JAAS - Jack Fong Cal Poly Pomona home page

453981
12
JAS48310.1177/0021909612453981Journal of Asian and African StudiesFong
Article
Political Vulnerabilities of a Primate
City: The May 2010 Red Shirts
Uprising in Bangkok, Thailand
JAAS
Journal of Asian and African Studies
48(3) 332­–347
© The Author(s) 2012
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0021909612453981
jas.sagepub.com
Jack Fong
California State Polytechnic University, USA
Abstract
Dynamics of the May 2010 ‘Red Shirts’ uprising in Bangkok are examined through literature about the
primate city, a city that is exponentially larger than a country’s other cities. Employing news coverage of
events, history about Bangkok’s urban and political development, and analyses of class-based inequalities and
nationalisms that the city harbors within its confines, attributes of primate city are expanded to include its
perennially vulnerable political status. Such a rendering of the politically vulnerable primate city is employed
to theorize how the primate city – when functioning as a national capital – is more than a large urban center,
but one that collects much of the nation’s hopes, dreams, and political struggles.
Keywords
Bangkok, inequality, primate city, social class, uprising, urban
Introduction
On 5 July 2011 the Pheu Thai political party of Thailand, a third incarnation of a party with members who supported ousted Prime Minister Thaksin Shinawatra in 2006, was officially declared
the winner over its Democrat rivals. It was a victory rendered more dramatic in that the new prime
minister of Thailand was Yingluck Shinawatra, Thaksin’s sister. The victory represented a just
comeuppance for the defeat their supporters, informally known as the ‘Red Shirts,’ suffered during April and May 2010 as it engaged in an urban uprising in the heart of Bangkok, the capital of
Thailand. For scholars of urban development, Bangkok – affectionately referred to Krung Thep, or
‘City of Angels’ by Thais – is classified as a primate city: a type of city that is exponentially larger
than the country’s other cities (Jefferson, 1939). The uprising occurred in the city’s more opulent
areas, one which ultimately faced a violent government crackdown. By the time the insurrection
was dramatically quelled on 19 May 2010, 85 people lost their lives and over 1,378 were injured,
but not before many parts of Bangkok burnt in the worst uprising the only major city in the country
had seen in 18 years (Laohong et al., 2010).
This set of events behooves scholars to consider how a primate city serving as national capital
fares when it is contested politically. Mark Jefferson (1939), the progenitor of the term, alluded to
Corresponding author:
Jack Fong, Department of Psychology and Sociology, California State Polytechnic University, Pomona, 3801 W. Temple
Avenue, Pomona CA 91768, USA.
Email: [email protected]
Fong
333
the political symbolisms of such a city, but did not fully elaborate on the attributes of a primate
city’s political dynamics given his background as a geographer. As such, after exploring the literature on Bangkok as primate city, my main task will be: (1) to illuminate the inordinately frequent
episodes of destabilizing politics that has afflicted Bangkok during the 20th and the first decade of
the 21st centuries. (2) My next task will be to discuss how the most recent conflagration in the city
was one that was more explicitly class-based in character than any other destabilizing political
event to befall the history of Bangkok. (3) My final task is to consider how the class-based uprising
could have been a result of globalization dynamics as well, thus enhancing and ‘updating’ the utility of Jefferson’s concept of the primate city by situating it within the context and consequences of
globalization, a world market that had yet to find prototypical expression in the 1930s.
In the preceding months leading up to the crescendo, thousands of supporters of ousted Prime
Minister Thaksin Shinawatra descended on the city to protest the Democrat-led government that
was placed in power by supporters of a military coup that purged him in 2006. Indeed, I was able
to witness many caravans of Red Shirts arriving during late March 2010 when I was in Bangkok to
analyze the political situation in the country. The Red Shirts, an informal moniker anti-government
protesters employ to signify their movement, reached Bangkok with much fanfare in vans, pickups, buses, as well as small-displacement 250cc motorcycles, many of which flew red and black
flags with political slogans printed on them. At the time the Red Shirts did not yet appear to possess
the acumen to engage in the violent crescendo that was to come, descending upon the city only to
support their social movement led by the political pressure group, the United Front for Democracy
Against Dictatorship (UDD). The UDD was aggressively agitating against the Democrat government of then Prime Minister Abhisit Vejjajiva.
Founded in 1946 after Thailand transitioned from absolute monarchy to a constitutional monarchy, the Democrat Party aimed, at least nominally, to serve the interests of the working class and
the poor. However, the volatile nation-construction process of Thailand since the party’s founding
has seen it often work to uphold imperatives by the military and royalists as well. Detailed on the
official Democrat Party website, its initial orientation during the mid-1940s was to function as an
opposition to the left-leaning government of Pridi Banomyong. Pridi was part and parcel to the
contingent of Thai revolutionaries that ended absolute monarchy in 1932. Since then, the Democrat
Party has intermittently gone into hiatus when particularly strong dictators would abolish the constitution and political parties, only to return when political conditions proved favorable, forming
coalitions in certain periods while attempting to be entirely hegemonic in others (Connors, 2007,
2008; Connors and Hewison, 2008). Led by a variety of leaders that were implicitly and explicitly
allied with royalty, the party has come to be seen as one that upheld the ethos of amathayathipathai
– a value system that honored aristocratic and elitist orientations toward governance – despite its
stated mission to provide a ‘responsible political alternative to the money-fueled political environment’ by upholding principles of ‘democracy, freedom, transparency, and public participation’
(Democrat Party, 2012: para. 18). Currently it has returned to its opposition status to contest the
pro-Thaksin Pheu Thai government led by Yingluck, harnessing pro-royalist ideas to weather continuing power plays by pro-Thaksin constituents (Connors, 2008). That the Democrat Party continues to be led by the Oxford-educated Abhisit Vejjajiva, former prime minister and current leader of
the opposition believed to have supported the removal of Thaksin, has thus not endeared the party
toward any rapprochement with the pro-Thaksin constituency.
Atop their pickup trucks euphoric supporters pounded their drums, waved flags, sloganeered
ideology through their megaphones, and blared Thai country music, or lookthung, through large
loudspeakers mounted in the bed of their trucks. Many supporters on the streets danced with alacrity as the motorized caravans passed and intermittently stopped at intersections. As I watched this
334
Journal of Asian and African Studies 48(3)
particular caravan arrive with many hundreds of supporters onto the historical Sukhumvit Road, a
major and perennially congested road in the Bangkok, I had to remind myself that it was only part
and parcel to the many caravans that preceded it weeks earlier, and followed it weeks later.
The blaring of lookthung music, a musical genre often associated with people from the rural
hinterland – a region conventionally referred to as Isan – is highly significant. Although the gathering of the Red Shirts and UDD supporters comprised Thais from all walks of life, the selffashioned populist movement exhibited a high degree of class consciousness which aimed to
topple a government it perceived as reinforcing amathayathipathai values. As an antipode, lookthung music was employed by the Red Shirts to remind the country that there was, indeed, great
class divide. Lookthung music sung of hope and hopelessness, of dreams and despair, of being
cheated by unscrupulous city folk, of being heartbroken when a lover left for Bangkok and no
longer returned; the songs all pointed to how urban dynamics during Bangkok’s spring was making
visible the problematic and complex class tensions and uncertain conceptualizations of democracy
in Thai society (LoGerfo, 1996). Thailand’s capital of Bangkok now had to hear this forceful Red
Shirts cacophony resonate through the city’s skyline more used to a soundscape, of honks, automobiles, autorickshaws known as tuk tuks, vendor chatter and their caterwauls.
Bangkok as Primate City
Mark Jefferson described the primate city as a city that is a ‘supereminent’ city not only in terms
of size but in national influence as well. It also is a city that represents the ‘culmination of national
life,’ containing ‘all exceptional products’ for consumption by the country’s inhabitants. A city is
primate if it is ‘at least twice as large as the second largest city’ (Brunn, et al., 2012: 20). Other
descriptions of the primate cities can be found in Ayal (1992), who noted how they dominate ‘over
all others’ (p. 355), or Ginsburg (1955) who noted how a primate city is one that contains ‘many
times the population of the next largest city’ (p. 455). There are a few notable primate cities. In
Africa, Cairo, Egypt and Addis Ababa, Ethiopia are examples. In Europe, Paris, France, has often
been cited as a primate city, as has London, United Kingdom. Mexico City is a prominent primate
city as well, while Jakarta, Indonesia, and Seoul, South Korea are other noteworthy examples. That
there are even primate cities ‘suggests an imbalance in development,’ with social inequalities that
will later allow us to transition into our discussion of attempts to politically rectify them (Brunn
et al., 2012: 20).
By the 20th century, Bangkok was also ascribed the dubious distinction of being a primate city.
Demographer Sidney Goldstein noted that ‘Bangkok’s urban primacy is among the most striking
in the world’ (1971: 209) while historian Larry Sternstein described Bangkok as the ‘world’s preeminent “primate city”’ (1984: 43). Eliezer Ayal (1992), for example, noted how Bangkok is indeed
‘an extreme case of primacy’ that ‘cannot be found in any other country at a similar level of per
capita income’ (1992: 355). He continues:
Almost all of the very substantial industrialization during the last three decades . . . has taken place in
Bangkok and its surroundings. The percentage of the population that lives in rural areas is still close to
80%, which, again, is the highest of any country with similar per capita income. (1992: 355)
Indicators of a city’s degree of primacy can be found through two main indices. The simplest
equation is the two-city primacy city index, acquired by dividing the population of the country’s
largest city by the population of the country’s second largest city. During 1996, Bangkok’s primacy
city index was 51, meaning that, at approximately 6 million, it was 51 times larger than Thailand’s
Fong
335
next largest city of Chiang Mai at 117,000 residents (Schwab, 2005: 66). Another commonly used
primacy city index is the four-city primacy city index, calculated by taking the population of the
largest city and dividing it by the sum of the populations of the second, third, and fourth-ranked
cities (Arriaga, 1975; Sokona, 1985; Yu, 1999). As of 2010, Hat Yai (with 158,007 residents),
Nakhon Ratchasima (142,645 residents), and Chiang Mai (142,632 residents) are the respective
second, third and fourth largest cities of Thailand. By 2011, a four-city primacy city index accords
Bangkok 13 times the size of Thailand’s other cities (Department of Provincial Administration,
2010; Ministry of Interior, 2010).
Decades ago, Ginsburg (1955) noted that, although Southeast Asia is renowned for its large
evocative cities, Bangkok is still without exception a ‘true primate city,’ one that fulfills a ‘multiplicity of functions and attractions’ which allow it to function as the heart of Thailand (p. 455).
Even in 1947, a two-city primary city index showed that the capital exceeded Chiang Mai, then
Thailand’s second largest city, 21 times in size. By 1955, Ginsburg was able to note how half the
country’s inhabitants still resided in the city, while its next largest cities averaged approximately
35,000 people. The same index by 1960 showed Bangkok as 27 times larger than its second largest
city while, by 1967, the index increased to 32 times (Goldstein, 1971: 209). Such a consistent
perennial increase in Bangkok’s primacy was already seen by Jefferson over seven decades ago,
noting that Bangkok already ‘was a well-marked primate city of Siam’ (1939: 231), superseding
Thailand’s other cities and drawing ‘away from all of them in character as well as size’ (1939: 227).
Today, the Bangkok Metropolitan Administration (BMA, 2011) records close to 6.3 million inhabitants in the city proper, with a population of 6,522 people per square mile (4,051 people per square
kilometer). The population figure jumps close to 12 million if one includes the five other smaller
adjacent provinces that closely orbit the city, provinces that constitute the greater Bangkok
Metropolitan Region (BMR): Nakhon Pathom, Pathum Thani, Nonthaburi, Samut Prakan and
Samut Sakhon. The BMR covers 3,027 square miles (7,761 square kilometers). The city proper
covers approximately 605 square miles (1,568 square kilometers) while exhibiting an annual population growth rate of approximately 1%. As of 2011, the BMA continues to measure the city’s land
use with four distinct categories, with residential and housing consuming 23%, agriculture consuming 23.58%, and other land use consuming 23.78%. Governmental institutions, industrial
establishments, and commercial structures consume the remaining 29.64% of the city’s real estate
(Ministry of Interior, 2010).
Although statistics about Bangkok as a primate city allow for an understanding of its size, population, density and demographics, there also exist many debates about the nature of primate cities
and their perceived inimical effects upon the hinterland. The debates have often focused upon the
primate city’s role within the urban/rural divide, as well as in how social inequalities are generated
in the relationship. Such views tend to accord the primate city a sort of parasitic character in that it
inhibits the growth of lesser cities due to its demands for excessive public investments and expenditures. As a result, smaller cities and rural communities suffer from a lack of resources and quality
of life deteriorates (Ginsburg, 1955; Henderson, 2002; Tolley et al., 1979).
Past literature on the primate city also contains slight apologias that excused its high degree of
urban concentration of institutions because they were deemed vital for economic efficiency
(Hansen, 1990; Williamson, 1965). Later findings, however, revealed that urban over-concentration
was indeed inimical to economic growth (Henderson, 2002). Richardson (1987) found that the
costs of absorbing an extra family in large cities of Bangladesh, Egypt, Pakistan and Indonesia is
three times that of rural environments’ abilities to do the same, and this rate increases as the city of
its respective countries grow larger. Ginsburg noted how growth of smaller cities and communities
may be disadvantaged by such growth, given that only ‘a limited number of services’ exist there
336
Journal of Asian and African Studies 48(3)
while ‘the great cities continue to possess a virtual monopoly of these services’ (Ginsburg, 1955:
457). That is, a city that is too large is one that ‘reduces economic welfare’ for the rest of the nation
(Moomaw and Alwosabi, 2004: 149).
The view of primate cities is thus not favorable. Some scholars argue that a primate city’s
growth is a deliberate strategy encouraged by the state polity to encourage over-concentration and
development so as to promote hegemony first in the urban area and later in the nation (Ades and
Glaser, 1995; Henderson, 2002). Henderson specifically cites Bangkok, Mexico City, Jakarta,
Seoul, Sao Paolo, and even Paris as complicit in this process (Henderson, 2002). Such favoritism
has been documented in Indonesia where economic activities are controlled by bureaucratic and
corporate entities in the capital of Jakarta (Henderson and Kuncoro, 1996; Kaiser, 1999). Indeed,
the Thai language Thailand – Is It Bangkok? published by the country’s Thammasat University’s
Faculty of Economics, compiled a variety of articles that focused on public policy ‘biases’ that
‘favored Bangkok over the rest of the country’ (cited in Ayal, 1992: 358). Henderson argues how
such favoritism for the primate city has denied ‘hinterland locations necessary transport and communication infrastructure benefits,’ which in turn protect the pro-urban polity competition from
hinterland producers (Henderson, 2002: 97).
Such a pattern echoes Dayley’s findings that the utopianistic rural communities idealized by
Thai elites – what he termed the ‘agrarian myth’ – is contradicted by rural populations that actually
prefer pragmatic, technologically-oriented and self-interested planning for quality of life improvement rather than ‘concerns about cultural purity, nostalgia, or religious renewal’ (Dayley, 2011:
343). If migrants from rural areas are unable to secure material culture of modernity for their
respective regions, they migrate to the capital city. Although many find temporary jobs, the jobs are
often low-paying and do not conclusively improve the quality of life for the long term. Compounding
the complexity of poverty in Bangkok is how such migrants mesh with what Krongkaew described
as Thailand’s ultra poor, constituted by general laborers rather than farm laborers. This contingent
exhibits unique demographic characteristics such as having ‘a higher incidence of widows as heads
of households, fewer number of working days, and greater burden of chronically ill and disabled
persons in the family’ (Krongkaew, 2002: 128). Furthermore, Krongkaew notes ‘surprisingly,
despite the Thai government’s large number of social assistance schemes, very few of the ultra
poor report receiving any assistance’ (2002: 128).
Some cautiously optimistic scholars provide an alternative reading of a primate city’s fortunes. This group criticizes how the use of an oversimplified dichotomy based on the urban–
rural divide tends to situate the primate city in a predator–prey relationship with other smaller
cities. More complex arguments, however, can be found in Ayal’s incisive criticism that ‘mostly
sociologists’ cite urban parasitism of the rural in ways that normatively view an unequal distribution of power as undesirable, a human condition that can (and should) be remedied. For Ayal, an
equal distribution of power in Thai society and culture has ‘never happened’ in Bangkok, or in
Thailand, for that matter (1992: 360). Ayal criticizes those who view Bangkok as parasitic for
harboring an idealism that views ‘the world as . . . a zero-sum game’ (1992: 360; see also
London, 1977). Ayal continues, ‘What is missing in such presentations is that the decisions made
by those who hold power, whatever their motivations, have tremendously increased the size of
Thailand’s national pie’ (1992: 360).
Ayal is not entirely incorrect in his observation. London (1977) notes the argument that a primary city is parasitic upon others has ‘been overstated . . . and denies the possibility that primate
cities may well prove to be generative in the long run’ (p. 51). A cultural reading of Thai society
and culture does not depart too far from his view. Thai society emphasizes strong vertical relationships based on power asymmetries that have their embryonic roots harking back to a world view
Fong
337
that defers to paternalism as flowing from the mandates of its kings (Fong, 2009). Such vertical
relationships make Thailand a hyper status-driven country where a social ethos exists to encourage
deference – and frequently sycophancy – to idealized educational degrees, occupations, gender,
and material wealth. Bangkok has always been a city that welcomed the exploits of aristocratic and
bourgeois, not proletariat, angels.
Bangkok as National Capital
The issues in the preceding paragraph create a segue for us to enter into the discussion of the primate city when it serves as a national capital. To undertake this task, one must now consider the
culturally emotive and power articulations of citizens as they negotiate the technocratic configurations and consequences of their urban setting. We need to focus on the role of power, conflict, and
crises as additional considerations that make the primate system comprehensible beyond infrastructure and demographics. Again we can appreciate Jefferson for his prescience in noting that
nationalisms will crystallize most readily in a primate city serving as a national capital since it
‘expresses the national disposition more completely than any other city . . . an earmark of intense
nationalism . . . the nation’s mind and soul’ (Jefferson, 1939: 229). Bangkok, like all primate cities
serving as national capitals, is the ‘front office’ of the country as ‘equally Paris is the front office
of France’ (Jefferson, 1939: 229).
Bangkok was founded as a new capital by the Siamese in 1768 after their capital of Ayutthaya
was sacked by Burma. Ayutthaya was the second city-state of Siam when it ruled much of Southeast
Asia, with the city-state of Sukhotai acknowledged by historians as the first manifestation of a
Siamese nation. Although Ayutthaya would occupy a longer duration of hegemony than Sukhothai,
approximately four centuries between the 14th and 18th centuries, the second Burmese attack on
Ayutthaya that occurred in 1767 delivered the coup de grâce. Refugees and the polity from
Ayutthaya migrated south along the Chao Phraya River, eventually leading them to the site that is
today Bangkok (Baker and Phongpaichit, 2005; Terwiel, 2005).
The city of Bangkok and its absolute monarchs ushered in dramatic changes for the entire
Siamese nation. By the time the Chakri Dynasty was promulgated in 1782 through the exploits of
King Buddha Yodfa Chulaloke (Rama I), Bangkok, as the national capital of then Siam, would
modernize through two scions of Chulaloke: King Mongkut (Rama IV) and King Chulalongkorn
(Rama V; Thananithichot, 2011). Mongkut was credited with laying the foundations of ‘modernization’ while Chulalongkorn succeeded in warding off British and French colonialism as well as
abolishing slavery (Terwiel, 2005; Thananithichot, 2011), but not before the country was forced to
cede large tracts of Laotian lands in the northeast to France in the aftermath of the naval Franco–
Siamese War of 1893.
Bangkok found its urban footing first as a land-oriented agrarian state. It relied on the land’s
productive capacities since its harbor, nested in the Gulf of Siam, was too shallow and distant from
major shipping routes of the South China Sea. However, ‘exceptional problems of poor drainage
plagued the city from the start’ (Ginsburg, 1955: 461). By the late 19th century, Singapore’s fortuitous geographic position meant that international trade would swing by its port rather than the port
of Bangkok. Yet even with this development Bangkok was unequivocally ‘primate’. Compared to
Singapore, it was more ‘indigenous rather than Western . . . a case of an indigenous capital acting
as a revolutionary medium for socioeconomic change’ (Ginsburg, 1955: 461). With the aviation
age, however, the city over time became as an important node for air transport logistics between
Europe and the Far East, as well as between Australia and Europe (Ginsburg, 1955: 462). With the
Suvarnabhummi International Airport that replaced the ageing Don Muang International Airport in
338
Journal of Asian and African Studies 48(3)
2006, Bangkok is now an important international air center in Southeast Asia and the third busiest
in Asia (Airport Council International, 2011).
Never colonized by any European power while its neighbors of Burma, Cambodia, Laos,
Vietnam, India and Indonesia fell under the yoke of British, French and Dutch colonialism, imperialistic pressures from Europe did force the city’s polity to envision the Thai state through new
constructions of territorial boundaries, but primarily on its own terms (Winichakul, 1994). In this
regard Bangkok was able to render Thailand’s trajectory in ways that were distinctly different from
that of its other Southeast Asian neighbors. As far back as 1865, a member of the Board of Foreign
Missions noted how Bangkok was ‘at once the seat of government, of religion, of foreign commerce, in short of nearly all public life in the kingdom’ (Sternstein, 1984: 49). In contrast to
Jefferson’s observation, ‘Bangkok is more to Siam than Paris to France’ (Sternstein, 1984: 49). By
1949, the polity’s vacillation in changing the country’s name from Siam to Thailand was resolved
and the name change became permanent.
During the 1950s, a national bourgeoisie based on banking and finance enhanced the city’s role
as an import–export hub, developing its industrial base (Brown, 1994; Hewison, 1989). Throughout
its post-World War II 20th century growth, Bangkok was where the vast majority of new factories
were built. The city also included comprehensive institutions that were headquarters for nationalized utilities, subsidized public transportation, financial services, a variety of educational, cultural
and entertainment facilities, as well as military institutions (Ayal, 1992: 358). When the aforementioned pull factors combined with the push factor of a chronically poor quality of life in many areas
of the hinterland, rural migrants hastened their flight to the ‘relative security of the city’ (Ginsburg,
1955: 457–458). Spurring economic growth, the city collected many of its migrants in ways that
allowed for the majority of them to be absorbed into the employment stream. This pattern ran
counter to the Todaro Migration Model which predicted that aggressive urban public sector
employment policies would actually result in a large population of unemployed workers from the
rural periphery. The vast majority of migrants to Bangkok, due to how informal networks are
instrumental in securing resources in Thai life, tend to find at least temporary employment ‘very
soon after or even before their move’ (Ayal, 1992: 358).
Political Vulnerabilities of Bangkok from the 1940s to May
2010: Expressing the National Disposition
It should be emphasized, however, that throughout much of the city’s history, a metaphysical and
sacred zeitgeist was never far from Thais given the continued staying power of monarchy and its
current monarch, King Bhumibol Adulyadej (Rama IX: 1927–present; Fong, 2009). As he matured
into a young king his visibility in the Thai political landscape increased as well. Much of this was
a result of General Sarit Thanarat, who ruled the country from 1958 until 1963 (Baker and
Phongpaichit, 2005; Fong, 2009; Handley, 2006). At a time when the communist threat against
Thailand was very real, any political crises that appeared to threaten the nation would prompt
Bangkok to suspend local autonomy in the rural hinterland, a tendency that saw its first explicit use
in 1952 when a Muslim separatist in the primarily Islamic south, Haji Sulong Tomina, was abducted
and jailed, only to later ‘disappear’ (Baker and Phongpaichit, 2005; John and Parashar, 2005). In
1959 Sila Wongsin, a religious healer from the Isan province of Khorat known for his separatist
tendencies, was publicly executed after Thai troops attacked his village. In 1961 Sarit ordered the
executions of Khrong Chandawong and Thongpahn Suthimat, leftists from the Isan region that
bemoaned the continually increasing centralization of Bangkok while severe conditions of inequality remained in the hinterland. Similarly, Sarit’s successor, a returning general named Thanom
Fong
339
Kittikachorn, bombed and napalmed hill villages when the Hmong hill tribes launched a rebellion
in the country’s northern provinces between 1967 and 1968 (Baker and Phongpaichit, 2005).
Unlike the previous dictator of the country, General Phibun Songkram, who helped usher in a
relatively more democratic Thailand by severely constraining the powers of its new constitutional
monarchy, Sarit freed the king to roam the capital and the country. Sarit’s gesture cannot be underestimated for its historical significance and irony: whereas constitutional monarchy was ostensibly
now weaker under a maturating and nascent Thai democracy, King Bhumibol would yield a moral
and righteous legitimacy that was as great, if not greater, than his absolute monarchical predecessors, so much so that even today politicians defer (those with republican sentiments rather grudgingly) to the sacrality of their king. More importantly, many in the population praise and revere his
charity, along with his ability to weather and resolve a variety of acute political crises that erupted
in Bangkok during 1973, 1976, and 1992.
The political crises of 1973, 1976 and 1992, where many student protesters and civilians were
killed by various hyper-nationalist factions as well as the military, were only alleviated when the
king, according to royalist narratives, successively intervened to save the country from unraveling.
In the 1973 episode, over 400,000 thousand students and civilians challenged the rule of the Field
Marshall Thanom Kittikachorn by mobilizing around Bangkok’s Democracy Monument on 13–14
October 1973. The iconic monument, one of two highly symbolic structures (the other being
Victory monument), was built in 1939 to commemorate the 1932 coup d’état that established
Thailand’s parliamentary democracy. The bloody crackdown that followed was countered when
King Bhumibol opened up his Chitralada Palace to allow in a group of student delegates to have an
audience with him (Handley, 2006: 210–211). Seventy-seven were ‘officially’ killed, but the exact
number is not known. Realizing his cause was lost given the king’s large moral footprint, Thanom
fled the country, only to attempt to sneak back in 1976. Thanom’s return sparked another set of
massive protests. Fearing a leftist incursion in the country, nationalist paramilitaries killed 46 students at Bangkok’s ‘people’s university,’ Thammasat University, founded by left-leaning Pridi
Banomyong in 1934, unequivocally the most progressive university in Thailand.
During 1992, under the rule of General Suchinda Krapayoon, Bangkok’s population again
grew restive. Having seized power in a military coup a year earlier, his political machinations
managed to result in the Thai parliament appointing him prime minister. Up to 200,000 people
filled Bangkok’s Sanam Luang, a massive public park near the Grand Palace. Between 17 and 19
May 1992 these supporters protested Suchinda’s appointment, and in a scene Thais are all too
familiar with, the government again launched a bloody crackdown that claimed 52 lives. Even
though the protests climaxed on 18 May 1992 with government troops shooting into the crowds,
tens of thousands remained at the park, prompting royal appeals by the crown prince and princess
of Thailand. Again King Bhumibol intervened. On 20 May 1992 he summoned Suchinda and his
rival, protest leader Chamlong Srimuang, to be reprimanded. At Bangkok’s Chitralada Palace,
both approached their monarch in a prostate position, televised for the nation to see. Protests were
called off by Chamlong forthwith, and Suchinda resigned his prime ministership by the end of the
week. Thus, for much of the populace, the king had become their interventionist monarch and is
revered as a sacred leader by the vast majority of Thais (Connors, 2007; Fong, 2009; Handley,
2006; Hewison, 1997).
During the Diamond Jubilee celebrations of the king’s 60th year on the throne in June 2006, a
surfeit of pomp and pageantry spanned a five-day celebration where a gathering of kings and
queens from over a dozen countries attended festivities in Bangkok, and throngs of royalist supporters celebrated as well. Over one million Thais in their yellow shirts – the birth color of the king
– congregated outside Bangkok’s Ananta Samakhom Throne Hall, completed in 1915, while almost
340
Journal of Asian and African Studies 48(3)
as many amassed at the Grand Palace. King Bhumibol also controversially legitimated the 19
September 2006 military coup that purged the government of the autocratic yet popularly-elected
Thaksin Shinawatra while he was in New York City, paving the way for another iteration of military rule to briefly return. Yet the blurring of Bangkok, Thainess, and a politicized royalism has had
previous iterations in the city, namely in 1982 when the city celebrated its bicentennial, in 1987
when the king celebrated his 60th birthday, along with the king’s 80th birthday, celebrated in 2007
(Thananithichot, 2011). By the May 2010 uprising, however, the ailing monarch was in a much
more subdued role. Sensing his political inefficacy, Red Shirts aggressively rallied around the
Victory Monument – built in 1941 to commemorate Thailand’s victory over the French in the brief
Franco–Siamese War – and Democracy Monument as well, only three miles apart as the crow flies.
Thus one cannot employ purely an economic lens to read the dynamics of Bangkok. In the capital city, political monuments function to romanticize, sacralize and charge Siam and Thailand’s
histories. The city also contains the prestigious Chulalongkorn University, founded in 1917 by
King Vajiravudh (Rama VI) to honor his father King Chulalongkorn (Rama V), whose diplomatic
acumen was credited with singlehandedly preventing colonial Britain and France from colonizing
Siam. Near the banks of the Chao Phraya River that snakes through Bangkok is the aforementioned
Grand Palace, a massive palatial compound that was the official residence of kings from the 18th
century until after World War II. Indeed, across the Chao Phraya, the early 19th century Wat Arun,
the ‘Temple of Dawn,’ stands watch over a massive and volatile political capital that has seen 18
military coups or attempted coups since 1932, and almost as many constitutional changes.
The most recent destabilization erupted after discontent over Thaksin’s 2006 ouster by the military. His populist base remained convinced of his legitimacy. By 2010, these supporters were galvanized enough to descend into Bangkok, a context that framed the beginning of this paper. Yet
prior to 2010, protests by pro-government and pro-Democrat ‘Yellow Shirts’ occurred at many
different venues in Bangkok. In 2008, they protested against a pro-Thaksin prime minister, Samak
Sundaravej at the city’s Government House, forcing Samak to vacate the premises. They organized
regular street protests and rallies, and descended upon Suvarnabhumi and Don Muang international airports, disrupting operations. By the time the Yellow Shirts succeeded in removing Samak
and, later, another pro-Thaksin prime minister Songchai Wongsawat (Thaksin’s brother-in-law),
Abhisit Vejjajiva of the Democrat Party rose to power. These developments exponentially amplified the overall indignation of the Red Shirts.
By 2009, hundreds of Red Shirts had raided a hotel where political leaders from Asia had gathered to attend the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) summit, forcing the cancellation of the summit. Victory celebrations were held at the Victory Monument thereafter. By April
2010, Red Shirts descended on the parliament building, forcing some politicians to climb over
walls and fences to escape.
Street rallies and protests were already frequent at different areas of Bangkok by spring 2010,
with surreal Orwellian scenarios such as an exiled Thaksin appearing on large projection screens
set up at various rally sites to inspire his supporters, most of whom congregated at the democracy
and victory monuments. Having declared a state of emergency, Abhisit attempted a crackdown on
10 April 2010 at the Democracy Monument area and 25 deaths ensued; earlier a group of Red
Shirts attempted to storm the first army headquarters but was turned back with water cannons and
tear gas. The bloodletting had begun. In the following days, Red Shirts and government forces
battled with grenade launchers, machine guns and homemade rockets. In the adjoining province of
Pathum Thani, part of the BMR, Red Shirts forced their way into a Thaicom satellite station. By
May, shots were fired at banks and grenade launchers were used against police outposts.
Fong
341
The Class-Based Nature of the May 2010 Uprising
During May 2010, thousands of Red Shirts had headquartered their operations at the inordinately
affluent Ratchaprasong shopping district, transforming approximately 2.5 square miles (4 square
kilometers) of adjoining city blocks into a fortressed compound. Were one to enter any of the opulent shopping complexes, smartly dressed retail workers sycophantically attend to consumers; all
the while, visitors are cooled with air conditioning that makes them forget about the perennially
torrid heat and humidity that is typical of the region, as well as the chaos of traffic, noise pollution
and small streets known as sois, or tight residential roads. The bustling cacophony on the ground
is comparatively less explicit in the Ratchaprasong area, hidden by a world of shadows created by
the city’s commercial high rises, closely-clustered skyscrapers and the elevated Bangkok Transport
System’s Skytrain, or BTS. Near the opulent Central World – the third largest shopping complex in
the world – security guards blow on their whistles to direct traffic into and out of the structure. In
the vicinity toward the southeast of the area is Lumpini Park, frequently used by Thais to exercise.
Its thick foliage serves as an important, albeit small antipode to the concrete and glass-centric
Ratchaprasong skyline that includes many lavish world-renowned hotels as well. The Red Shirts’
occupation of the Ratchaprasong area was thus a brilliant ideological proclamation by those who
have little or nothing, to those who have plenty. Many Red Shirts would hardly be able to afford
the items that wealthy Thais, expatriates and tourists could conspicuously consume at Ratchaprasong.
By mid-May there were few smartly dressed people in the area and even fewer tourists: a state
of emergency had been declared during this period. Indeed, the Red Shirts at Ratchaprasong had
already been surrounded by government troops that nested the Red Shirts’ occupation area within
their own 12 square kilometer cordon, in effect creating a noose that would tighten in the coming
days. It was not a wholly encompassing noose, however, as residual urban battles would ensue
outside of the area as well, claiming five more lives and 960 injuries. But it was at Ratchaprasong
that Red Shirt leader ‘Seh Daeng’ (Commander Red) was shot in the head by a sniper on 13 May
2010 while granting an interview to a New York Times journalist. On 14 May clashes intensified in
the Ratchaprasong area as gunfire, sniper attacks and again, grenade launchers, were employed by
both sides. By 17 May over 37 fatalities were recorded as government troops retook sections of
Ratchaprasong. On this same date, four days after being shot, a comatose Seh Daeng died from his
wounds. Sensing the tide turning, the government ordered helicopters to fly over the Ratchaprasong
compound to drop flyers urging protesters to leave.
The crescendo was reached on 19 May 2010 when armored personnel carriers stormed the barricades of the Red Shirts in an all-out assault. Seeing their imminent defeat, Red Shirts leaders took
to their makeshift stage and ordered their supporters to end the fight. Disappointed in the outcome,
militant Red Shirts shifted their tactics toward surgically oriented political arson: hardcore rankand-file Red Shirts broke out of the Ratchaprasong cordon, dispersed and began to burn certain
structures throughout Bangkok while others continued to fight the Thai army. By 10 May a total of
85 people lost their lives: 80 men and five women; two were journalists and three foreigners of
Japanese, Burmese and Italian origin.
A veritable class uprising did ensue if one examined the patterns of collateral damage upon conspicuous consumption infrastructure as indicators. Thailand’s Center for the Resolution of Emergency
Situation (CRES) identified the 36 structures that were torched in Bangkok (see Table 1).
Thirty conspicuous consumption infrastructures that were set alight were of four main categories: (1) private banks; (2) state-owned agencies/banks; (3) high-end conspicuous consumption
establishments; and (4) commercial/corporate high rises. The remaining six miscellaneous structures that were torched were adjacent to the 30 structures and were likely burnt inadvertently.
342
Journal of Asian and African Studies 48(3)
Table 1. List of 36 places in Bangkok hit by arson (Nation, 2010).
Structure
Classification
1. Office of the Narcotics Control Board (ONCB)
2. Commercial building in Bon Kai community
3. Kasikorn Bank, soi Ngam Doo Plee branch
4. Siam Paragon Shopping Complex
State agency
Commercial/corporate high-rise, floors unknown
Private bank
High-end conspicuous consumption establishment
– high-end shopping complex
5. Central World Shopping Complex
High-end conspicuous consumption establishment
– high-end shopping complex
6. Maleenont Tower
Commercial/corporate high-rise, 35 floors
7. Government Savings Bank, Sam Liam Din Daeng State-owned bank
branch
8. Metropolitan Electricity Authority, Klong Toei
State agency
branch
9. Metropolitan Waterworks Authority, Klong Toei State agency
branch
10. Stock Exchange of Thailand
Other
11. Sogo Department Store in Ratchaprasong area High-end conspicuous consumption establishment
– high-end shopping complex
12. Siam and Scala Theaters
High-end conspicuous consumption establishment –
located in Siam Square, a high-end shopping complex
13. Post Publishing Public Company Limited
Other – owner of Bangkok Post, an English language
daily newspaper.
14. Bangkok Bank, Asok branch
Private bank
15. Bangkok Bank,Victory Monument branch
Private bank
16. Bangkok Bank, Chan Road branch
Private bank
17. Center One Shopping Mall
High-end conspicuous consumption establishment
– high-end shopping complex
18. Siam Square
High-end conspicuous consumption establishment
– high-end shopping complex
19. Siam City Bank, Siam Square branch
High-end conspicuous consumption establishment
– located in Siam Square
20. Bangkok Bank, Siam Square branch
High-end conspicuous consumption establishment
– located in Siam Square
21. Retails shops in Siam Square soi 5 and 6
High-end conspicuous consumption establishment
– located in Siam Square
22. Mahatun Plaza Building on Ploen Chit Road
Commercial/corporate high-rise, 18 floors
23. Bangkok Bank, Rama IV branch
Private bank
24. 7-Eleven store, Sam Liam Din Daeng branch
Other
25. Krungthai Bank next to Mater Dei School
State-owned bank
26. Krungthai Bank, Asok branch
State-owned bank
27. Bangkok Bank, Bangjak branch
Private bank
28. Tesco Lotus Express convenient store, Rama IV Other
branch
29. Bangkok Bank, Sathupradit branch
Private bank
30. Bangkok Bank, Saphanluang branch
Private bank
31. Siam City Bank, Sam Liam Din Daeng branch
Private bank
(Continued)
343
Fong
Table 1. (Continued)
Structure
Classification
32. Siam City Bank, Sunthornkosa branch
33. 7-Eleven store near Victory Monument
34. Bangkok Bank, Hua Lam Phong branch
35. Siam Commercial Bank, Prachachuen branch
36. Big C Superstore, Rajdamri branch
Private bank
Other
Private bank
Private bank
Other
Type of structure attacked in Bangkok:
Notes:
Private banks: 12
Classification, types of structure attacked, and notes
State-owned agencies/banks: 6
by author.
High-end conspicuous consumption establishments: 9 Commercial/corporate high rises: 3
Other: 6
Total structures: 36
Many of the banking infrastructures were symbolically linked to the surfeit of wealth had by Thai
elites as well as the institutions that protected their status. Government structures were attacked as
well since they are often viewed by many Red Shirts as instrumental in supporting Thailand’s
upper classes, the nobility and the royal family, institutions that indirectly or directly reproduced
notions of amathayathipathai.
In the aftermath of the May 2010 protest, Bangkok Pundit, a highly respected blog on Thai
political issues, reported that Thailand’s state planning agency, the National Economic and Social
Development Board (NESDB), estimated that damages from the conflagration would exceed 100
billion baht, or 1% of gross domestic product. The NESDB also noted how avoidance by tourists
and investors to the globalization-friendly city would be sources of future economic loss. However,
Bangkok Pundit itself estimated a figure of over 290 billion baht, or close to USD$9 billion.
Revenues from tourism for the 2010 year was precariously low, according to Tohru Nishihama, an
economist at Dai-ichi Life Research Institute Inc. in Tokyo, even though during the previous quarter Thailand’s growth from output, exports and consumption was at its highest in 14 years (Bangkok
Pundit, 2010). Bangkok’s collateral damage spanned an area of approximately 36 square miles (57
square kilometers).
Globalization and the Primate City
An important extrapolation about the political vulnerabilities of a primate city like Bangkok is how
globalization has altered people’s ties to their respective countries. Although globalization has
certainly ushered in impressive dynamics that (1) quickly spread information, (2) promote free
trade, (3) contribute to the free movement of financial resources, (4) enhance technological innovation, and (5) unfetter movement of labor across national boundaries, it has simultaneously ‘eroded
primordial loyalty and identification with family, clan, tribe, linguistic group, or religion’ (Laquian,
2005: 140). Sassen noted the same tendency, which she described as a ‘denationalizing of national
territory,’ one that ‘contributed to a sense of powerlessness among local actors’ (1998: xxvii).
Citing Bangkok as one of the world’s more important global cities along side New York, London
and Tokyo, Sassen notes how it also exhibits major issues of global cities, such as a ‘sharpening
344
Journal of Asian and African Studies 48(3)
inequality in the concentration of strategic resources and activities between . . . others in the same
country’ (2001: 125). When local citizens are unable to penetrate mainstream society through their
only significantly major urban center, globalization and its discontents may continue to have classbased dynamics which characterize its political terrain. With the denationalizing of nation already
set in place by globalization, Bangkok may no longer be able to wholeheartedly express the
‘nation’s mind and soul,’ as noted by Jefferson (1939: 229). Exacerbating this dynamic may be
how the rupturing of a unanimous rendering of the Thai nation was also influenced by the migration patterns of citizens from the rural hinterland.
Although Bangkok is the country’s exponentially largest city, this does not mean that the city
can permanently collect every migrant coming to the city. If the city cannot take in migrants beyond
a certain parameter, the only option for migrants is to have but a temporary stay in the city if they
desire to have some modicum of a quality of life. Fuller, Kamnuansilpa, and Lightfoot (1990:
535–536) identify a back and forth ‘circular mobility’ migration taking place between rural areas
and Bangkok, an important economic strategy for rural households. This phenomenon exhibits
patterns where migrants temporarily stay in the city insofar as the can harness urban networks for
whatever labor opportunities are available, only to later return to their rural provinces with their
earnings. Studies by Goldstein et al., (1977) and Papanek (1975) demonstrate similar patterns of
the semi-permanent stays of migrants to Bangkok. Sternstein noted this same pattern for the
younger demographic as driven by ‘seasonality tied to the school calendar’ (1974: 138). For Fuller
and colleagues, ‘circular mobility is quantitatively far more significant than the types of permanent
migration recorded by national censuses . . . and is . . . consequential for the social and economic
development of both urban and rural areas’ (Fuller et al., 1990: 536).
Yet circular mobility is not a simplistic phenomenon. The process actually includes a variety of
nuanced strategies that include ‘return migration . . . wage labor migration, seasonal mobility,’ and
‘sojourner movements’ (Chapman, 1982: 1–2). The strength of the link between: (1) the primate
city of Bangkok and its embodiment of the elitism and conspicuous consumption that denies the
disadvantaged opportunities for full participation and inclusion into Thai society; and (2) the
migrants’ temporary links to Bangkok in ways that minimize their emotional investment and loyalty to it urgently requires more precise elaboration and investigation. Such is the misplaced ambitions of Bangkok as a primate city: expectations that the super-city can perennially bridge cultural,
political, and economic distances of the entire nation.
What remains to be seen are pivotal historical episodes that are on the horizon for Bangkok: the
period after King Bhumibol and his almost seven decades of paternalistic rule and the real likelihood of Thaksin’s return, a pathway already being paved by his sister’s election victory, a victory
which will be seen as a mandate for supporters of Thaksin’s politics. On 24 March 2012 the
Bangkok Post reported that Thaksin told his supporters that he would soon make an ‘elegant’ return
to the country, one that will see him ‘come back with style.’ In the meantime, Thaksin cheered his
supporters on, noting how the Pheu Thai government was ‘doing its very best’ to help detained Red
Shirts complicit in the uprising to be freed. Thaksin noted: ‘I would like Red Shirt detainees to be
patient. I am talking with judges and everything should be settled. If the government has no money
to bail out the Red Shirts, I will use my own money to bail out everyone. I keep in close contact
with red shirt leaders’ (Kingkaeo, 2012: para. 3). Thaksin further insisted that his return was
‘imminent.’
Cautiously extrapolating from Bangkok given the listing of arson sites and the types of structures attacked, the data suggest that primate cities serving as national capitals in countries with
glaring inequalities – if they continue to be exacerbated by globalization – will be highly vulnerable to class-based political upheavals in the future. This is due to the sheer density in how state and
Fong
345
conspicuous consumption institutions are configured proximately to one another. Such density
allows for reactive political entrepreneurs to see explicit antipodes of inequality. That is, ensconced
within the shadows of the opulent skyscrapers are the unresolved tropes of Krongkaew’s ultra poor
(2002): the impoverished selling lottery tickets, children selling garlands and cleaning automobile
windows during red lights, or most poignantly, physically disfigured citizens with missing limbs
begging for money, while others ably sing lookthung songs and classic Thai ballads outside impressive office high rises.
No matter where one enters the chronology of 18th-, 19th-, or 20th-century Bangkok, the city
functions not only as the country’s front office but as its tangible political frontline as well. In
Bangkok, different nationalisms and great class divisions and interests compel political entrepreneurs to mobilize their constituencies to forge a nation. Now in the age of globalization, the city’s
status as a conspicuous consumption capital – amplified by banking and shopping ‘monuments’ –
is also contested by aristocratic old world views of hierarchy that attempt to supplant globalization’s inequalities with their own, contributing to the city’s volatile interaction between development
and tradition in highly complex ways. In Thailand’s super-city where privy council members
uphold royalty while republicans and many economistic Thais would rather see otherwise, dramatic chapters for the primate city of Bangkok and its 244-year history are still being written.
References
Ades A and Glaser E (1995) Trade and circuses: Explaining urban giants. Quarterly Journal of Economics
110: 195–227.
Airport Council International (2011) Year to Date Passenger Traffic. March. Available at: http://www.
airports.org/cda/aci_common/display/main/aci_content07_c.jsp?zn=aci&cp= 1-5-212-218-222_666_2__
(accessed 26 June 2011).
Arriaga E (1975) Selected measures of urbanization. In: Goldstein S and Sly DF (eds) The Measurement of
Urbanization and Projection of Urban Populations. Liege: International Union for the Scientific Study
of Population, 19–87.
Ayal EB (1992) Thailand’s development: The role of Bangkok. Pacific Affairs 65(3): 353–367.
Baker C and Phongpaichit P (2005) A History of Thailand. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bangkok Metropolitan Authority (BMA) (2011) Available at: www.bangkok.go.th (accessed 19 June 2011).
Bangkok Pundit (2010) Economic Costs of Political Instability. Available at: http://asiancorrespondent.
com/32811/economic-costs-of-political-instability-part-2/ (accessed 6 July 2011).
Brown D (1994) The State and Ethnic Politics in South-East Asia. London: Routledge
Brunn S, Hays-Mitchell M and Ziegler DJ (2012) Cities of the World: World Regional Urban Development.
Plymouth: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc.
Chapman M (1982) Themes on Circulation in the Third World. Working Paper No. 26. East- West Population
Institute. Honolulu: East–West Center.
Connors MK (2007) Democracy and National Identity in Thailand. New York: Routledge.
Connors MK (2008) Article of faith: The failure of royal liberalism in Thailand. Journal of Contemporary
Asia 38(1): 143–165.
Connors MK and Hewison K (2008) Introduction: Thailand and the ‘good coup’. Journal of Contemporary
Asia 38(1): 1–10.
Dayley R (2011) Thailand’s agrarian myth and its proponents. Journal of Asian and African Studies 46(4):
342–360.
Democrat Party (2012) History. Official website of Democrat Party. Available at: http://www.democrat.or.th/
en/about/history/ (accessed 9 February 2012).
Department of Provincial Administration, Ministry of Interior (2010) Available at: www.dopa.go.th (accessed
3 September 2010).
346
Journal of Asian and African Studies 48(3)
Fong J (2009) Sacred nationalism: The Thai monarchy and primordial nation construction. Journal of Contemporary Asia 39(4): 673–696.
Fuller TD, Kamnuansilpa P and Lightfoot P (1990) Urban ties of rural Thais. International Migration Review
24(3): 534–562.
Ginsburg NS (1955) The great city in Southeast Asia. American Journal of Sociology 60(5): 455–462.
Goldstein S (1971) Urbanization in Thailand, 1947–1967. Demography 8(2): 205–223.
Goldstein S, Goldstein A and Tirasawat P (1977) Rural ties of urban migrants in Thailand. Southeast Asian
Journal of Social Science 5: 31–41.
Handley PM (2006) The King Never Smiles. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Hansen N (1990) Impacts of small and intermediate-sized cities on population distribution: Issues and
responses. Regional Development Dialogue 11: 60–76.
Henderson V (2002) Urban primacy, external costs, and quality of life. Resource and Energy Economics 24:
95–106.
Henderson JV and Kuncoro A (1996) Industrial centralization in Indonesia. World Bank Economic Review
10: 513–540.
Hewison K (1989) Power and Politics in Thailand. Manila: Journal of Contemporary Asia Publishers.
Hewison K (1997) The monarchy and democratization. In: Hewison K (ed) Political Change in Thailand:
Democracy and Participation. London: Routledge, 58–74.
Jefferson M (1939) The law of the primate city. Geographical Review 29(2): 226–232.
John W and Parashar S (2005) Terrorism in Southeast Asia: Implications for South Asia. Singapore: Pearson
Education.
Kaiser K (1999) Pre- and Post-Liberalization Manufacturing Location in Indonesia (1975– 1996). 27 May.
Mimeo LSE.
Kingkaeo N (2012) Thaksin vows to pay Red Shirts’ bail. Bangkok Post. 25 March. Available at: http://www.
bangkokpost.com/print/285866/ (accessed 25 March 2012).
Krongkaew M (2002) Thailand’s agrarian myth and its proponents. Journal of Asian and African Studies
37(2): 128–146.
Laohong K, Ruangdit P and Kheunkaew S (2010) PM vows to seek truth: Full investigation promised into
riots – Abhisit: Priority is to heal the mind. Bangkok Post. 22 May. Available at: http://www.bangkokpost.
com/print/178754/ (accessed 18 June 2010).
Laquian A (2005) Beyond Metropolis. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press.
LoGerfo J (1996) Attitudes toward democracy among Bangkok and rural northern Thais: The great divide.
Asian Survey 36(9): 904–923.
London B (1977) Is the primacy city parasitic? The regional implications of national decision making in
Thailand. Journal of Developing Areas 12: 49–s67.
Ministry of Interior, Royal Thai Government (2010) Available at: www.moi.go.th (accessed 12 August 2010).
Moomaw RL and Alwosabi MA (2004) An empirical analysis of competing explanations or urban primacy
evidence from Asia and the Americas. Annals of Regional Science 38: 149–171.
Papanek CF (1975) The poor of Jakarta. Economic Development and Cultural Change 24: 1–27.
Richardson H (1987) The costs of urbanization: A four country comparison, economic development. Economic Development and Cultural Change 33: 561–580.
Sassen S (1998) Globalization and its Discontents. New York: The New Press.
Sassen S (2001) The Global City. Trenton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Schwab W (2005) Deciphering the City. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson/Prentice Hall.
Sokona O (1985) Urban primacy in developing countries: The case of Mali. Population Today 13(4): 6–7.
Sternstein L (1974) Migration to and from Bangkok. Annals of the Association of American Geographers
64(1): 138–147.
Sternstein L (1984) The growth of the population of the world’s pre-eminent ‘primate city’: Bangkok at its
bicentenary. Journal of Southeast Asian Studies 15(1): 43–68.
Terwiel BJ (2005) Thailand’s Political History: From the Fall of Ayutthaya to Recent Times. Bangkok: River
Books Co., Ltd.
Fong
347
The Nation (2010) List of 36 Places in Bangkok Hit by Arsons. Available at: http://www.nationmultimedia.
com/home/2010/05/20/national/List-of-36-places-in-Bangkok-hit-by-arsons-30129869.html (accessed
12 July 2012).
Thananithichot S (2011) Understanding Thai nationalism and ethnic identity. Journal of Asian and African
Studies 46(3): 250–263.
Tolley G, Gardner J and Graves P (1979) Urban Growth Policy in a Market Economy. New York: Academic
Press.
Williamson J (1965) Regional inequality and the process of national development. Economic Development
and Cultural Change 13(4): 3–45.
Winichakul T (1994) Siam Mapped: A History of the Geo-Body of a Nation. Honolulu: University of Hawaii
Press.
Yu Z (1999) New Paths to Urbanization in China: Seeking more Balanced Patterns. New York: Nova Science
Publication Inc.
Author biography
Jack Fong is a political and urban sociologist who explores the interplay of power in the context of urban life.
His other article and monograph publications include topics related to ethnopolitics of the Karen in Burma,
Thai nationalism, separatism, and American urban life.