, E.L., Shleifer, A., 2003. The rise of the regulatory state. Journal of Economic Literature 41 (2), 401–425. Coarse, R. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica 4 November: 386–405. Dinc, I.S., and R. Brown. 2004. “Politicians and Banks: Political Influences on GovernmentOwned Banks in the Emerging Countries.” Accessed February 4, 2005. http://webuser.bus.umich.edu/dincs/paper. Faccio, M. 2006. “Politically Connected Firms.” American Economic Review 96 (1): 369–386. Fama, E.F., L. Fisher, M.C. Jensen, and R. Roll. 1969. “The Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information.” International Economic Review 10 (1): 1–21. Fazilah, M. 1996. “Performance of Group-affiliated Firms: A study of Politically-affiliated Business Group in Malaysia.” PhD dissertation, University of Rhode Island. Ferguson, T., and Voth, Hans J. 2004. “Betting on Hitler-The value of Political Connection in Nazi Germany.” Working paper, University of Massachusetts. Accessed February 4, 2005. http://ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=651984. Fisman, R. 2001. “Estimating the Value of Political Connections.” American Economic Review 91: 1095–1102. Gale, B. 1985. Politics and Business: A Study of Multi-Purpose Holdings Berhad. Petaling Jaya: Eastern University Press. 23 Gomez, E.T. 1993. “Corporate Involvement of Political Parties in Malaysia.” PhD dissertation, University of Malaya. Gomez, E.T. 1995. Political Business: Corporate involvement of Malaysian Political Parties, Softcover edition. Queensland: James Cook University of North Queensland Publication. Gomez, E.T., and K.S. Jomo. 1998. Malaysia’s Political Economy: Politics, Patronage and Profits. 2nd ed. Cambridge University Press. Gordon, D., 1974. A neo-classical theory of Keynesian unemployment. Economic Inquiry 12 (4), 431–459. Hart, O., 1983. Optimal labor contracts under asymmetric information: an introduction. Review of Economic Studies 50 (1), 3–35. Hayes, R., Schaefer, S., 2000. Implicit contracts and the explanatory power of top executive compensation for future performance. RAND Journal of Economics 31 (2), 273–293. Huang, C., 2005. Securities regulatory efficiency and underwriter reputation: a case study of the China Southern Securities ‘MACAT incident’. Management World 7, 129–138 (In Chinese). Huang, C., Shi, G., 2006. Study on the association between securities regulator’s reputation and the reputation of underwriters. Economic JingWei 5, 116–119 (in Chinese). Ito, T. 1998. “Bail-out, Moral Hazard and Credibility.” Paper presented in Wharton Conference on Asia Twin Financial Crisis, Tokyo. Jiang, D., Liang, S., Chen, D., 2009. Government regulation, enforcement and economic consequences in a transition economy: empirical evidence from Chinese Listed Companies Conducting Split Share Structure Reform. China Journal of Accounting Research 2 (1), 71–99. 24 Johnson, S., and T. Mitton. 2003. “Cronyism and Capital Controls: Evidence from Malaysia. National Bureau of Economic Research meeting on “The Malaysian Currency Crisis,” Cambridge, MA, February, published in 2003.” Journal of Financial Economics 67: 351–382. Jomo, K.S., and E.T. Gomez. 1997. Rents and Development in Multiethnic Malaysia. London: Cambridge University Press. Kali, R., Y. Wiwattanakantang, and C. Charumilind. 2001. “Crony lending: Thailand before the Financial Crisis.” Working paper, University of Arkansas. Keynes, J.M., 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Khwaja, A.I., and A. Mian. 2004. “Do Lenders Favor Politically Connected Firms? Rent Provision in an Emerging Financial Market.” Working paper, University of Chicago. Krueger, Anne O. 1974. “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society.” American Economic Review 64 (3): 291–303. Krugman, P., 1991. Target zones and exchange rate dynamics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (3), 669–682. La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, R.W. Vishny, and G. Zamarippa. 1999. Related Lending. Manuscript, Harvard University, April 3, 1999. Lane, T., and S. Philips. 2002. “Moral Hazard, Does IMF Financing Encourage Imprudence by Borrowers and Lenders?” IMF Economic Issues 28. Lin, Y., 1994. The Theory of Institutional Change. Shanghai Joint Publishing (in Chinese). Liu, J., Yin, B., Yi, J., 2005. A positive analysis on relationship between China security underwriter’s reputation and IPO firm’s quality. Finance and Trade Economy 3, 9–16 (in Chinese). 25 Lyon, J. D., B. M. Barber, and Tsai, C.-L. 1999. “Improved Methods for Tests of Long-Run Abnormal Stock Returns.” The Journal of Finance 54 (1): 165–201. Mukherjee, A. (2010). The optimal disclosure policy when firms offer implicit contracts. The RAND Journal of Economics, 41(3), 549-573. North, D.C., Thomas, R.P., 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge University Press. Pistor, K., Xu, C., 2002. Law enforcement under incomplete law: Theory and evidence from financial market regulation, Working Paper, <http://www.ssrn.com>. Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes, and A. Shleifer. 1999. “Corporate Ownership Around the World.” The Journal of Finance 54 (2): 471–517. Posner, R., 1974. Theories of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 5 (2), 335–358. Rajan, R.G., and L. Zingales. 1998. “Which Capitalism? Lessons from the East Asian Crisis.” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 11: 40–48. Roberts, B. 1990. “A Dead Senator Tell No Lies: Seniority and the Distribution of Federal Benefits.” American Journal of Political Science 34: 31–58. Searle, P. 1999. The Riddle of Malaysian Capitalism. Kuala Lumpur: ASSA South East Asia Publication Series. Sharpe, S., 1990. Asymmetric information, bank lending and implicit contracts: a stylized model of customer relationships. Journal of Finance 45 (4), 1069–1087. Shleifer, A., 2005. Understanding regulation. European Financial Management 11 (4), 439–451. Song, W., Uzun, H., 2003.The impact of clients’ alleged financial reporting fraud on underwriter reputation. Working Paper, <http://www.ssrn.com>. 26 Spulber, D., 1999. Regulation and the Market. Shanghai: Shanghai Joint Publishing, Shanghai People’s Publishing House (in Chinese). Stigler, G.J., 1970. The optimal enforcement of laws. Journal of Political Economy 78 (3), 56– 536. Stigler, G.J., 1971. The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2 (1), 3–21. Wallner, K. (1997). Implicit contracts between regulator and firms: The case of Japanese casualty insurance. Woo, W.P. 1998. State Supported Programmes and Their Costs. Singapore: Mimeo presented at the National University of Singapore. World Bank. 1996. Managing Capital Flows in East Asia. Washington, DC: World Bank. Xu, C., 2008. Study on the effect of securities underwriter’s reputation based on the Chinese stock market. Ph.D. Thesis, Jinan University (in Chinese). Xu, H., Wei, L., 2007. Reputation effect of investment banks: research from aspects of market share and service quality. Economic Research 2, 124–136 (in Chinese). Yoshihara, K. 1998. The Rise of Ersatz Capitalism in South-East Asia. Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press. Yu, H., 1994. The economic theory of regulation and analysis of process. Economic Research 5, 50–54 (in Chinese). Zach, T. 2003. “Political Events and the Stock Market: Evidence from Israel.” International Journal of Business 8(3). Zhang, S., 2001. To clear the transmission channels, to improve the financial structure: China’s current macro-economic analysis. Management World 2, 8–20 (in Chinese). 27 Zhang, S., 2005. Implicit contracts between state-owned commercial banks in the reconstruction of firm management. Nankai Economic Studies 2, 79–83 (in Chinese). Zhang, Z., 2007. An analysis of the equilibrium regulation model in China’s securities market. Fudan Journal (Social Science Edition) 6, 19–25 (in Chinese). Zhang, Z., Yao, L., Li, F., 2001. China’s securities market system, the generation of risk and resolve. Economic Research 10, 60–66 (in Chinese). Zhou, H., 2006. A depressed stock market: the impact of implicit commitment to withdraw. China Opening Herald 1, 98–100 (in Chinese). Zhu, X., Ling, D., 2005. The system of economic transition and behaviour change transaction. Economic Issues 7, 7–8 (in Chinese). Zingales, L., and A. Dyck. 2001. “Private Benefits of Control: An International Comparison.” Working paper, University of Chicago. 28
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz