Economic History Association Abstracts of Papers Presented at the Annual Meeting Source: The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 65, No. 2 (Jun., 2005), pp. 550-571 Published by: Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3875079 . Accessed: 08/04/2014 18:14 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. . Cambridge University Press and Economic History Association are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Economic History. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions AbstractsofPapers Presented at the Annual Meeting SESSION 1A:LOCATION,LOCATION,LOCATION:THE GEOGRAPHYOF INVENTIONAND INNOVATION How Silicon Valley's Skilled Immigrants are Transforming the Geography of Innovation Silicon Valley's high technology economy was created in the 1960s and 1970s by engineers from the east and Midwest of the United States. By 2000 over 40 percentof the region's high-skilled workers were foreign-born, overwhelmingly from Asia. These U.S.-educated immigrantengineers are transformingthe geography of innovation as they build technical communities that link Silicon Valley to centers of lower cost skill in their home countries.In a process that is more akin to "braincirculation" than "brain drain," these closely knit networks of engineers and entrepreneursare transferringtechnology and know-how between distantregional economies faster and more flexibly than most large corporations.By seeding localized processes of entrepreneurialexperimentationin formerlyperipheraleconomies, while maintainingclose ties to the technology and marketsin Silicon Valley, networksof skilled immigrantsin the 1990s creatednew centers of innovationin Israel and Taiwan. A comparableprocess is now underwayin regions of China and India, with significant long-termconsequences for patternsof innovationand economic growth. ANNALEESAXENIAN,University of California, Berkeley The Geographyof Inventionin High- and Low-TechnologyIndustries. Evidencefrom the Second IndustrialRevolution Productionin "technologically-mature" manufacturingindustrieshas in recentyears relocated from increasingly more-developed to less-developed countries with lower costs of labor. It is not clear, however, if these lattercountrieswill realize corresponding increases in their generationof new technologicalknowledge. More generally, we do not fully understandthe sources of geographic clustering in invention, or how prevalent and persistent such clusters are. To investigate these issues, this paper explores the geographicpatternsof inventionin the shoe, textile and electric industriesin the United States duringthe Second IndustrialRevolution. Using both U.S. patentrecords and informationabout the inventorsdrawnfrom census manuscriptsand city directories,I find that in generalthe location of inventiondoes not appearso directly, or closely, related to the location of production. The intriguing implication is that because individuals with the appropriateknowledge and skills to be effective contributors to new technology are often young and scarce in supply, they will be inclined to migrateto those areas where demand for the technology (and rents to their scarce human capital) is high and resources to supportthe R&D are available. The historical evidence appearsto suggest that invention and productionmight not be clustered in the same location. This may be unwelcome news for developing countriesthat hope to emerge as centers of invention after having attractedshifts in manufacturingcapacity from developed countries. DEE SUTTHIPHISAL,McGill 550 This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAAbstracts 551 Do Patents Encourage Knowledge Spillovers? Evidencefrom the Geographic Location ofInnovations at the CrystalPalace The two primarygoals of patent laws are to encourageinvention and to diffuse the new knowledge from invention. This paperuses differences in patentingrates across industriesto examine whether patenting helps to diffuse technical knowledge, or, in other words, whether patents facilitate knowledge spillovers. Preliminary findings based on the location of 4,465 British exhibits at the CrystalPalace Exhibitionin London in 1851 suggest that, in the nineteenth century at least, patents facilitated the spread of new ideas. Innovations in industries with high patenting rates were geographicallydispersed,whereas innovations in industrieswith low patentingrates exhibited strongpatternsof geographicconcentration,not only within countries,but also within cities. PETRA MOSER,MassachusettsInstituteof Technologyand NBER SESSION iB: LONG-RUNECONOMICGROWTHAND INEQUALITY Long-Run International Inequality in Human Development and Real Income: Evidencefrom Europe and the New World Is inequality cumulatingover time? Has the gap between Core and Peripherywidened duringthe last two centuries?For most people, including academics, the answer is yes, even though few systematic attemptshave been made to measureit. In this paper an attemptis made to assess intercountryinequalityover the nineteenthand twentieth centurieson the basis of income and social welfare indicatorsfor a large sample of Core and Peripheralcountriesfrom Europe and the New World for which data on GDP and social indicators of welfare are available. In particular,a new, improved HumanDevelopment index is constructedon the basis of new non-income indicators of well-being defined along Kakwani(1993) axiomatic indices, and presentedtogether with new estimates of purchasingpower parity adjusted GDP per head. Alternative measuresof inequality,including entropydecomposableindices, are provided for real income and humandevelopment. LEANDROPRADOSDE LAESCOSURA,Universidad Carlos III, Madrid The Evolution of Income Concentrationin Japan, 1887-2003: Evidencefrom Income TaxStatistics This paperpresentslong-runseries of top income sharesin Japanbetween 1887 and 1950 and of top wage income sharesbetween 1951 and 2003, using income tax statistics. Preliminaryanalysis of the data indicates that the top 1 percent wage income share in Japan has been relatively stable over the postwar years, in contrastto the sharpincreasein the top sharein the United States afterthe 1970s. The paperexplores the causes of the changes in income concentrationfrom both historical and comparative perspectives. CHIAKIMORIGUCHI, Northwestern and NBER, AND EMMANUEL SAEZ, Universityof California,Berkeley This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 552 EHAAbstracts Two Centuriesof Economic Growth:Europe Chasing theAmericanFrontier Starting from the same level of productivityand per-capitaincome as the United States in the mid-nineteenthcentury, Europe fell behind steadily to a level of barely half in 1950, and then began a rapid catch-up. While Europe's level of productivity has almost converged, its income per person has leveled off at about three-quartersof America's. How could Europebe so productiveyet so poor? The simple answer is that hours per person in Europehave fallen drasticallyin the past 40 years, reflecting long vacations, high unemployment,and low labor force participation,and only about onethirdof the Europe-Americadifference reflects voluntarilychosen leisure. A historical analysis traces Europe's falling behind after 1870 to Americanpolitical unity, fostering large-scale material-intensivemanufacturingand a set of marketinginnovations, and after 1913 to the early Americanexploitationof the great inventions of electricity and the internalcombustionengine, while Europewas distractedby wars. After 1950 Europe's catch up was achieved both by exploiting the great inventions40 years late, and also by the gradualerosion of early Americanadvantages.But after 1995 the gap began to widen again, a developmentthat brings to the forefrontfundamentalAmerican advantagesin fosteringand exploiting innovation. ROBERTGORDON,Northwesternand NBER SESSION 2A: GOVERNMENTPOLICYTOWARDSINNOVATION EquilibriumImpotence: Whythe States and not the AmericanNational Government Building a nationaltransportationsystem was a central link in the developmentof the nineteenth-centuryAmerican economy. Despite calls for national improvements, the federal governmentspent nearly an orderof magnitudeless on transportationprojects between 1790 and 1860 than did state and local governments.This paper develops a generalpolitical economy model of a democraticlegislaturefaced with the problem of financing a large transportationinvestment that serves a minority of the geographic units representedin the legislature-states in the federal case. We show that three alternativefinancing schemes can commandmajoritysupportand leave no district worse off, and that the federal governmentwas only able to use two of three methodsbecause of constitutionalrestrictionson taxation.We show that 97 percent of all federal transportationexpendituresfollowed the two schemes, and that the federal governmentmost often used a method of finance suited for small local projectsrather than interregionalprojects.We complete the argument,by comparingthe state experience. States were able to tailor taxes to suit political constraints.As a consequence, states built most of the largestand most importantinter-regionaltransportationlinks in the antebellumera. JOHNWALLIS,Maryland ANDBARRYWEINGAST,Stanford Antitrustand InnovationPolicy in Early Cold WarAmerica This paper examines the influence of antitrustpolicy upon technological change in two American industries-computing and paper, duringthe decades following World War II. It combines detailed examinationof key antitrustprosecutionswith thorough This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAAbstracts 553 case studies of firm behavior based on records in corporatearchives. The paper focuses upon both the theory and the practice of antitrust.By examining developments in two widely divergentindustries,it attemptsto elucidatewhetherthe Departmentof Justice acted upon a comprehensivetheoreticalunderstandingof the relationshipbetween competition,marketstructure,and technical change. The paperthen investigates whether antitrust activities significantly altered firm behavior regarding technical change, whether any changes in firm behavior followed paths anticipatedby the Department of Justice, and whether altered firm behavior ultimately influenced the course of technical change in significantways. STEVE USSELMAN, GeorgiaInstituteof Technology SESSION 2B: SOCIALWELFAREIN VICTORIANBRITAIN Poverty among the Elderly in VictorianBritain Despite the sharp increase in wage rates for manual workers from 1850 to 1914, poverty rates among the elderly remainedhigh in Victorian Britain, although the extent of pauperismvaried significantly across Poor Law Unions. This paperbegins by examiningthe ability of workersto provide for their old age throughsaving and membership in friendly societies. We constructa data set consisting of informationfor all 586 English Poor Law Unions for 1891/2. We estimate regressionequationsto explain variationsacross unions in the extent of pauperism,and test several conjecturesmade by contemporariesand repeatedby historians.For example, what effect did the substitution of workhouses for outdoor relief have on the number of elderly paupers?We then examine the implicationsof our results for the debate over national old-age pensions which occurredfrom the 1890s until the adoptionof the Old Age Pension Act in 1908. GEORGEBOYER,Cornell ANDTIMOTHYSCHMIDLE,Cornell TheEconomicReturnto PrimarySchooling in VictorianEngland In this paper,I use longitudinaldata on individualmales linked between the English censuses of 1851 and 1881 to examine the effect of childhood primaryschool attendance on adult socioeconomic status in VictorianEngland.Primaryschooling was not compulsory,nor was it state provided. Primaryeducationwas a choice made by parents for their children.The panel natureof the data allows both the schooling decision and the effect of that decision on the individual's adult labor market outcome to be analyzed. A structuralmodel of rational school choice indicates that parentswere responsive to the anticipatedfuture economic effect of the schooling on their children. For individualsfrom all socioeconomic backgroundswho received primaryschooling, the benefits were substantial. JASON LONG,Colby This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 554 EHAAbstracts SESSION 3A:COLLECTIVEINSTITUTIONSAND COLLECTIVEINVENTION Craft Guilds and Property Rights to Technical Knowledge in Premodern Europe, c.1300-c. 1800 The role of technology in the transitionfrom premodern,"Malthusian,"to modem economies in late eighteenth-and nineteenth-centuryEuropeis among the majorquestions in economic history, but it is still poorly understood.In particular,the view that premodernsocieties experienced low laborproductivityand stagnantliving standards, which suggests that technological change before c. 1800 was close to zero due to pervasive guild rent seeking and poorly specified propertyrights to knowledge is hardto squarewith the fact that the surge of technological innovation in the eighteenth century occurredwithin institutionalframeworksnot too dissimilarto those of 1300. It is well known that the technical knowledge of premoderncraftsmenand engineers was largely experience-based,or experiential. However, the implications of the fact that there were basic cognitive limitationsto how technicalknowledge could be expressed, processed and transmittedhave yet to be examined in detail. The paper elaborateson this point, spells out the main implicationsfor propertyrights to knowledge, and suggests that the principal, endogenous bottleneck to premoderntechnical diffusion and innovationwas the cost of person-to-personteaching and demonstration. S. R. EPSTEIN, LondonSchool of Economics Medieval GuildsRedux: ContemporaryInstitutionsfor CollectiveInvention This essay draws on recent scholarshipconcerning the natureand function of medieval guilds. I arguethat certainfeaturesof these guilds appearin modem institutions that furthercollective invention:patentpools, industry-widestandard-settingorganizations, informalknowledge exchange among academic scientists, and (in a more limited way) open source softwaredevelopment. In particular,guilds and modem institutions share three features: an "appropriabilitystructure"that makes it profitable for individualentities to both develop new technologies and sharethem;reliance on group norms, as opposed to formal legal enactments,as an enforcementmechanism; and a balance of competition and cooperation under which group-generic information is informationis not. Collective invention institutions shared,but individual-proprietary demonstratethat formal propertyrights are not the only way to foster innovationand that mediating institutions may mitigate property-rightsbottlenecks, lessening what has been termedthe "tragedyof the anticommons." ROBERT MERGES, Universityof California,Berkeley Patronage, Reputation,and CommonAgency Contractingin the ScientificRevolution: TheHistorical Originsof "OpenScience" Institutions The emergence duringthe late sixteenth and early seventeenthcenturiesof the idea and practice of "open science" was a distinctive and vital organizationalaspect of the Scientific Revolution. In contrastto the previously dominantethos of secrecy in the pursuit of Nature's Secrets, a new set of norms, incentives, and organizationalstructures reinforced scientific researchers' commitments to rapid disclosure of new knowledge. The appearanceof "cooperativerivalries" in revealing new knowledge were a functional response to heightened asymmetricinformationproblems encoun- This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAAbstracts 555 teredby the Renaissancesystem of court-patronageof the artsand sciences, createdby the increasing practical reliance upon new mathematicaltechniques in a variety of "contextsof application."Fragmentedpolitical authoritygave rise to relationsbetween noble patrons and savant-clientsthat resembled the situation economists describe as "common agency contractingin substitutes,"therebypromotingmore favorable contractterms for the agent client membersof Europe'snascent scientific communities. PAULDAVID,Stanford SESSION 3B: GOVERNMENTSPOLICYTOWARDSINNOVATION CapitalDeepening in AmericanManufacturing,1850-1880 We use establishment-leveldata to study capital deepening-increases in the capital-outputratio-in Americanmanufacturingfrom 1850 to 1880. In nominalterms,the aggregate capital-outputratio in our samples rose by 30 percent from 1850 to 1880. Growthin real terms was considerablygreater-70 percent-because prices of capital goods declined relative to outputprices. Cross-sectionalregressions suggest that capital deepening was especially importantin the larger firms and was positively associated with the diffusion of steam-poweredmachinery.However, even after accounting for shifts over time in such factors, much of the capital deepening remains to be explained. Although capital deepening implies a fall in the average productof capital it does not necessarily imply that rates of return were declining. However, we find strong evidence that returnsdid decline. We also show that returnswere decreasingin firm size, althoughthe data are not sufficiently informativeto tell us why it was so. JEREMY ATACK,Vanderbiltand NBER, FREDBATEMAN,Georgia, ANDROBERTMARGO,Vanderbilt and NBER Industrializationand Urbanization:The U.S. Experience, 1820-1920 The U.S. went from an agriculturalto an industrialnation between the early nineteenth and the turn of the twentieth centuries. In the seventeenth century, manufactured goods were producedby artisansand households, or were importedfrom England. However, beginning in the early nineteenth century, manufacturedgoods were increasingly produced in factories, especially in New England. As the century progressed, manufacturinggrew and spread to the Middle Atlantic and became concentratedin the northernregion of the United States, forming a manufacturingbelt. This paper explores the linkages between industrializationand urbanization.Whereas early industrializationwas associated with growth of manufacturingin ruralareas, late industrializationwas significantly correlatedwith the growth of manufacturingin urban areas. This paper constructsdata on U.S. cities and counties for the period between 1820 and 1920 and examines the varioustheories of industrializationand urbanization. KIM, WashingtonUniversitySt. Louis and NBER SUKKOO This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 556 EHAAbstracts TheIndustrialRevolutionin the Prewar Lower YangziRegion of China This article utilizes a GDP frameworkto make an assessment of economic growth and change in China's most advancedregion, the Lower Yangzi, from the early modem period to the present It offers a quantitativeassessment of the Shanghai-basedindustrializationin the first three decades of the twentieth century through a detailed compilation of a 1933 Lower Yangzi GDP. It shows that the Lower Yangzi in the 1930s had a per capita GDP 64 percent higher than China's national average, and experienceda magnitudeof growthand structuralchange between 1914-1918 and 19311936 comparableto that of Japanand her East Asian colonies duringthis period. This paper furtherprovides a historical narrativearguingthat the city-state model adopted in early-twentieth-centuryShanghai,with its secure propertyrights and provision of public goods, laid the institutionalfoundationof an IndustrialRevolution in the Lower Yangzi with long-lastingpolitical and economic impactacross East Asia. DEBINMA,National GraduateInstitutefor Policy Studies,Japan SESSION 4A: CHALKAND TALK: SCIENCE,ACADEMIA,AND INNOVATION Whydid U.S. Universitiesbegin Patenting and Licensing during the 1970s? A numberof scholars have documentedthe role of the 1980 Bayh-Dole Act in the growth of patentingand licensing by universitiessince 1980 (Hendersonet al., 1998). But Bayh-Dole is properlyviewed as initiatingthe latest, ratherthan the first, phase in the history of U.S. universitypatenting.Relatively few universitiesmanagedtheirpatent portfolios themselves during the 1925-1970 period, but this situation began to change duringthe 1970s. This paperreviews the causes of increasedentryby universities into direct managementof patenting and licensing, as well as the factors underpinning the growth in private universities' role as patentersand licensors, duringthe 1970s. We draw on a databaseon university patents covering the 1948-80 period, as well as data on "InstitutionalPatent Agreements"between universities and federal agencies responsible for the bulk of academic researchfunding, in an analysis of the determinantsof entryand the "governance"of licensing underthe termsof IPAs. DAVIDMOWREY, Universityof California,Berkeley ANDBHAVEN SAMPAT, GeorgiaInstituteof Technology Academic Science and the GrowthofIndustrial Research This paper argues that the unique form taken by American universities in the late nineteenthand early twentieth centurieshelped promotethe adoptionof industrialresearch laboratoriesin nearby firms. Proximity to academic science reduced the costs faced by firms establishing research labs-by easing communicationwith academic consultantsand facilitatingthe hiring of university-trainedscientists-and as a result the early industrialresearch laboratoriesbenefited by locating close to universities. This paper explores the link between the blossoming of American higher education and the growth of industrialresearch,taking a two-prongedapproachto the research question.First, it tests whetherthe early industrialresearchlabs were more likely to be located near universities. It finds that the number of industrial research labs in a county in a given year is significantlyrelatedto the numberof universitiesand the ex- This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAAbstracts 557 tent of university spending on research.However, for a firm-level subsampleconsisting of firms in the chemical industry,proximityto academic science is found to matter only for young firms. Industrialresearchlaboratoriesestablishedbefore the expansion of higher education in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries are not more likely to be found nearuniversities.Secondly, the papertests for evidence of spillovers arisingfrom universityresearch. MEGAN MACGARVIE, BU TheEvolutionof Biological Resource Centers Biological resourcecenters (BRCs) are "living libraries"that authenticate,preserve, and offer independent access to biological materials, such as cells, cultures, and specimens. This paper explores the role that such institutionsplayed within the life sciences over the last century.The history of biomaterialsexchange highlightsthe key challenges in ensuringthe integrity of the researchprocess and the role of collective institutionsin addressingthose challenges. Understandinghow institutionsimpact the degree of confidence in research materials and the implications for overall research productivityrequires a paradigmfor assessing the role of institutions in cumulative progress.From the perspective of the economics of science and technological change, BRCs offer an importantcase study of the importanceand requirementsfor step-bystep scientific and technologicalprogress,and the impact of institutionson the process of cumulativeknowledge production. SCOTTSTERN,Northwesternand NBER SESSION 4B: THE THREEDONS: THE VIEW FROM THE SPIRESOF OXFORD Labor Productivityin ArableAgriculturearound the World,1700-1870 We introducea large, new data set on agriculturaloutput and employment in the wheat-producingareas of the world between 1700 and 1870. Using these data,we present new estimatesof laborproductivityin arableagriculturearoundthe world. Output per worker varied wildly across countries, with Western Europe and North America generally having substantiallyhigher outputper workerthan India and China. Most of the variationin outputper workerwithin WesternEuropeand North Americawas due to variations in output per acre (i.e., acres per worker were similar across western countries). But the labor productivitydifferentialbetween North America and Europe on the one hand, and India and China on the other,was a result of a massive differential in acresper worker. LIAMBRUNT,Oxford The Nitrogen Hypothesis and the English Agricultural Revolution: A Biological Approach This paper uses a science-based model of nitrogen in agricultureto gauge the contributionsof animal manure,peas, beans, clover, and convertible husbandryto crop yields from 1300 to 1800. Medieval yields were not depressedby a deficiency of animals in so far as they recycled nitrogen on the arable. The cultivationof peas, beans, This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 558 EHAAbstracts and clover introducedenough nitrogen into farmingto account for half of the rise in crop yields, while convertible husbandrycould explain even more. Convertiblehusbandry was importantin raising yields in the sixteenth century, but its advantage waned as the cultivationof legumes spreadin the seventeenth. Changes in population explain why these improvementswere not adoptedin the middle ages but laterbecame profitable. ROBERT ALLEN,Nuffield College TheNorthAtlanticMeat Tradeand its InstitutionalConsequences Expansion of the internationalgrain markethas been extensively studied, but the trade in meat and meat animals is relatively poorly explored. This is all the more surprising because by the eve of the First World War, it was of nearly comparablevalue to the graintrade.The meat tradebore considerableresemblanceto the grain trade,but differences are at least as striking. Lower transportationcosts and increased demand drove the developmentsas they did in grain. However, the impact of new technology cannot be simply summarizedin terms of much lower freight rates. Long distance trade in meat inexorablyaltered conditions of meat supply and was tied to the evolution of new wholesale and retaildistributionof fresh meat. Majorchanges in industrial organizationemerged.With the new distributioncame largerfirms and greatervertical integrationin both meat distributionand in transportation.In meatpackingand distribution, Americanfirms emergeddominantin both exportingand importingregions. In ocean shipping,liner companiestransportedthe cattle and meat. KNICK HARLEY, Oxford SESSION 5A:FIRMSAND INVENTORSIN THE NINETEENTHAND TWENTIETHCENTURIES TheDecline of the IndependentInventor:A SchumpeterianStory? Joseph Schumpeterarguedin Capitalism,Socialism and Democracy that the rise of large firms' investments in in-house R&D spelled the doom of the entrepreneur.We explore this idea by analyzing the career patternsof three cohorts of inventors from the late nineteenthand early twentieth century.We find that over time highly productive inventors were increasingly likely to form long-term attachmentswith firms. In the Northeast,these attachmentsseem to have takenthe form of employmentpositions within large firms,but in the Midwest inventorswere more likely to become principals in firms bearing their names. Entrepreneurship,therefore,was by no means dead, but the increasing capital requirements-both financial and human-for effective invention and the need for inventorsto establish a reputationbefore they could attractsupport made it more difficult for creativepeople to pursuecareersas inventors.The relative numbers of highly productive inventors in the population correspondingly decreased,as did patentingratesper capita. NAOMI LAMOREAUX, University of California, Los Angeles and NBER AND KENNETH SOKOLOFF, University of California, Los Angeles and NBER This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAAbstracts 559 Patents and Technological Competencies: A Cross National Study of Intellectual PropertyRight Strategies in the SyntheticDye Industry,185 7-1914 The dramaticincrease of firm patentingin the United States duringthe last two decades may give the impressionthat the acquisitionof patents is becoming increasingly importantfor protectingand leveraging technological competencies. A historical perspective on how firms acquire technological competencies and leverage them in different marketsreveals, however, that it is far from obvious that the possession of patents will lead to long-tern competitive success. Germanand Swiss firms in the early years of the synthetic dye industrycreated superiortechnological competencies than their British and French counterpartsprecisely because they were initially unable to obtainpatentmonopolies in theirhome markets.Analyzing the history of the synthetic dye industryfrom 1857-1914 in a variety if countries,the purpose of this paper is to contributeto a more nuancedunderstandingof the role of patents in the development of firm capabilities. JOHANNPETERMURMANN,Northwestern Technology, Investment, Finance and Performance in the Second Industrial Revolution In recent researchon the relationshipbetween finance and growth, there has been growing attentionto heterogeneityacross industriesin their dependenceon the financial system and the benefits that they derive from it. Various hypotheses have been advanced about the financial demands of different industriesand their determinants. However, a dearthof evidence on the patternsof finance across industriesand theirrelationship to technology, investment, and performancehas hamperedprogress on the topic. My paper will analyze the role of finance in three prominentindustriesin the United States-electrical equipment,chemicals, and automobiles-for the period from 1890 to 1929. All three of these industriesplayed a prominentrole in the Second Industrial Revolution. During the period covered by my study, they experienced high levels of technological change and innovation, an increase in their capital requirements and a rapidgrowth in their output.Company-leveldatawill be used as the basis for a quantitativeanalysis of investment,finance, and performancein these industries. It will be complementedwith qualitative discussions of technological change, competitive structureand organizationalcharacteristicsin these industries. MARYO'SULLIVAN,INSEAD SESSION 5B:FINANCIALMARKETSAND INSTITUTIONS Related Lendingand EconomicPerformance:Evidencefrom Mexico There is a broadconsensus thatbankersin LDCs engage in related(insider)lending. There is not, however, a consensus as to whether related lending has a positive or negative effect on economic growth. We argue that related lending has negative consequences for growth comparedto the outcome that would obtain in an efficient capital marketbecause bankers choose borrowersbased on personal contacts ratherthan the quality of the underlyingprojects. The result is the misallocation of capital. We also argue that related lending arises as a rationalresponse to high levels of default This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 560 EHAAbstracts risk. Thus, it is an endogenous outcome of weak propertyrights or informationasymmetries that are costly to overcome. In sum, relatedlending is a second-best outcome, but it is superiorto the readily available alternative:banking systems that effectively do not lend at all for productivepurposes. ITAM NOELMAURER, ANDSTEPHEN HABER,Stanford TheDevelopmentof the Paris Bourse in the InterwarPeriod In this paper,we present a new databaseon the FrenchBourse duringthe interwar period, which should enable a much more thoroughresearchon the functioning and development process of that market. This database includes for every listed security monthly prices, earnings,splits, and other capital operations,issues, and, most importantly, a measureof liquidity.Using this database,we first present a few stylized facts on the developmentof the Parisiancapital marketduringthe interwarperiod. We discuss the limitationsof earlier indices and build a new stock index which, being better constructedand restrictedto blue chip firms, is more easily comparableto foreign indices of the same period. This new index modifies the standardview of the Paris market in the interwarperiod, showing for example that the price growth was higher than previously thoughtduringthe 1920s and thatthe decline in the stock prices startedearlier than in New York. PIERRE-CYRILLE ENS, Paris HAUTCOEUR, ANDMURIEL Lille, ESA PETIT-KONCZYK, ContractualResponses to InstitutionalChanges. A Historical InstitutionalAnalysis This paperuses historicalrecordsand economic theory to investigate the combined institutionaland contractualarrangementsthat facilitated long-distance trade in late medieval Venice. Institutionalchanges that enhanced the State's ability to verify informationled the transitionfrom the sea loan (a debt-like contract)to the commenda (an equity-like contract)and enabled a betterallocation of risk. These institutionaldevelopments also lessened the merchants'opportunitiesto influence the ventures' outcome throughtheir choice of action/effort,thereby mitigatingmoral hazardproblems with respect to projectchoice and effort. The Venetians, insteadof designing contracts to economize on agency costs, developed betterinstitutionalarrangements. DELARA,Alicante GONZALEZ YADIRA PLENARY SESSION 6: ENDOGENOUSGROWTH,SCIENCE,AND ECONOMIC HISTORY GrowthTheory,EconomicHistory, and the Arc of Science We achieve our most complete understandingof any phenomenon when our conversations follow an arced trajectorythat starts from a specific context, moves up to higher levels of abstraction,and then returnsback to a (possibly different) specific context. Economic theorists in general, and growth theorists in particular,focus much of their energy on the ascending portion of the arc. They are skilled at strippingthe This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAAbstracts 561 context from a conversationand translatingit into the abstractlanguage of mathematics. But the real test of their efforts comes in the returnback down to the kind of context that economic historiansexamine, contexts in which countries,firms, sometimes even people, have names. Examples drawnfrom economics and other disciplines suggest that a good indicatorof a successful returnis a change in how we use naturallanguage. In the end, new words and phrases or sharpenedunderstandingsof existing ones may be some of our most importantresearchoutputs. PAULROMER,Stanford Endogenous Changes in 20th CenturyAmerica NATHANROSENBERG, Stanford SESSION 7A:INSTITUTIONSAND NATURAL RESOURCESIN THE AMERICANWEST TransactionCosts and Resistance to WaterRights Transfers:TheLegacy and Lessons of the Owens ValleyTransferto Los Angeles The completion of the Los Angeles Aqueduct from Owens Valley in 1917 brought an importantnew source of water to the city. Indeed, with Owens Valley water, Los Angeles grew from 250,000 people in 1905 to over 2,000,000 in 1930. Today, Owens Valley water accounts for approximately60 percent of Los Angeles's water. The water transferwas the first, one of the largest, and the most controversialrural-to-urban water transferin the United States. Because it is presented as all that can go wrong with water transfers,it figures prominentlyand negatively in all efforts to promote a re-allocationof water in the semi-arid West today. This paper examines the transfer process and negotiationsbetween the city and land owners in the Owens Valley. Between 1905 and 1935 Los Angeles purchasedvirtuallyall of the privatepropertyin the valley. It would seem that because Los Angeles purchasedthe land and internalized the externalitiesinvolved, the episode should have been a success story instead of one that complicates currenttransferefforts. Instead, the negotiations were acrimonious, and periodicallyviolence eruptedleading to dynamitingof partof the Los Angeles aqueduct, one of the country's largest public works projects up to that time. This paper examines the sources of the disputes over price and why they were so difficult to resolve. It also presentsthe likely economic history of agriculturein the valley had irrigation continued to evaluate the often-claimed assertion that the water transfer destroyeda vibrantagriculturaleconomy, leaving instead,a desert. GARYLIBECAP, Arizona and NBER The Evolution of Irrigation Institutionsin California: The Rise of the Irrigation District, 1910-1930 This paper addresses the phenomenonof the dramaticdecline of private irrigation institutionsand the correspondingrise of public irrigationinstitutionsin early twentieth-centuryCalifornia.The existing literaturepresentsexplanationsof this transformation that view public irrigationorganizationseither as solutions to marketfailure or primarilyas a mechanism for the redistributionof income. An alternativeexplanation This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 562 EHAAbstracts is set forth in this paper. This explanationmaintainsthat the rise of the public irrigation districtwas the result of a complex interactionof agricultural,regulatory,and legal changes during the early years of the twentieth century. As large farm holdings were increasinglysubdividedand sold duringthe nineteenthand early twentiethcenturies, and the with impositionof water rateregulationin 1912 and the growing political influence of water users, it became increasinglydifficult for private irrigationcompanies (which were commonlyjoint land-waterdevelopmententerprisesthat relied upon land sales, not water sales, to turn a profit) to capturea sufficient share of the benefits of new, large-scaleirrigationprojectsto make them privatelyprofitable.The rising social rates of returnon irrigationinvestmentafter 1910, coupled with the failure of private water companies to realize these gains, led to a demandfor organizationswhich could appropriatethese benefits. This in turn led to key legislation in 1911 and 1913 which greatly enhancedthe organizationaladvantagesof the public irrigationdistrict. Primarydata collected from irrigationdistrictsand contemporarynewspapers,as well as data from publishedstate and federal sources, provide supportfor this hypothesis. EDWARD McDEVITT,CaliforniaState, Northridge Why WouldOrder WithoutLaw Result in First Possession? WaterRights During the CaliforniaGold Rush Economists and legal scholars have long been intriguedby the question of why orderly resourceallocationoften occurs in the absence of formallaws that define and enforce propertyrights, a phenomenondubbedOrderWithoutLaw by RobertEllickson. Ellicksom debunksthe persistentmisconceptionthat formal law is all that mattersbut contains few specific predictionsregardingthe propertyrights arrangementslikely to emerge from a situation lacking formal laws. This paper examines the emergence of the legal principle of first possession fromjust such a situation:the mining camps of the early California Gold Rush. Despite the absence of formal controlling law, the mining camps set in place orderlyproceduresfor acquiring,maintaining,and alienating water rights, but varied dramaticallyin their reliance on first possession. This fact permits us to gain insights into the factors that influence the adoption of first possession by private agents under democraticconditions essentially unconstrainedby controlling legal precepts. MARKKANAZAWA, CarletonCollege SESSION 7B: THE STARBUCKSESSION:SAILING,WHALINGAND STEAMSHIPS Wasthe Shiftfrom Sail to Steam in Ocean Shipping,1860 to 1912, Skill-Biased? This paper examines the extent of skill bias associated with the shift from sail to steam technology in ocean shipping between 1860 and 1912. It employs a data set of merchantseamen crew agreementsto compare occupationaldistributionsand wages between skilled and unskilled workers on sail versus steam crews over this period. It also estimates the wage premium to literacy and the age-wage profile for merchant seamen underboth technologies. Many contemporaryaccountssuggested that the shift from sail to steam technology was deskilling and resultedin a general deteriorationof seamanship.In contrast,the results here suggest by some measuresthat the shift from sail to steam was skill-biased although this result depends on how skill bias is meas- This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAAbstracts 563 ured. The study thus documents a significant late-nineteenth-centuryepisode of the changingrelationshipbetween technology and skills. DAVID MITCH,Maryland Incentives and Productivity in Corporations:Evidence from the American Whaling Industry The use of incorporation contributed to the development of many nineteenthcentury industries,but whaling was not one of them. Of the whaling venturesthat received corporatechartersin the 1830s, none survived for more than nine years, at a time when unincorporatedwhaling venturesenjoyed growing success. This paper analyzes the historical origins of the contractsand organizationalforms employed in the American whaling industry, and examines their development in response to moral hazardproblems.Most whaling ventureswere owned by a small numberof investors, and were configuredto providepowerful incentives. The corporateform of ownership, as implementedin the 1830s, was incapable of providing the incentives requisite for success in whaling. The analysis of a newly collected panel of more than 800 whaling voyages from 17 differentports supportsthe main conclusions of the paper. ERICHILT, Wellesley SteamshipCompetitionand NineteenthCenturyImmigration The behavior of the major transatlanticpassenger steamship companies is investigated during the third quarterof the nineteenth century. This time period saw the steamshipreplacethe sailing ship, a large decline and then large increase in immigrant volume, rapid changes in the technology of the steamship, and, in contrast to later years, competition among the various companies. Data on each passenger steamship arrivingat New York City are gatheredfrom the U.S. PassengerLists for every third year beginning in 1852 and continuingthrough1876 (thus, for nine differentyears). In sum, the data set contains informationon 2,864 voyages undertakenby 306 ships operated by 36 different companies. The paper presents empirical informationon the market shares of the major companies, investigates the reasons for the changing shares,and examines the competitivebehaviorof the steamshipcompaniesand market in a variety of ways. RAYMOND COHN,Illinois State SESSION 8A:THE SPREAD OF INNOVATIONS:DIFFUSIONAND RESISTANCE TheDiffusion of the SteamEngine in Eighteenth-CenturyBritain In this paper we concentrateon the diffusion of steam technology across British counties during the eighteenth century. Following a ratherestablished approachfor analyzing the diffusion of new technologies, we fit logistic growth functions to the data on the numbersof steam engines erected in each county. Afterwards,in orderto assess the factors influencing the diffiusionof steam power technology, we estimate "adoptionequations"relatingthe numberof steam engines erected in each county with a numberof localizationfactors such as coal prices, availabilityof water sites, number This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 564 EHAAbstracts of textile mills and number of blast furnaces. In this way, we are able to provide a thoroughreconstructionof regional variationsin the timing, pace and extent of usage of steam engines. Our analysis sheds some new light on the differentadoptionpatterns characterizingthe diffusion of Newcomen and Watt engines. Eindhoven Universityof Technology, ALESSANDRO NUVOLARI, B. VERSPAGEN, EindhovenUniversityof Technology, Sussex ANDN. VONTUNZELMANN, Farmer Resistance to the Tuberculin-TestingProgram to Eradicate Bovine Tuberculosis in the UnitedStates, 1893-1941 A recurrenttheme in the economic and technological history literaturesis the importance of active opposition to technical change. This paper examines the concrete example of widespread farmerresistance during the early twentieth century to government-ledcampaignsto use new tuberculin-testingtechnologies to eradicatebovine tuberculosisin the United States. Drawing on newspapersources and the archivalrecords of the Bureauof Animal Industry,we explore four issues: the political economy of opposition;the role of earlierscientific controversiesin the discourseof the opposition movement; the techniques including radio and litigation used by the opponents; and finally internationalcomparisons. ALAN OLMSTEAD,Universityof California,Davis ANDPAULRHODE, Universityof North Carolinaand NBER Diffusion of the Cotton-PickingMachine, 1949-1964 Within a 20-year period after 1949, mechanical cotton harvesting in the United States replacedwhat for centurieshad been a hand operation.This innovation,perhaps even more than others in American agriculturehad enormousimplicationsfor the society into which it was introduced,includingthe disappearanceof the South as a separate region in the United States, the Civil Rights movement, the rural-urbanmigration of African-Americans,racial economic equality, and the demise of America's cities. Despite recent progress in understandingthe labor marketdynamics involved, the diffusion of the mechanical cotton picker itself remains incompletely understood,especially its striking west-to-east pattern.Here with newly constructedhand-to-machine harvest cost data, we estimate the diffusion of the mechanicalcotton harvesterwith a two equationmodel. We find diffusion resulted from the rapid decline in the costs of mechanical cotton harvesting due to local (cotton yields) and exogenous improvements in technology (productivitygains in manufacturingand distributionexogenous to the mechanizationof the cotton harvestitself). WAYNEGROVE, LeMoyneCollege Baldwin-WallaceCollege ANDCRAIG HEINICKE, SESSION 8B:PRODUCTIVITYIN EUROPEAND THE UNITED STATES InterwarMultifactorProductivityGrowthin the UnitedStates Multifactor productivity growth in the private nonfarm economy in the United States was 2.12 percent per year (continuouslycompounded)between 1919 and 1929 This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAAbstracts 565 and 2.31 percent per year between 1929 and 1941. In both periods MFP growth in manufacturingwas exceptional: 5.12 percent (1919-1929) falling to 2.91 percent between 1929 and 1941. If MFP growth in manufacturingwas lower, how did the 19291941 years end up yielding a higher rate of MFP growth than did the 1920s? The answer appearsto lie in a very high rate of MFP growth in transportand public utilities (4.67 percentper year), combinedwith moderategrowth in wholesale and retail distribution, which preliminaryestimates place at about 1.81 percentper year. In comparison, I estimate MFP growth in transportand public utilities at only 1.86 percent per year between 1919-1929, and wholesale and retail distribution,at only about 0.8 percent per year. ALEXFIELD,Santa Clara TFP, Social Savings and the ConsumerSurplusof the Film Industry,1900-1938 This paper estimates and comparesthe benefits cinema technology generatedto society in Britain, France, and the United States between 1900 and 1938. It is shown how cinema industrialized live entertainment,by standardization,automation, and making it tradable.The economic impact is measuredin three ways: TFP-growth,social savings in 1938 and the consumer surplus enjoyed in 1938. Preliminaryfindings suggest that the entertainmentindustry accounted for 1.5 to 1.7 percent of national TFP-growthand for 0.9 to 1.6 percent of real GDP-growthin the three countries. Social savings were highest in the United States (c. 2.5 billion dollars and three million workers) and relatively modest in Britain and France,possibly because of the relative abundanceof skilled live-entertainmentworkers. Convergingexchange rates and PPP price ratios suggest rapid internationalmarket integration.The paper's methodology and findings may give insight in technological change in other service industriesthat were also industrialized. GERBENBAKKER,Essex BenchmarkEstimatesof UK/USSectoral Productivity,1870-1950 Two competing views of relative UK/US labor productivity since 1870 have recently emerged in the literature.Ward and Devereux (2003) provide expenditurebased benchmarkcomparisonsof UK/US productivity.Broadberry(1997, 1998) provides productivitycomparisonsbased on UK/US sectoral output. Whereas the Ward and Devereux comparisons are based on a direct comparisonof prices and expenditures in each benchmarkyear, Broadberry's(1997, 1998) comparisonsare to a large extent derived from time series extrapolations. The direct comparisons show the United States leading the United Kingdom as early as 1870 but the sectoral comparisons suggest that the United States does not pass the United Kingdomuntil the turnof the twentiethcentury.In this paper,we reconcile the evidence on UK/US sectoralproductivitywith the direct, expenditurebased estimatesof overall productivity. MARIANNE WARD, Loyola College, MD ANDJOHNDEVEREUX,CUNY This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Abstractsof Posters Presented at the Annual Meeting Risk Sharing, Adverse Selection, and Institutional Change: The Case of the Israeli Kibbutz The Israeli Kibbutz, a voluntary egalitariancommune, presents a puzzle for economic theory as moralhazardand adverseselection might take place. Yet, the Kibbutz has existed for almost a century,implying that these problemswere mitigated.I delve into the factorsat the center of the Kibbutzlong success and recent change by providing a theoretical frameworkand by assembling and analyzing large micro-level data sets, both at the individual level and the Kibbutz level. The analysis suggests that although productivemembersare the first to leave, the Kibbutz is a self-enforcing institutionprovidingvaluablerisk sharingand public goods. Northwestern University RAN ABRAMITZKY, The Impact of Subsidized Family Planning on the Fertility of African-American Women,1960-1990 Demographic surveys in the 1960s revealed far higher rates of "unplanned"births among African-Americanwomen thanwhite women. Following the enactmentof Title X of the Public Health Service Act in 1970, the first comprehensivefederal initiative to subsidize family planning,fertility rates among black women fell rapidly.Using archival and published data, this poster analyzes the impact of subsidized family planning services on racial differences in fertility. It is demonstratedthat within states and cohorts declines in births among African-Americanwomen relative to white women from 1970 to 1990 are stronglyrelatedto higher levels of service in 1970. Futurework will examine the effects of family planningusing richercounty-level data. MARTHA BAILEY,VanderbiltUniversity WhiteFlight, or the Rush to the Suburbs" Disentangling the Relationship Between Black In-Migrationand WhiteSuburbanization American cities underwenta rapid and racially distinctive process of suburbanization following World War II. However, this enduringpatternof "chocolate cities and vanilla suburbs"need not imply the existence of a direct racial dynamic in residential decision ("white flight"). Variation in racial composition across cities is largely the byproductof a series of location choices made by ruralblack migrants.Migrantsmay have been attractedby exactly those aspects of a city that underlie the demand for suburbanliving (e.g., wage growth, industrialmix), or by falling demand, and thus lower prices, for central city housing accompanyingthe "rushto the suburbs."This paper will re-examine the relationship between race and suburbanizationwith an original instrumentfor black migrant flows into northernand western cities. The instrumentpredictsin-migrationto a particularnortherncity based on southernpush factors, weighted by the state-of-birthprofile of the city's existing black migrantstock. LEAHPLATTBOUSTAN,Harvard University This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAPosters 567 Industryand Ingenuityin Dixie: FactorsAffectingthe PostbellumSouthernEconomy? Persistentwidespreadpoverty in the postbellum South remains a mystery. Scholars have offered a varietyof hypothesesto explainthis phenomenon:emancipation,the legacy of slavery, institutionsand land tenure,labormarketintegrationor lack thereof,racism, insufficientspendingon education,capitalmarketimperfections,culturalinstitutions, the impactof the WarBetween the States,Reconstruction,cotton overproduction, agrarianmentalities,and a lack of "inventive"activity.This posterwill presentresultsof preliminaryinvestigationin which I evaluatethese hypothesesand ascertainthe contribution each factormade to poor southerneconomic performance.In addition,I explicitly test the hypothesisthat southernershad "backward,anti-capitalist"mentalitiesusing stochasticfrontiertechniquessummarizedin Coelli, Rao, and Battese (1998, An Introductionto Efficiencyand ProductivityAnalysis),the theoreticalframeworkdiscussedin Mokyr(1990, TheLevel of Riches ), and the dataset summarizedin Atack and Bateman (1999, Historical Methods).Preliminaryresults indicatethat southernfirms were as efficient as theirnortherncounterpartsrecordedin the 1880 Censusof Manufactures. ART CARDEN,WashingtonUniversityin Saint Louis History of China's OverseasInvestments:Emphasis on the OpportunitiesProvided by its Entryto the WTO China's accession to the WTO marks its entry to the world. This has definitely boosted its economic growth.It has even led to more contactbetween Chinaand WTO members and other countries. It was the new economic situation that actuatedChina overseas capital expanded from trade, shipping, and the restaurantbusiness to manufacturingand processing, resource exploitation,project contracting,agriculturalcooperation,and researchand development.Chinais in transitionfrom lower-level (mainly international)trade toward higher-level (direct investment in productionand production requisites)trade.It practicesthe strategyof "foreigncapital inflow" and "domestic capital outflow"throughdeveloping foreign tradeand attractingforeign capitaland operating external direct investments and having active involvement in the global economy. It is now workinghardto steady its economic growth and improveits industry structureto merge into the global economic course. Related to this strategicdevelopment,a history of China's overseas investmentsis discussed. PEILIN DENG,SouthwestJiao Tong University A Co-evolutionaryApproach to Institutionaland Technological Change in Industrial Regimes:Labor and Managementin the UnitedStates and Germany,1900-1933 A growing literaturestresses the divergences between national "Varietiesof Capitalism." This poster argues that these developed because technologies, organizational arrangements,institutions,and routines of behaviorin an industryor region co-evolve with each other.New technologies or routinesmay act as factors changing the conditions for the replications of others. Well adjusted systems-"regimes"-emerge, as firms choose those routines and technologies that work best in their given environment. Regimes may exist concurrentlyand compete. Over time the most effective become prevalentin an industryor region and ultimately shape social ideologies and institutionson a nationalscale. Simon HELLMICH,UniversitatBielefeld This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 568 EHAPosters The UnexpectedTransformationof Women's Higher Education, 1965 to 1980 The dissertationaims to explain the rapid and unexpectednarrowingof the gender gap in higher educationthat took place between 1965 and 1980. It offers an explanation, based on a theory of social change developed by Timor Kuran,of why we might expect to see sudden shifts in women's economic roles ratherthan gradualadaptation to economic changes. Social norms, it is argued,played a key role in shapingwomen's choices regardingeducation and work. The dissertationalso investigates empirically the labormarketconsequencesof changes in women's highereducation. STACEYJONES,Stanford University AnalyzingVariationsin TotalFactor Productivityby Meansof CointegrationAnalysis The aim of this paper is to analyze the determinantsfor variations in total factor productivity (TFP) in three different types of industries: labor-intensive, capitalintensive, and knowledge-intensive industries in Sweden from 1950-1994. Testing eight differenthypotheses by means of the cointegratedVAR model is used to carry this out. Each hypothesis reflects a certaingrowth process with mechanismsviolating perfect competition and/or constant returnsto scale under which TFP is computed. The results pint out that 86 to 90 percent of TFP variationscan be explained by such growth processes, moreover the determinantsfor TFP differ between industrieswith different methods of production:e.g., learning-by-doingand negative sector shocks are the most importantdeterminantsfor TFP variations in labor-intensiveindustry, whereas in capital-intensiveindustryTFP is determinedby economies and diseconomies of scale. In knowledge-intensive sectors complementaritybetween subjective knowledge and capital and reversedcomplementaritiesdue to path dependencygreatly affect variationsin TFP. CAMILLAJOSEPHSON, Lund University Measurementand Analysis of ProductDiversification Technology sets the boundaryof what to produce and how to produce for firms. It determines firms' flexibility to adjust themselves over time. Unlike how to produce (productionprocess with many inputs and adjustmentmargins, such as labor, capital, material,and capacity),what to produce(product)has never been studiedas one of the adjustmentmargins. The annualdiversificationindex is constructedin this paper,using Census Bureaufirm/plant-leveldata. Preliminarywork shows that the diversification index 1) increased at the firm level but decreased at the plant level, 2) procyclically fluctuated,and 3) has different trends by size and industryduring the last three decades in the United States. KIM, Universityof Marylandand the WorldBank NAMSUK Strengthening Intellectual Property Rights: Experience from the 1986 Taiwanese Patent Reforms Intellectualpropertyrights (IPR) have recently moved to the forefrontof debates over internationalpolicy. As each countryestablishes its own institutionsof IPR, a divergence exists between net producersand net consumersin the returnsto providing This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHA Posters 569 strongprotection.Underpressurefromthe developedworld,many developingcountries have begun to strengthentheir IPR, particularlyas regardsto patents.These changes in policy provide us with an opportunityto learn more about the effects of intellectual propertyinstitutionsin developing countries.Whetherand to what extent do stronger IPR spurinventiveactivity in a developingcountry?Whatare the factorsor characteristics of industriesin which strengtheningpatentrights ha the most favorableimpact on inventive activity? Will the strengtheningof IPR in developing countriesinduce more foreign directinvestmentand technologytransferfrom abroad?In an attemptto answer these questions,this paperuses the 1986 Taiwanesepatentreformsto examine the impact of strengtheningpatentrights in a developing economy. The evidence on the number of patentsawardedto Taiwaneseinventorsas well as that on R&D spendingin Taiwan suggest that the reforms stimulated additional inventive activity, especially in industrieswhere patentprotectionis generallyregardedas an effective strategyfor extractingreturnsand in industriesthatare more R&D intensive.The reformsalso seemed to induce additionalforeign directinvestmentin Taiwan. On the otherhand, for industries that chiefly use othermechanismsto extractreturnsfrom their innovation,such as secrecy, the strengtheningof patent rights had little effect on their inventive activity. Neither investmentin R&D nor the numberof patents awardedin these industriesappearedto be much affectedby the strengtheningof patentprotection. SHIH-TSELo, Universityof California,Los Angeles Economic Development and Classical Music: A Case Study of Complex Technology Transfer New musical works and styles are the outcome of deliberativeresearchand significant experimentationand so composition is akin to "invention."The project takes grandopera as a case study of a complex technology, embodied in composersand musicians. This informsthe migrationof composers,establishmentof conservatories,and role of extra-marketsupport-most effectively provided at first in princely states. The project examines the relationship between composition rates, national income and state regime, building on their neighborsin music by importingmusicians, and institutional models. Contemporarycomposition rates imply that convergence has occurred in Europe. SIOBHANMCANDREW, Nuffield College, OxfordUniversity Land Re-allotmentsan the RussianPeasant Communein the Late ImperialPeriod This project investigates the causes and implicationsof communalre-allotmentsof plots among membersof open-field communitiesin late ImperialEuropeanRussia. As partof a largerprojecton the developmentof Russia's ruraleconomy after serfdom, it utilizes descriptions of land communes from archival sources and a data set on reallotmentsin Moscow province to explore the determinantsof the practice and implications for agriculturalproductivity. The evidence suggests that external seignorial and state obligations and local economic conditions impacted the decision to re-allot plots, while demographicfactorswere uncorrelatedwith the practice.No evidence that re-allotmentshamperedagriculturalproductivityis found. STEVEN Yale University NAFZIGER, This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 570 EHAPosters EndogenousEntry and Competitionin the Retail MarketsDuring the Early Twentieth Century This paper examines the endogenous numberof retail establishmentsacross a wide variety of segments and marketsin orderto determinethe natureof competitionin the retail industryduringthe early twentieth century.The analysis uses data from the first census of Retail Distributionin a discrete dependentvariable model to estimate the underlyingprofit function of nearly a dozen differentretail segments. Special attention is given to how the spreadof the automobile,changes in female labor force participation, and the geographic size of a city affected in turn the value of the services provided by retailers, equilibriumstore counts, and entry thresholds.Evidence suggests variationin these factorsplayed a significant role in the competitive structureof retail markets. In particular,more extensive automobile ownership is associated with a reduction in the value of retail services and consequently larger entry thresholdswith fewer storesper capita. TODDC. NEWMANN,University ofArizona UnderstandingWomenas TransitionalEconomicAgents in Early ModernSpain Spanish women witnessed immense political, social, and economic change during the period from 1580 to 1620. The empire transitionedfrom the most powerful Spanish king ever, Philip II, to his less-than-impressiveson, Philip III. The Spanish economy's expansion of the sixteenth century gave way to a minor crises during the first quartof the seventeenthcentury.All the while, the Spanishpeople struggledto understand and manipulatean empire in full maturity.My poster summarizesa chapterof my dissertationand evaluates the ways in which women in the centralSpanish city of Valladolid experienced the ebbs and flows of the Spanish economy. Using over 200 court cases drawnfrom municipal,university,and appellatecourts in Valladolid, I argue that women played a central role in providing an urban economy capable of weatheringsignificantdemographicchanges. I show that as transitionaland formative economic agents, Spanish women contributedto the efficient allocation of resources, thereby benefiting the larger imperial economy. Their contributionis rooted in Spanish law, which honors women's propertyrights. I suggest that women's roles as economic agents may explain the durabilityof the Spanish empire despite serious economic and political problems. DAVID(JACK)NORTON,University of Minnesota Slavery,InstitutionalDevelopments,and Long-RunGrowthin Africa, 1400-2000 Can Africa's currentstate of under-developmentbe partiallyattributedto the large trade in slaves that occurredduring the Atlantic, Sahara,Red Sea, and Indian Ocean slave trades?Qualitativeevidence from the African history literaturesuggests that the answer to this may be yes. This poster attemptsto answer this question empirically. Using data from historicalrecordsthat reportslave ethnicities,an estimate of the total numberof slaves taken from each country in Africa between 1400 and 1913 is constructed.An importantfinding is that the number of slaves exported from a country was an importantdeterminantof economic performancein the second half of the twentiethcentury. NATHAN NUNN, Universityof Toronto This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EHAPosters 571 Industrial Demographics and Productivity Growth in Indonesian Manufacturing, 1975-1995 Indonesian economic history suggests the existence of plant size duality in manufacturing,with few dominantlarge companies, and a large number of small and medium enterprises.Exploiting manufacturingplant-level panel data (1975-1995), this poster used plant heterogeneityand demographyto explain slow productivitygrowth. It decomposes Total Factor Productivitygrowth in to intraplantTFP growth, market share reallocation among incumbents, and plant-turnovereffect. Both market share reallocationfrom low to high productivitygrowth plants, and the process of entry and exit of small- and medium-scaleplants offer a high and positive contributionto aggregate TFP growth. These are, however, cancelled out both by the reallocationof market shares from high to low productivitylevel plants, and incumbents' intraplantproductivity losses. VIRGINIE VIAL,LondonSchool ofEconomics Rural-UrbanMigrationin the Pilsen Area During the IndustrialRevolution This poster deals with the rural-urbanmigrationof the families duringthe Industrial Revolution in one of the most developed parts of the Austro-Hungarianempire-the Pilsen area. My analysis indicates that the household head's expected real rural-urban wage gap was not the main factor which led to the migrationof families. Instead, the family migrationdecision-makingprocess was more of a maximizationof a dynastic utility function. The methodology of the control group technique is used to compare the exact structureof migrantfamilies at the time of arrivalto an urbanarea with the exact structureof families that stayed in the hinterlands.This, in additionto analyses of the expected rural-urbanreal wage gap, helps to analyze family migrationmotifs. ALEXANDER KLEIN,CERGE-EI This content downloaded from 128.32.24.216 on Tue, 8 Apr 2014 18:14:06 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz