Democracy and the Left The case of Indonesia in comparative Indian and Philippine perspectives Draft synopsis of a book project Olle Törnquist Preface to the UiO Democracy Programme’s workshop; Rome, Nov. 7-9, 2011 After Suharto’s crackdown on dissidents in Jakarta on the 27th of July 1996, I postponed the finalising of a book about the problems of popular politics of democratisation. The manuscripts were based on longitudinal contextual case studies in Indonesia, the Philippines and Kerala. The reason for delaying the book was that Suharto and his followers’ uncompromising politics of cracking down on dissidents made it clear in my view that the regime was unable to handle the increasingly urgent issue of succession and reform. Hence, I concluded, it was crucial to conclude the book at this point but to follow the political process for some time as it might well transform into democratisation before arriving at more definite conclusions. (Törnquist 1996) When Suharto had to step aside already two years later in much the same way Ben Ali and Hosni Mubarak did some months ago, however, my role as embedded scholar1 meant that there was no time to resume work on the book. Ironically, moreover, I gained so much exciting participatory insights and information for about a decade and a half (especially in Indonesia but also in Kerala and the Philippines) that even though it should now be possible to recommence the project the material is overwhelming. Hence I have decided to account for the theoretical and methodological lessons from democracy analysis and assessments in a separate text, but it still remains a major challenge to make sense of the remaining material in a book about the political dynamics, especially as it should not bee to long but anyway readable for generally interested scholars, students and leading practitioners, not just for experts on Indonesia (and India and Philippines). Therefore I will be most thankful for your reactions and comments on the following synopsis. I know that there are many pages for you to read, but hopefully it is possible to focus on the structure and the major arguments. Do they make sense for the interested reader? The following draft text may later on serve as a basis for the introductory-cumsummary chapter in the book, but is not proportional to the final book in which the main focus will be the problems of democratisation after the mind 1980s, i.e. from the section entitled ‘Democratisation or business as usual’ on pages 12 and 13 in this paper. 1 I directed and contributed to extensive case studies and two rounds of all-Indonesia democracy assessment surveys in partnership with local colleagues, investigative journalists and senior activists. The research was financed by the Universities of Uppsala and Oslo, the Swedish and Norwegian aid authorities, the Norwegian Ministry for Foreign Affairs, the Ford and Tifa Foundations, the EU representation to Indonesia and by a substantial amount of voluntary labour by the participating researchers and informants. 1 Introduction Leftist liberals and socialists have been decisive in the struggle against colonialism and for improved democracy in the global South, yet three crucial questions worry concerned scholars, experts, activists and pro-democrats in general. Firstly, why have not the leftist struggles been more successful but at times even ended up in the rise of authoritarianism? Secondly, why has it proved possible for internationally supported actors to achieve limited levels of democracy in their own benefit, ignoring radical civil society groups (CSOs) and social movements? Thirdly, why have not these more consistent CSOs and social movements made significant difference in their attempts at fostering more substantial democracy even when benefitting from more freedoms and new opportunities? In looking for answers to these puzzles, I have applied theoretical and comparative perspectives in longitudinal studies of the dynamics of left oriented politics in the context of at first hand Indonesia but also the Indian state of Kerala and to some extent the Philippines. A few more words are needed therefore about the analytical structure and the comparisons. My framework for thinking about the left and democracy is simply to compare over time how the crucial actors in decisive political processes in each context interact as they relate in different ways to (i) the institutions that most scholars would agree are the major means to promote the aim of democracy in terms of popular control of public affairs on the basis of political equality;2 and (ii) aspects of actors’ political capacity to use, resist and alter the institutions that students of power in political organisation and movement deem to be critical.3 What have been the major problems and options of leftist politics and policies in these regards and how can we understand them? While collecting grounded information in these respects, comparative insights have been the major way of reading the data and then discussing what explanatory arguments make sense. The comparisons are on different levels and issues. Indonesia 2 David Beetham (1999) makes the pioneering distinction between the aims and means of democracy and also shows convincingly that most scholars agree on the just mentioned aim of democracy, but as his list of the necessary means is constrained to the liberal democratic model only as well as to the specific institutions developed in western Europe and North America in particular, the following more open ended dimensions may be theoretically as well as empirically more inclusive: (i) Equal and inclusive citizenship in relation to well defined public affairs; (ii) Governance in line with International law and UN-conventions; (iii) Rule of law; (iv) Equal justice; (v) Civil and human rights, including social and economic rights; (vi) Basic needs and education, including on citizen’s rights and democracy; (vii) Democratic political representation through parties and elections; (viii) Institutionalised channels for interest- and issue based representation; (ix) Citizen’s constitutional and legal rights based participation; (x) Democratic decentralisation without compromising equal citizen rights; (xi) Democratic control of instruments of coercion (including private forces); (xii) Transparent, impartial and accountable governance; (xiii) Government’s independence and capacity to implement decisions; (xiv) Freedom of and access to public discourse, culture, academia; (xv) Democratic civil society. For a more elaborate discussion, see Törnquist 2012.. 3 (i) Political exclusion and inclusion in the political terrain; (ii) Ability to transform economic, social, cultural and coercive capital into authority, i.e. political power. (iii) Capacity to turn private concerns into public political matters; (iv) Capacity to mobilise and organise support for demands and policies; (v) Ability to use existing means of participation and representation, reform them and develop new ones. For a more elaborate discussion, see Törnquist 2009 and Törnquist 2012. 2 constitutes the major case of how leftists have engaged or disengaged in democratisation. This is because most structural characteristics of post-colonial countries are at hand in Indonesia; because the largest democratically oriented radical popular movement and party developed and were eliminated here; because a new and different democratic movement evolved against what many deemed to be successful authoritarian development; because this generated what is now the worlds’ third largest but rudimentary democracy; and because the proponents of many different theories claim that they can make sense of these developments – which thus makes Indonesia a critical case in discussing the pros and cons of many arguments on the left and democracy. Yet all kinds of conditions and processes that tend to be crucial in other cases where not at play in Indonesia, and also not all relevant leftist positions. In these respects I have thus broadened the perspective to India and the Philippines. In India, firstly, a significant part of the old left held on to democracy, while on the one hand the pro-Indira Gandhi sections and the Maoists did not and on the other hand one of the worlds’ most impressive attempt was made to combine old and new left-democratic projects in the south western state of Kerala. In the Philippines, secondly, the communists who claimed that democratisation was not a viable way to fight authoritarianism proved entirely wrong, but the new pro-democrats have not made major advances in spite of being more politically oriented than in Indonesia. It is of course impossible to identify perfect comparisons of neither most similar nor most different cases; and so many different (and similar) factors must constantly be kept in mind, even when it only possible to contrast diverse perspectives and experiences. But by focusing on specific themes and processes it has been possible, I think, to gain some fruitful insights. The historical experiences until the mid-1980s in Indonesia in comparison with India and the Philippines dominate the initial part of the text and define the fundamental problem of the left and democracy. I draw on my conclusions in previous books and articles where I applied relevant results from the research of more area studies oriented colleagues to my analytical and comparative framework and added studies of documents and rather extensive interviews with leading activists. The following and most extensive parts of the forthcoming book focus, then, on the attempts of overcome the problems of the old political projects. Indonesia remains the major case but the experiences from the Philippines and especially the Indian state of Kerala become increasingly significant. Equally important, the main empirical sources for the analysis are now grounded case studies and surveys with local colleagues, journalists and activists as well as participant observation. The end of anti-colonial democratisation As in many other colonies, the first wave of democracy in Indonesia grew out of the struggle against imperialism, racism and indirect rule through local strongmen. The first 3 wave came to a halt after the national elections in 1955, followed by partial local elections in 1957. Ironically, there was little wrong with these elections. But the outcome was a stalemate between nationalists, traditional and modern oriented Muslims as well as the rapidly advancing communists, including the failure of the liberal socialists. An attempted coup, the stepping down of the Vice President, and the protests in the regions led most actors to conclude that democracy was the problem, not the solution (e.g. Bourchier and Legge 1994). There was the fear that the remarkably successful Communist Party was about to be elected into power. The communists did not give priority to democracy, arguing that it was crucial to struggle against those who were siding with the West in the cold war (Törnquist 1984). Both the liberal oriented socialists (often in agreement with those in Singapore) and the Muslims in the ‘western camp’ assumed that real democracy was impossible before the country had been properly modernised. All important actors abandoned, thus, democracy, most prominently, President Sukarno, along with mainly Java and Bali based nationalists, communists, as well as traditionally oriented Muslims and military officers in favour of a unitary state, developing instead an anti-colonial campaign to ‘liberate’ West New Guinea. It was used to nationalise all Dutch properties and to introduce ‘guided democracy’. This was to corner and undermine the pro-western liberal socialists, modernist Muslims and related officers, who in turn developed western-supported regional rebellion from their major bases on the ‘outer islands’. When Jakarta seemed able to contain the rebels however, the West altered its policies in favour of attracting liberal technocrats and anti-communists in the national army command. This was part of a new strategy based on Samuel Huntington’s idea that there was a need for strong state and political institutions ahead of democracy – the socalled politics of order (Huntington 1965) – to thus be able to govern modernisation, handle popular expectations and contain communism. In addition to relying on the army, the measures included generous western education of economists, administrators and officers in cooperation with American military academies, university based area studies programmes and Ford Foundation. In short, all major actors and their international sponsors agreed that however defined democracy was premature and had to be preceded with structural and institutional changes. These positions resonate well with the internationally still predominate theories and recommendations. The first is best know for the compatible classical dictums of Samuel Lipset and Barrington Moore that democracy requires market-led modernisation, freedoms and civil society, driven by bourgeois capitalists and other middle classes. The second is the ‘sequencing of democracy’ thesis which is an updated version of Samuel Huntington’s famous thesis that liberal democracy presupposes not just capitalist modernisation but also strong state institutions including the rule of law (e.g. Mansfield 4 and Snyder 2007). The third is by leading scholars of comparative social science such as Göran Therborn and Dietrich Rueschemeyer and Evelyne and John Stehpens arguing that democracy rests with the dynamics of capitalism which have made the dominant capitalists strong enough to abstain from direct control of government when democracy is demanded not so much by the bourgeoisie and middle classes as by the working class (in alliance, then, with middle classes), as well as when the dominant elite need broad popular support to for instance go to war. The fourth is by the radical nationalists and communists who maintain that a democracy which is inclusive of ordinary people can only be built after structural changes such as by way of controlling foreign capital and implementing land reforms. Remarkably, Indonesia has proved all these general theories insufficient and at times even counterproductive. Let us examine them one by one. Democratically dubious modernisation and middle classes Quite against the expectations that modernisation would be the midwife of democracy, and also by contrast to the more successful middle class driven democratisation in India and the Philippines at the time, modernisation oriented Indonesian middle classes lost much of the enthusiasm in these matters as soon as the results from the first 1955 general elections became obvious. The western oriented socialist party was almost wiped out and religious based parties and the nationalists behind Sukarno and the Communist Party made significant advances. Most said then that democracy was premature and that the right conditions first had to be generated. They advocated for the rule of law and for certain rights and freedoms, but not for popular sovereignty. With regard to the rights, moreover, not even liberal intellectuals were consistent. Many supported the army-led crackdown and the mass killings of the members of communist-oriented popular movements in 1965-1966. The same was true in the Philippines with harsh repression against leftist dissidents, convincing in turn so many peasants as well as intellectuals of the need for a Maoist driven insurrection. Even in India, significant numbers of supposedly more modern oriented middle classes behind Prime Minister Indira Gandhi opted several years later for the introduction of a state of emergency, with the support of the Moscow oriented communists. Some of the intellectuals later disagreed with Suharto’s ‘new order’ but were unable to build a substantial middle class constituency even for their opposition to corruption and clientelism. Most members of the middle classes enjoyed instead the social and economic benefits under Suharto and it was only when their special privileges were undermined by the Asian crisis in 1998 that many gave passive support for change. This seems to be a general tendency. By the 1980s and particularly the 1990s modernisation oriented Indian middle classes was the main force. They managed to gain broad popular support by way of Hindu nationalist ideology for a rather sharp turn if favour of neo-liberal oriented politics and policies. Aside form differences over identity 5 politics, the Congress Party too accepted economic liberalisation. Today it is clear that the Indian economic miracle is based largely on the trading, service and IT sectors where the rising middle classes are engaged, but also on cheap labour for basic jobs and needs. The pattern has been much the same in Thailand, for instance, where the modern middle classes and several supposedly democracy oriented NGOs have even rallied behind the king and the military to oppose unwanted populist politicians and policies on the basis of electoral success. Quite recently in India again similar tendencies has come to the foreground with extra parliamentary actions against corruption that have also turn against the primacy of parliamentary democracy. Back in Indonesia, intellectual dissidents with roots in the middle classes were indeed in the forefront of the final struggle against the Suharto regime. But they lacked a constituency in the socio-religious reform movements; and they were unable to draw on clientelism based on positions in the state and in business. The Indonesian attempts to build parties based on liberal, middle class ideas and interests have failed miserably until today. Politics of order against democracy Huntington’s (1965) idea of a strong state that precedes democracy, the so-called politics of order, was successful internationally. It provided legitimacy for Suharto’s coup against Sukarno (which resembled the development in Singapore and the so-called middle-class coups in Latin America and elsewhere) as well as to the subsequent decades of an authoritarian ‘new order’. Yet, there were no signs that the regime was able to give birth to the institutions that were capable of controlling corruption and establishing the rule of law and which were supposed to pave the way for democracy at a later point. Indeed, Indonesia continues to suffer from corruption and disrespect for the rule of law also after the overthrow of the Suharto regime. There have been severe problems of combatting these plagues by relying on the politicians that have been elected since 1998. But it is an irony that the old argument about the need for stable institutions ahead of democracy, which created the problem in the first place, seems to return to the fore, much like it has done among educated liberals, businessmen and royalists in Thailand. More capitalism, less democracy On a general level democracy in Indonesia was of course held back by the weakness of the kind of bourgeois and middle classes that scholars such as Göran Therbon has written about and which in the context of the first democratic countries in Europe and North America were relatively independent of the state, had to regulate their own differences and had sufficient economic resources to compromise with increasingly strong working class demands for equal political and social rights. In the struggle for national independence Indonesian trade unions and labour organisations were important. They were found on plantations and within transportation 6 and other sectors of the colonial economy. Workplace struggles and politics were often combined. After independence, however, the priorities of labour were subordinated to the broader aim of building a national economy. This was part of the social pact between a so-called national bourgeoisie, small and middle farmers and labourers that was advocated generally at the time in the global South by radical nationalists and communists. Populist President Sukarno and the reformist Communist Party took the lead. One of the largest peaceful popular movements in the South failed to stimulate economic growth and to prevent the military and its business allies from capturing the benefits of the massive nationalisations of foreign companies. Labour leaders were eliminated, classoriented labour organisations were repressed, and the few remaining unions were subordinated to authoritarian state-corporatism. Much the same took place in the Philippines with the rise of President Marcos, even if the scale of repression was not as massive. India, on the other hand, withstood the harshest repression but faced similar problems of slow or stagnating economic growth. Despite the rapid expansion of capitalism since the 1970s, neither industrialists, nor the growing numbers of professionals and workers were able to push the Suharto new order in the direction of more democracy. Labour primarily resisted excessive exploitation and major strikes took place in the export producing factories which tried to minimise wages in order to compete internationally. Organised labour in the Philippines faced similar problems, while the Indian challenges (until the opening up of the economy in the 1990s) where more related to fragmentation, party politicisation of unions and the immense importance the informal sectors. It is true that Indonesian labour also opposed brutal primitive accumulation and attempted to place social and civil rights on the agenda. But the connections between unionism and actions more directly in favour of democracy were weak. Labour did not play a major role in the fall of Suharto. Much the same was true in the case of Marcos and Indian unions too have lost much of their political importance. The largest strike in the world (among Mumbai’s textile workers in the early 1980s) came to nothing and the leader Datta Samant who had broad support among the workers failed miserably in gaining votes within politics (Törnquist 1989, 1991, 1991a, 1993, 2002, 2004, Quimpo 2004). This does not mean that the conflicts between labour and capital in Indonesia were unimportant in preparing for the change. It was only in the second part of 1997 after the Suharto regime could no longer regulate the tensions of despotic capitalism that finance capital and other dominant groups lost confidence in its ability to deliver. Ironically, as late as by early May 1998 it was to a large extent the anger among ordinary people over Suharto’s and his advisors’ decision to reduce subsidies even more than demanded by the IMF that boosted student protests and convinced the ruling elite that the captain would have to leave the ship. Why has labour not been able to take advantage of the post-Suharto opportunities? Part of the explanation lies in the crisis that generated his removal. The 7 world’s third largest democracy was not born out of the successful development of capitalism but from its social and economic crisis. The same holds true of the rebirth of the Philippine elite democracy; and it is tempting to say that the massive resistance against Indira Gandhi’s state of emergency was not just about authoritarianism but also her lack of delivering on promises to combine state directed yet market based economic growth with poverty alleviation. Back in Indonesia, the economic crisis meant thus that labour’s bargaining power had substantially diminished. Equally important, however, is its lack of capacity among workers to benefit from the new political space that opened up, at least temporarily. Small autonomous groups and organisations were each fighting the remnants of authoritarianism in their own factories and workplaces. Paradoxically, the divisive patronage offered by the authorities, NGOs, sectoral organisations, and by foreign supporters aggravated matters. Again, similar problems appeared under rather similar conditions in post-Marcos’ Philippines. But even more interestingly, unions and labour were also facing similar challenges in-spite of many different conditions in the countries, thus pointing to importance of defunct political strategies. Meanwhile, in Indonesia and the Philippines in particular but also rather often in India there was no clear-cut, unified enemy to fight given the deliberate disintegration of the state apparatus, privatisation, and the decentralisation of resources. Power struggles were increasingly localised in a jungle of private bosses and semi-private militias. Some labour activists have looked for new patrons at the centre, recreating top–down organisations. Almost all continue to rely on pressure politics, lobbying, and networks or more old fashioned clientelism (Cf. Törnquist 2004, 1993, Quimpo 2004; Ford 2009). Sukarno and PKI nationalism undermine democracy We turn now to the thesis that successful anti-feudalism and radical nationalism had to precede efforts at a democracy. The major proponents of this argument in Indonesia were President Sukarno and the Communist Party, PKI, which by the early 1960s, next to the Soviet Union and China, was the largest communist party in the world with some three million members and about 15 million organised sympathisers. Basically similar basic analyses and strategies were applied in India and the Philippines even if the Maoists took an additional step by claiming that it was necessary to encircle the urban centres and modern capitalist economy by way of armed struggle based on the interests of peasants, dalits, tribal populations and other marginalised groups. Similar arguments have returned to the fore in Indonesia with new populist-nationalist and socialist movements that speak in favour of the politics of Hugo Chavez in particular. And the Maoist thesis has remained surprisingly intact in India and quite successful in the context of Nepal. What are the major lessons regarding democracy from the politics of Sukarno and the PKI? 8 Communist-led popular movements and ultimately Sukarno as well were eliminated because of its involvement in the so-called 30th September Movement directed against the conservative top military leadership. Its actions triggered and legitimised army-led repression and the mass killings across the country, supported by the West. It is now beyond doubt (thanks to John Roosa 2006) that the party chairman Aidit engaged secretly in this adventurous movement and a common explanation for PKI’s collapse is thus that Aidit betrayed the party and the related movements. This however avoids the more fundamental question of why he engaged in these manipulations in the first place. The first argument in my own studies suggests that Aidit’s involvement was rational, given that the party’s strategy had been undermined (Törnquist 1984). Aidit’s involvement was not just an individual ‘mistake’ but was part of an attempt to weaken the anti-communist military leaders in a way that the communists’ main strategy had not been able to do. Thus, the fundamental problem was not Aidit’s regression into the avantgarde politics of the 1940s (of which the 30th of September movement very much reminds) but that the party’s strategy itself was counterproductive. The strategy was to set aside ‘bourgeois democracy’ and to link up with Sukarno’s ‘guided democracy’, land reform and radical nationalism. However, neither aspect of the strategy helped to alter the balance of power. The strategy even helped to strengthen the grip of the military over the economy and the state. The issue of democracy has been neglected in the debate about the failure of the PKI, the massacres, the rise of the ‘New Order’, as well as the failure of resistance. In leftist circles the focus has been on the deficiencies of individual leaders, including their failure to pursue ‘proper’ Maoist strategies. Only recently Max Lane (2010:41-51) has pointed to the fact that the PKI gave up on democracy in the late 1950s and early 1960’s by supporting Sukarno’s ‘guided democracy’. The party failed to object when elections were cancelled by the regime and even supported the banning of critical parties, politicians and artists. It failed to insist on ‘bourgeois democratic’ protection or to prevent the army from taking up leading positions in the economy and civil administration. It would certainly have been risky for PKI to do without the protection of the nationalist forces loyal to Sukarno. In India in the mid 1970s the old Communist Party held on to Mrs Gandhi’s state of emergency and protection in much the same way as the PKI did in relation to Sukarno. The more forceful break-away Communist Party-Marxist, however, was able to link up with ‘bourgeois forces’ in support of democracy. It could survive state repression while mobilising popular support behind its own radical social and economic reforms. It contributed to the termination of the emergency, the defeat of Indira Gandhi’s government and ensured that a Marxist party could lead Left Front governments in both West Bengal and Kerala. Similarly in the Philippines, the Maoist argument about the need for armed struggle to do away with Marcos was proved wrong by the peaceful people’s power demonstrations combined with electoral activism. It is true that the Indonesian army was more prepared to intervene in politics and to engage in 9 repression than its Indian counterpart but the vulnerability of PKI could possibly have been compensated for by broad political alliances. At least it would have made it more difficult for the army to gain full support of both the opposition domestically and the West for its bloody repression. (Cf. Törnquist 1989, 1991, 1991a) Moreover, the communists may well have emphasised that the constitution of 1945, which Sukarno reintroduced, offered protection for both human rights and genuine elections. In principle it would have been possible to struggle for a combination of liberal rights and interest group based democracy instead of accepting Sukarno’s ‘guided democracy’, which Suharto later transformed into a system of state-corporatism and patrimonialism controlled by the military. The question remains: Why did PKI give up on democracy? This puzzle takes us to my second main argument, which is that the problems of strategy in turn were based on poor analysis of the accumulation of power and capital in Indonesia and of how people would be able to resist it and build alternatives. To trace the root causes for this one needs to begin with PKI’s tendency in the early 1950s and onwards to identify with Lenin the powerful actors that de facto turned against imperialism and feudal-like structures in terms of a so-called revolutionary bourgeoisie – but to then upgrade these actors into Stalin’s more rigid notion of national bourgeoisie with a supposedly ‘objective’ and thus ever present interests in turning against imperialism, fighting ‘remnants of feudalism’ and even in promoting ‘bourgeois democracy’ because of the assumption that businessmen and professionals had no other alternative, if they did not wish to become collaborators and pave the way for the communists. These theses were supposed to be generally valid in countries such as Indonesia, India and the Philippines. In Indonesian reality, however, the entrepreneurial oriented actors were often close to the West and anti-communists while the nationalists were not very production oriented and used instead their radical politics and administrative power to enrich themselves. And in the late 1950s when the supposedly progressive nationalists who were drawing on their positions in state and politics were taken aboard PKI’s and Moscow’s upgraded calculations about ‘non-capitalist development’ as substitutes for the vacillating ‘national bourgeoisie’, most politicians, administrators and officers of this kind used instead radical nationalisations and monopolised control of state regulation, assets, credits, investments, prices and jobs as well as of labour and trade unions for primitive accumulation of capital and appropriation of economic surplus. There were similar problems in the Philippines but significantly less so in India where public institutions were more solid, where there were some elements of public accountability and where the ‘national bourgeoisie’ was more production oriented. (C.f. Törnquist 1989, 1991, 1991a) These strategic problems in turn were related to insufficiencies in Marx’ model of the rise of private capitalism in Britain in particular, according to which primitive accumulation of capital refers to the appropriation of land and other means of production 10 from peasants and artisans by strong private actors supported by the state. Thereby the basic means of production were turned into capital (that could be invested) and labourers were turned into commodities (that could be exploited), which enabled capitalist accumulation of capital. In Indonesia as well as in India among many other post-colonial countries but less so in for instance the Philippines it is true that the dominant private actors were typically too weak to act in a similarly forceful way. But that did not mean that they had to chose between turning into lackeys of old colonisers and new imperialists or engaging in the ‘national bourgeois’ or ‘non-capitalist’ projects envisaged by the PKI and their Indian comrades. On the contrary: while not being able to dispossess most people of their land and other means of production, the dominating actors were any way capable of using politics, state and military coercion to accumulate indirect control of natural resources, land and many small businesses – and thus also much of the surplus produced in these sectors – as well as to nationalise or take advantage of foreign owned companies in addition to foreign aid. There were of course huge regional differences and generally this was more common in Indonesia than in India. Yet, in India too it was common to talk of a passive capitalist transformation (or passive revolution); and today similar arguments have been put forward with increasing strength by scholars such as Kalyan Sanyal (2007) and Partha Chatterjee (2008). It is true that PKI-initiated research of the agrarian scene in the late 1950s and early 1960s identified more complicated forms of exploitation and coined the concept of ‘seven village devils’ rather than landlords only. And within other economic sectors the leaders picked up on the Chinese concept of ‘bureaucratic capitalists’ to characterise its new opponents. But the party never acknowledged that irrespective of economic sector the prime base of their adversaries was in their control of politics, state and coercion rather than in links to landlords and imperialists, whom PKI continued to regard as the main enemies and tried to weaken by way of supporting Sukarno’s land reform, nationalisation of foreign companies and generally radical nationalism. In short, the PKI failed to acknowledge that the prime base of their adversaries (which tended to be led by the military) was in their control of politics, state and coercion rather than in their links to imperialists and (the rather few) landlords, which the party continued to regard as the main enemies. The consequences were devastating. The ‘national bourgeoisie’ and the state leaders, who supported or at least accepted Sukarno, did not act as expected. Although PKI constrained militant labour activism in order to build a social pact with the ‘national bourgeoisie’ and the supposedly progressive nationalists in the state apparatuses, little happened in terms of dynamic investments and growth. There were similar problems in the Philippines and to some extent in India too. The result in Indonesia was severe economic mismanagement and crisis. Protests against looting and corruption resulted in more repression but the communists could not fight back as they would thus have lost the 11 support of Sukarno. People were mobilised for the nationalisation of foreign companies and in support of anti-imperialist policies with the purpose of undermining the strength of the so-called bureaucratic capitalists because their power was supposed to be based on foreign capital and the West. But the military leaders continued to extend their control over both nationalised foreign companies and state resources in general. Although, the rural scene was more complicated, there was certainly not much land to distribute and few big landlords to fight. It was very difficult to avoid infightings among small landholders, tenants and labourers, who were subject to more indirect means of exploitation by patrons and local strongmen, who had gained political and administrative power and dominated production and trade. This was not unique for Indonesia even if concentration of land was more important in India and the Philippines. Later, under Suharto’s new order, the extraction of surplus by political and administrative means became more brutalised, of course, and was also used for outright expropriation of land. The same tendency applies to the Philippines and in India too, in spite of more resistance – most recently as part of land grabbing for non-agricultural purposes even in then Left Front dominated West Bengal. With regard to Indonesia in the late 1970s and early 1980s, therefore, my research suggested that the main enemy of the rural poor was rather perceived as the state itself and those in command of it rather than the landlords and strongmen with a base in private capitalist production (Törnquist 1984a). Democratisation or business as usual? In conclusion so far there were there were thus two main positions on democracy in Indonesia by the early 1980s. The predominant one was that the rise of post-colonial capitalism under Suharto was based on centralised neo-patrimonial regime. It had been successful in terms of economic growth but had failed to bring benefits to the middle classes and people in general who were prevented from organising politically while dissidents were suppressed and marginalised (e.g. Crouch 1994 and Robison 1996). The other position (including my own) was that the rise of post-colonial capitalism had generated contradictions that would in themselves nourish radical struggle for democracy. Democracy, in this alternative view, was necessary to fight this type of capitalism which was based on the monopolisation of the means of primitive accumulation (often statebased) and the subordination and repression of common people. In fact many, including poor farmers, fisher folks, urban poor and labourers as well as businessmen and members of the middle classes had already began to turn against the regime, students in particular, at least those who were not given special privileges. The prognosis was therefore that the opponents would come to share a basic interest in democratisation which could be politicised by pro-democracy groups. (Törnquist 1984 and 1984a) Based on comparative studies, I also suggested that a similar analysis and conclusion was valid in the 12 Philippines and in several contexts in India too, in-spite of many structural differences in other respects. (Törnquist 1989, 1991, 1991a) In Indonesia where the argument was particularly at odds with the mainstream position it is well know that the second proposition proved generally correct. Democratisation was certainly not on top of the dissidents’ agenda initially, but things changed within a decade and political liberalisation and democracy was no doubt the major issue when Suharto was overthrown. Unlike what was expected, however, those opposing Suharto’s dictatorship and primitive accumulation by demanding democracy did not also opt for democratising the state. On the contrary, they primarily reduced state and politics by way of privatisation and a rather minimal liberal democracy. In other words my conclusion that demands for democracy would become crucial was thus generally right but at the same time also specifically wrong in assuming that democratisation would be more extensive and substantive by including the hugely important control of state and government. The dynamics of limited democratisation Having specified this paradox, the main puzzle that I wish to address in the main parts of the book is therefore why the widely important democratisation became very limited in character, and what if any chances are there for more substantial democratic transformation. Nobody had dared to challenge Suharto until the student protests gained momentum by April and May 1998. Key local military and political leaders as well as foreign governments were at first hesitant to abandon him. As formal powers were transferred to Vice President Habibe the process of displacement was at first passive and slow. It was soon followed, however, by the quick repositioning of the elite. Leading actors were anxious to protect their authority, legitimacy, contacts, and access to resources within the disintegrating Suharto regime. The pro-democrats were unable to respond to this by gaining the political initiate and suggest realistic alternatives. In less than a year and a half after the overthrow of Suharto, therefore, most of the organised pro-democracy groups had thus lost momentum and much of their influence (Törnquist 2000). In spite of the subordination of the pro-democrats, however, those who were seen to be promoting democracy internationally were a few additional turbulent years able to claim that Indonesia had turned into a success story (cf. Aspinall 2010). Indonesia, with the largest Muslim population in the world, with a Christian minority and a wide range of ethnic groups, had gone from being the most authoritarian to the most liberal country in Southeast Asia. Although Papua remains a problem, East Timor has become independent and the civil war in Aceh has been replaced with rudimentary local self-government and democracy. The political role of the military has been significantly reduced. Corruption 13 remains severe but is at least much criticised. The economy does well thanks to the export of raw materials and middle class consumption. How did this happen? How was it possible to achieve these partial yet important victories without really altering the structural conditions? It is tempting to conclude that Indonesian democracy is fake, that it is an oligarchy based on Suharto’s old elite and that the main difference with Suharto’s time is that the various sections of this elite are now formally governing themselves through democratic elections in which they use the huge funds that they have accumulated in the past as well as their influence in media and various public and private institutions to get the people to vote for them (Robinson and Hadiz 2004). A more careful examination (e.g. Piryono et.al. 2007 and Samadhi and Warouw 2009) emphasises instead the process of de-politicisation. In this view, centralised political governance of public affairs, including business opportunities, has been replaced by decentralisation, privatisation, and delegation to numerous non-government institutions. Elected executives, parliamentarians, and NGO leaders have taken over from those who were in the past appointed by the authorities. There have been no safe heavens for the old oligarchs. However they have been given the best possible opportunities to accommodate to new alliances with former dissident politicians, businessmen, and social leaders. Both central and local government institutions as well as political parties have thus been de facto monopolised by the powerful elite thanks to funds, networks and control of media. Formal rules prevent ordinary people from running as candidates even in local elections. Only parties that have funds enough to establish offices and collect signatures in the country at large are allowed to contest. Candidates need to be well educated and on the village level they must often pay for the administrative costs of the elections out of their own pockets. Suharto’s corporative system of top-down representation has not been replaced. Democratic issue- and interest based representation continues to be overshadowed by pressure group politics, lobbying, and media campaigns, which require good contacts and access to substantial funds. In the Philippines the same tendency had been obvious already during the people power demonstration along the EDSA ring road when elite figures such as Corazon Aquino and Cardinal Sin gained the initiative almost immediately and was then followed up in the reintroduction of what Ben Anderson effectually labelled ‘cacique democracy’ (Anderson 1988). Later on John Sidel (1999, 2004) analysed most convincingly the same tendency in terms of bossism, emphasising the extensive role of state and politics, including elections. The only possible opening for renewal, others added, seemed to be the extensive decentralisation, particularly fought for by liberal senator Pimentel. Decentralisation was however mostly dominated by local elites. Even in Indonesia Sidel’s politically (and electorally) rooted bossism spread rapidly in spite of some resistance from the comparatively stronger communitarian ethnic and religious organisations as well as the remnants from the bureaucratic-colonial state that had been 14 so weak in the Philippines. (C.f. van Klinken 2007, 2009, Nordholt 2004, Nordholt and van Klinken 2007) In these respects, it is rather Indonesia and India that now remind more of each other. India continues to benefit from its stronger and less corrupt state and political institutions, more inclusive political system and more independent and vibrant scholarly community as well as politically subordinated military. Yet deinstitutionalisation, informalisation and the expansion of corruption have been parallel and as rapid as the neo-liberalisation of the economy; and while democracy is being undermined it survives. (C.f. eg Harriss-White 2003 and Corbridge and Harriss (2000), CSDS 2007) Obviously elitist democratisation in Indonesia and the Philippines and its survival in India have thus been associated with de-politicisation of public affairs. But why was depoliticisation possible in the first place? The main answer seems to be the lack of a powerful alternative capable of mobilising a broader stratum of popular forces on a democratic platform. What are the roots of these weaknesses? The limits of ‘new politics’ In Indonesia the pro-democracy movement which was critically important in the process that finally incapacitated the Suharto regime and opened up for reformasi soon lost momentum and much of its potential significance, as already indicated, rather surviving as a congregation of watch dogs and lobby groups with only occasional influence. The movement had three major roots (e.g. Törnquist 1997; Lane 2008; Aspinall 2005). One strand was made up of the liberal and socialist oriented intellectuals, including student groups, who had been critical of the authoritarianism of Sukarno’s and PKI’s radical nationalism. Some even supported the military in 1965 before they later realised that Suharto’s coup involved mass killings, which they found abhorrent, and that the military, rather than the middle-class technocrats and intellectuals, would be at the helm. Another strand of the pro-democracy movement came from the non-communist trade unions and the civil society organisations that focussed on the farmers and urban poor. A third strand belonged to a new generation of civil society groups concerned with ‘alternative development’, often focusing on the environment or issues of human rights and corruption. These groups agreed among themselves that the authoritarian state was a major obstacle and that ‘civil society’ was the basis for any alternative. Class differences were not in the forefront and the new groups were neither based on extensive membership nor country-wide organisations outside the major cities, functioning rather as influential networks. The focus was on specific issues, rights, and problems. While there were occasional radical actions, a predominant worry was how to avoid provoking major repression. By the late 1980s leftist-oriented students tried to alter this cautious approach. They argued that any substantive improvement called for radical change. Democracy was 15 crucial for the transformation of Indonesia’s repressive and exploitative model of development. Such change, they said, called for political leadership and closer links between civil society groups, activists and ordinary people. The points were widely accepted but there was no agreement on how to implement them. While occasionally forming temporary coalitions, most groups kept to their own projects in opposing the regime. Moreover, the radical would-be political leaders made good use of the NGOs to win sympathisers, gain contacts and resources and build their own organisations. Thus the groups were suspicious of each others. Meanwhile other activists tried to reach out to ordinary people by relating to existing socio-religious organisations but, before the fall of Suharto, only rarely to separatist-cum-nationalist leaders in East Timor, Papua and Aceh in order to avoid accusations of betraying the country. It is correct to talk about a ‘democracy movement’ in the sense that groups agreed on the need for political change and democratisation but there was no ideological unity or nation-wide coordination, and almost no attempts at forming united fronts and parties. While important in undermining the legitimacy of the Suharto regime it stood for no coherent alternative. A major claim was that ‘civil society’ and the people themselves should run the country. The movement failed to develop and alternative transitional arrangement and snap elite-negotiated elections made activists to loose momentum. They became socially and politically marginalised. Why was it so difficult for the various fragments of the democracy movement to come together and form a genuine political alternative? The answer is simple: there was no strong reason for any of the actors involved to do so. This conclusion comes out clearly from the extensive studies of the democracy groups, both before and after Suharto (Budiman and Törnquist 2001, Prasetyo et.al. 2003, Priyono et.al. 2007, Samadhi and Warouw 2009) and also covered in country-wide surveys in 2003 and 2007. Typically, the pro-democrats only relate to sections of the population, rarely providing links between them. There were only few attempts, for instance, to link activities in workplaces, residential areas, and communities. Activists were engaged in specific localities, paying little attention to wider issues of governance, development, and public welfare. There was much focus on the rule of law, human rights, corruption, and civil control of the army, less on citizenship and almost nothing on representation and the capacity of governments to implement policies. Activists rarely tried to mobilise followers inside public administration and to engage in organised politics, nor were they present in public and private workplaces. Their main achievement was to collect and disseminate information, engaging in lobbying and pressure group activities and promoting self-management and self-help. The way they gained authority and legitimacy was primarily on the basis of their superior knowledge and their participation in the public discourse. This was at the expense of organising with a view of obtaining a public mandate or winning elections. In spite of some advances the activists remained poorly connected to social movements and popular 16 organisations (and vice versa). Collective action was mainly based on individual networking and alternative patronage as opposed to participation in broad and representative organisations. Parliaments and executive institutions were primarily approached through lobbying by NGOs and critique through the media. Given the issues that were given priority to, lobbying and media activism was simply a more effective strategy, at least in the short run, than to engage in building mass politics, viable political parties, or broad interest-based organisations. Those involved in these group activities or as individuals no doubt gained some important experience. As such it was a major achievement compared with the subordination suffered under Suharto when organised politics (except in the government party) was prohibited on the grassroots level in order to turn ordinary people into what the regime called a ‘floating mass’. After Suharto, however, the pro-democracy activists themselves were ‘floating’ by having failed to develop a solid social constituency. They were unable to generate substantial improvements in terms of popular control of public affairs on the basis of political equality. In many cases they even contributed to more privatisation and polycentrism. It was not clear what people (demos) would control what public affairs. In addition, the groups were often marginalised or co-opted by more powerful local actors within politics, administration and business, as well as by international organisations and donors. This was not unique for Indonesia. The pro-democrats had similar experiences in the Philippines. It is true that many of the CSOs were more closely attached to various political movements and parties, but only in some few and innovative cases to which we shall return did this point to ways of resolving the problem of fragmentation and only marginally the insufficiently broad and solid social base. Moreover, many Indian CSOs and social movements opted out of organised politics and especially the old Left parties, giving priority instead to pressure politics, judicial and media activism as well as lobbying. (C.f. Törnquist 2002) Neglected links Extensive research has been undertaken in cooperation with Indonesian pro-democracy activists who, in response to these problems, have tried to develop new ways of engaging in organised politics. Hence this chapter cannot be concluded before we have examined their experiences in supplementary view of the experiences from similar attempts in the Philippines and the Indian state of Kerala. How did these political innovators try to overcome both their own social and political marginalisation and powerful elite’s monopolisation of the political system? It is possible to identify eight trends or types of actually existing projects and experiences (Törnquist et.al 2009). (1) Communities for democracy The first was characterised by attempts at democratising popular communities such as customary (adat) groups, indigenous populations and Muslim congregations on the basis 17 of equal citizenship. This was meant to provide the foundations for alternative local governance and interventions in mainstream politics. Typically, however, a community would not claim equal citizenship rights for all people in the locality but for itself as a special community. It was also not clear what public affairs (such as what natural resources or citizen rights and obligations) that their community rather than people in general or several communities together would control and on what grounds. In this respect it is useful to recall the historical rise of the world renowned civil society in the Indian state of Kerala that was one of the pillars of its model for human development that formed the backbone of much of the thinking of the UNDP and Amartya Sen. The roots are in the struggle by socio religious reform movements in the 1900th century against India’s possibly stiffest cast system. On the one hand, in brief, the movements that called for special rights and support never did away with communitarianism in the public sphere and politics and still constitutes the backbone of conservative politics in Kerala. On the other hand the movements that organised along communitarian lines such as caste and religion but demanded equal citizenship rights including with regard to education and access to jobs in the public sector later on contributed to the Kerala model of making welfare an integrated part of economic development, and many of their demands were combined with the class struggle for land and better standard of living among peasants and workers. (Cf. Tharakan 1998) (2) Direct politics In the second kind of project, there was an effort to bypass ‘rotten politics’ by building a new model of ‘direct politics’ to develop media and public discourse, social auditing, struggle against corruption, and participatory budgeting. Yet again it was not clear what people would control what public affairs and how decisions were taken, who was represented, and to whom activists were accountable. While many issues were no doubt important, it seemed as if the most powerful and resourceful actors with best contacts tended to dominate. Similar strategies have been most common in the Philippines and India as well. This also tend to be the kind of practices in favour of popular demands for accountability that gain support from international organisations such as the UNDP as it fits into their programmes for ‘good governance’. Progressive actors in the Philippines have however tried to move ahead by relating the demands for accountability to political projects for more comprehensive democratic alternatives on the village (barangay) and municipality level. And in the Indian state of Kerala, as we shall return to, similar aspirations in relations to the panchayats on the village, block and district levels have been combined with political agreements with the mainstream leftist parties. (3) Union politics The third type of project that could be identified was that CSOs and labour leaders facilitated trade union based politics and parties. In some cases this was combined with community organising in neighbourhoods but also ethnic and religious groups. 18 Commonly, however, the differences between the unions, their leaders and other related communities were also scaled up, thus preventing broader joint work and linkages to other pro-democratic constituencies and wider popular issues. In the Philippines similar attempts were better combined with other movements such as among peasants and urban poor, but early party politicisation of the various groups and movements anyway prevented broader and more unified work. An opposite local attempt in Tarlac (Central Luzon) by the legendary founding father of the Maoist New Peoples Army (‘Dante’ Buscayno) who changed his priorities after the fall of Marcos in favour of building alternative local politics on the basis of class interests and solidarity among small farmers and their families also failed. This was partly because of the devastating volcanic eruption of Mt Pinatubo, but mainly because of much more diverging economic interests among the followers and insufficiently developed policies and politics. (Törnquist 2003) In Kerala by contrast there were no similar efforts as the established old Left and other parties already dominated and constrained the further development and unification among the many trade unions. (Törnquist with Tharakan 1996, Törnquist 2004) (4) Movement politics A similar fourth kind of project was the promotion by CSOs and related leaders of broader social movement based politics and parties. One such attempt was based on environmental groups, another on farmers’ and agricultural workers’ organisations. To counter the suspicion that the political activists would cater to their own interests, it was agreed that candidates in elections would come directly from the basic organisations. Most of these organisations, however, obviously deemed the political project to be too risky and expensive as compared to their usual practices of fostering clients’ and members’ interests as pressure and lobby groups. Moreover, the questions of how to develop and decide on joint platforms and priorities as well as to elect and keep candidates accountable were never really resolved. After several years of trial and error, some of the Philippine activists were more successful in these respects. While the dominant Maoists and a few other party-building groups proceeded with their own projects, dissidents with different leftist persuasions who agreed on the possibilities of advancing by way of democratic means and thus the need for various CSOs, interest based organisations such as unions and political organisations to not just be active outside but also within the framework of elections and parliamentary politics to build a broad political party. A major source of inspiration was the Brazilian labour party (PT), even if the trade unions that played such as crucial basic role in Brazil were less strong in the Philippines. Remarkably, in the mid-1990s, nongovernmental organisation campaigners, social movement activists, socialists, communists and former Maoists managed finally with what seemed to be impossible – to build a joint citizen action party which was called Akbayan. This was based on a very broad platform of joint visions and priorities rather than a closely worked out ideology 19 and strategy; and initially it allowed for both political groups and individuals to become members. Akbayan vitalised cooperation and managed to gain some representation in the parliament via a separate national so-called party list were groups and small parties could get a maximum of three seats each. But this was obviously not an avenue for broader representation; and aside from a few initiatives on the very village (barangay) level, Akbayan rarely managed to make a difference in the main elections of political executives such as mayors and of members to local councils and the national congress and senate in spite of attempts to coordinate activists and groups behind a few leading progressive politicians who tended to be members of mainstream political parties-cum-machines. (Törnquist 1993, 1998, 2002, Rocamora 2004, Quimpo 2004, Törnquist et.al. 2009) Meanwhile there were no similar attempts in Kerala as they would have been a threat against the existing leftist movements and parties. Most activists tried instead to reform and revitalise the Kerala model and its roots in CSOs and social movements combined with party politics for equal citizenship and state led welfare politics. The main strategy was to combine initiatives from below (and special attempts to include more women and marginalised groups such as among fisher folks and dalits) with political alliances in favour of participatory planning and democratic decentralisation. We shall return to this below. (5) Movement cooperation with parties and candidates The fifth project that stood out in Indonesia was characterised by groups which tried to make an impact by negotiating political contracts of co-operation with strong political actors who needed to broaden their alliances and support base beyond a predominant clientelist arrangements. The politicians engaged in programmes that attracted wider sections of the population that wished to see, for instance, less corrupt governance and better public welfare systems. In exchange for lending their good names and endorsing the politicians in elections, pro-democracy groups typically tried to sign a memorandum of understanding with the politicians to thus increase the capacity of wider sections of the population. Many of the actual arrangements were however only statements of intentions and limited to rather narrow issues. Furthermore, most civil and popular actors lacked sufficient bargaining power to enforce the deals. They were typically unable to deliver a substantial number of votes, and lacked an organisation that was able to keep successful politicians accountable after the elections. Generally speaking there were analogous problems in the Philippines. In addition the more activist- than local governance oriented leaders also tried agreements with crucial politicians, civil society personalities, business people and at times dissident officers. Such agreements were related, for instance, to additional attempts at new people power demonstrations against the abusive of power. Typically, however, there were problems of combining these extra-parliamentary actions with the efforts at building alternative social movement based politics from below and in relation to demands for 20 more democracy as a means to combine social welfare and economic development. (Quimpo 2004 and Törnquist et.al. 2009) (5 ½ ) The Kerala combination The main innovative efforts that gained widespread international reputation evolved however in Kerala during the 1980s, 1990s and early 2000. This was a particularly exciting combination of social movements based politics and political contracts in favour of what may be called supplementary democracy and which call for a somewhat more elaborated review already at this stage. In the mid 1980s concerned scholars, school teachers and professionals, most of whom were also political and civil society activists, became increasingly disturbed by the problems of sustaining Kerala’s world reputed model of human development that was mentioned earlier. This had been a crucial source of inspiration for actors such as the UNDP and scholars like Amartya Sen. Now it was getting unviable. (Törnquist with Tharakan 1996, Tharakan 1998, Isaac with Franke 2000) Contextually there were three major historical factors behind the model. The first was the promotion in the 19th and early 20th century of commercial agriculture by semiautonomous princely states in the southern part of today’s Kerala. The second was that some of the extensive socio-religious reform movements which fought the rigid caste system had as already indicated supported cultural pluralism in addition to demanding equal citizen rights and state support rather than special privileges for specific communities. In this way they initiated Kerala’s remarkable combination of an extensive civil society and public welfare policies. The third was the class based agrarian reform movement which grew strong in the 1930s. This was led by socialists and communists who combined it with demands for homestead plots to the agricultural workers, a multitude of profession-based trade unions, educational groups and credit cooperatives. Later on this became the backbone of the leftist political fronts which won several of the elections after the inception of the state of Kerala in 1956. But by 1980s production stagnated, in-spite of the land reforms and more. The leftist parties had failed to foster a new social pact that could combine welfare reforms and growth. Rather they had become increasingly dependent on supporting their powerful party-related interest groups and unions. In addition they relied on centralist governance of both their parties and the state as well as on environmentally unsustainable projects to generate cheap energy for Kerala’s few modern industries and ever increasing and consumerist middle classes (which benefitted from extensive migrant labour remittances). Meanwhile vulnerable people (such as among the most subordinated castes, tribal populations and fisher folk) who had not benefitted from the reforms tended to rely on community support and rarely supported the left. By contrast to Indonesia however, the extensive mass based parties, popular movements and organisations and citizen groups had not been eliminated. Hence, most of 21 the dissident scholars and activists did not turn their back to organised politics. To foster change, however, the reformists could not just work from inside the existing parties and organisations (of which many of them were anyway rather frustrated) but developed a people science association into an educational mass movement (KSSP) of knowledgeable and innovative reform facilitators. This movement initiated a number of campaigns related to education and literacy, mapping of local resources and cooperation among farmers. The main aim was to show how popular participation for community based welfare- and development policies (by contrast to special interest driven policies) could reform and thus reinvigorate the Kerala model in a sustainable way. Initially the advocates in Kerala of the supplementary democracy perspective were very successful. Temporarily they even gained hegemony in fostering democratic decentralisation combined with a full range of the kind of supplementary channels of democratic popular influence that were instrumental in promoting inclusive development agendas on the local level. The initiatives were even broader than the participatory budgeting practices in Brazil. Yet there were also a number of serious challenges. (Törnquist with Tharakan 1996, Törnquist 2004, Tharakan 2004, Törnquist et.al 2009, Isaac with Franke 2000, Heller 2005, 2007) The primary one was to combine the new channels of participation with the established system of interest based representation and the elected institutions of local government – all of which was also affected by the fact that Kerala was modernised in the context of case and religious based reform movements. The contradictions between the established liberal democratic system and the new forms of participation and representation were a problem of democratic principles as well as of power. In the Brazilian case, mainstream political representation as well as interest and community groups were severely delegitimised by being elitist and clientelist while the new workers party that initiated the participatory budgeting was seen as a fresh new comber. In Kerala the established system of representation had indeed deteriorated but was still channelling the most powerful interests and popular aspirations. Actually, most major leftist leaders and parties were very much rooted in the old system too. So when the reformists initiated new channels of democratic popular influence by way of top level support for decentralisation and popular participation, this was seen as a threat by a wide array of established politicians, interest organisations (e.g. among labour, farmers, employers special casts and religious communities) as well as central level bureaucrats, linedepartments and connected contractors. Moreover, this was not just a question about central versus local but also between vested interests in different channels of influence, including on the very local level. So when the new planning and participation proceeded beyond discussion to the altering of power relations and distribution of funds, conflicts increased, accusations ran wild and compromises and accommodation of various interests became inevitable. This made implementation quite difficult, even to the extent that the participatory new channels of influence could rarely be utilised to hold back special 22 political and other interests and to contain abuse and corruption. Hence it is remarkable that the reformists who wanted to foster more democratic space for ordinary people that were marginalised or critical of the special interests anyway never paid serious attention to how it would be possible in theory and practice to combine conventional democratic representation and interest-group influence, on the one hand, with new and additional channels of more direct participation, on the other hand. (And at the time of writing it is obvious that the issue remains unresolved even at the national level, given the current conflict over the authority of elected but often corrupt politicians versus self appointed anti-corruption campaigners.) Another major challenge was the focus on targeting the poor in the decentralised planning of various development and welfare measures. On the one hand it was a priority that all people in need of support should be considered on an equal basis irrespective of political or other affiliations, in addition to special support for women’s concerns. And in principle this was applauded by so many people who were frustrated with the special privileges to well connected persons and were sympathetic to more universal and impartial practices. On the other hand however, the targeting of the poor also meant that the huge numbers of less vulnerable people and not least the resourceful and entrepreneurial middle classes felt that there was very little for them in the decentralised participatory planning; and hence they rarely engaged. A third stumbling block was the lack of a viable strategy for linking the democratic practices and welfare measures to a strategy for economic growth. The most fundamental reason for the decentralisation and participatory planning was that the Kerala model of human development had been undermined by economic stagnation. Yet the new efforts never managed to foster growth coalitions that acknowledged and even benefitted from welfare measures. (C.f. e.g. George 1993 and 2011) Decentralisation and participatory planning had insignificant effect on production and employment. One apparent reason was that this would have called for politically uncomfortable exposure of petty rent-seeking among some of the supporters of the leftist parties themselves as well as for much more priority to production oriented measures in the development planning than to separate welfare measures that might attract specific voters. A final major challenge was that most of the reformists tried to stay out of organised ‘dirty’ politics without forming any alternative vehicle, thus being easy to silence and marginalise. When the old communist patriarch E.M.S Namboodiripad passed away in 1998 it was even possible for conservative communist critics to suggest that those who subscribed to his long standing ideas of decentralisation and reduction of the party-politicisation of interest organisations in favour of development priorities were actually influenced instead by the World Bank and neo-liberalism. Likewise, conventional politicians were fielded as candidates is that in face of the local and state elections in 2000 and 2001 respectively even in constituencies where reformists (including several women) had gained positive reputation. Ironically thus, the left 23 oriented parties did not just make a poor election in the state at large but also lost where decentralisation and participation had been quite successful. Meanwhile the conservative communists gained the upper hand in various ideological and factional struggles inside the parties. And this in turn implied that many of the civil society activists who were not very active or even formally enrolled in any of the parties lost influence and confidence in the concerted efforts and campaigns, no matter whether they were expelled or branded as next to traitors by the conservative party leaders. It is true that decentralisation had survived when the left parties got back in power in 2006 and that several leaders now said that they would support a second phase of participatory planning. But critical public discussion and evaluation remained secluded and most of the political and popular momentum to use decentralisation to foster local democratisation and to combine welfare and growth was no more. (6) Advancing from within the mainstream The sixth project was to build political fronts from within an already powerful party or movement (or to take over the weak local chapters of such parties), turning them into instruments of change. The problems, however, included the risk of being co-opted and the uphill task of building strength enough to advance when being unable to build fractions inside the party or movement. This strategy was avoided in Kerala as any factionalism within especially the main leftist party the Communist Party of India-Marxist (CPI-M) would have been counterproductive. Yet of course leading reformists were active also within this and other parties and their political clout rested primarily with their supreme knowledge, expertise and links to external movements and efforts. Over the years this proved to be a difficult balancing act. The activists who primarily were based in non-party led movement were rarely entrusted as candidates in elections, some of them were even expelled and many were thus disappointed and became less interested in organised party politics. A number of researchers have argued that the remarkable people’s planning campaign in Kerala rested almost entirely with the political power of the leftist parties. But if fact one may well argue instead that much of the successful parts of the Kerala experience were inspite of rather than thanks to the political support of the CPI-M in particular. As already indicated some leading leftist politicians did indeed support the efforts, especially in its initial stages. But the major parts of the CPI-M as well as other leftist parties and their related interest associations were quite hesitant to the introduction of decentralisation and supplementary institutions and practices of participatory democracy; after 2001 some of them denounced the efforts as revisionist. It may also be added that when the CPI-M leaders for a brief period of time in 1999 and 2000 did came out in defence of the efforts it was mainly to stand up against the critique by competing leftist parties and even caused some CPI-M cadres to try to dominate the new institutions, thus at times causing more harm than providing support. (Törnquist with Tharakan 1996) 24 In the Philippines by contrast the work from within was embraced by rather many activists who wanted to go beyond agreements and alliances. The paradigmatic case was the efforts by rethinking former Maoists campaigners to frame and run the presidential campaign of nationalist oriented senator-cum-film actor Estrada in such a successful way that they would gain influential seats in his administration. Initially this proved successful but ended up in next to a catastrophe as Estrada himself and quite other ‘advisors’ got the upper hand and the President was discharged for having abused his powers. (7) Local parties and candidates The seventh type of project was to fight for the legalising of local parties and independent candidates in elections. This project was mainly developed and also proved to be successful in the autonomous war-thorn and tsunami affected province of Aceh. Remarkably, these leaders and activists even managed to build an alliance and to win the 2006 elections of local executives, in spite of resistance from semi-aristocratic GAM leaders in exile and mainstream Indonesian politicians. Thus it was possible to project the new institutions as a model for the country at large as well as for other conflict areas. The advances, however, were rapidly undermined. The international community were busy with the post-tsunami reconstruction work without making much effort to also employ the massive programmes in attempts at better governance in Aceh. This helped making it possible for the semi-aristocratic leaders and local strongmen with access to the command structure of the rebel movement to become dominant, to develop powersharing agreements with former enemies and to do away with their utmost to marginalise the reformists. Moreover, the reformists themselves were not very successful in using the positions that they had gained in the elections to foster interest based representation and initiate alternative development. Hence most actors turned instead to lobbying, clientelism, and corruption in their efforts to retain their positions. (Törnquist et.al. 2011) In the Philippines, one of the major similar strategies was to draw on the political influence and legitimacy of CSOs and social movements to initiate local political coalitions and to launch more or less independent candidates in cooperation with supposedly progressive mainstream actors. This proved possible at times on the very local level but very difficult to scale up within the framework of a non-proportional electoral system where votes counts quite fraudulently and where bossism, resources and fame decide. Moreover, extra parliamentary campaigns often gained more attention as they seem to offer more immediate gains. (Törnquist et.al. 2009) By contrast however, the Kerala activists never tried to form local parties or to go for independent candidates, preferring instead various forms of cooperation with the mainstream left of centre parties and to provide space for direct or CSO- and movement based participation in local government, especially with regard to development planning. 25 (8) A principled party of once own The final major project in Indonesia was to build a national ideology-driven party to provide political guidance and coordination to the CSOs and the social movements. Firstly, however, there were simply no strong and broad popular movements. Secondly, the would-be leaders were better read into radical literature than capable of serving as the representatives of the movements that nevertheless existed, There were no similar attempts by the pro-democrats in Kerala, only among some Maoist inspired groups. Ideology was not negated by the rethinking Left but centralist enactment was. The radical leftist Philippine democrats argued similarly but had given up on the mainstream radical parties as well as on the capacity of any of the hard-core alternatives. Hence they opted instead, as we have seen, for the building of a rainbow party without a clear cut ideology. In this party various political tendencies could cooperate and combine their work with individuals from various CSOs and movements. This fostered much joint work and innovative thinking and was hardly a problem as such. The problem of less than expected political outcomes was rather related to the unfavourable opportunities and political priorities that have been pointed to above. . Possible openings in comparative perspective The projects that have been identified above usually reflected existing priorities and organisational practices among the pro-democrats. Their aims were modified, but not their politics. With partial exceptions in Kerala and the Philippines, their main focus was still on issues of immediate concern for their own movement rather than on interests of wider concern that would have called for broad alliances and mass politics. Moreover, when anyway trying to cooperate, they had problems of poor political representation, both within the groups and organisations themselves and in relation to political parties, parliaments and state institutions. To discuss possible ways ahead, these specific problems (as opposed to general models or projects) need to be analysed in comparative theoretical perspective. Why, for instance, have similar dilemmas been less important and tackled more successfully in, for instance, the paradigmatic historical cases of Scandinavia? (Cf. Törnquist 2011, Törnquist and Stokke 2012) Tentative studies indicate that the Scandinavian actors related to similar challenges by engaging in three levels of intermediary and transformative politics. Firstly, parties and their policies were directed by popular movements which realised that they had to engage collectively in organised politics to further some of their most vital issues; and in doing this they deliberated and coordinated their actions and demands in so-called labour communes. Second, one basic demand was joint institutionalised participation in relevant sectors of public governance (so called plural or social corporatism). This was in addition to typical liberal democratic and civil society based lobbying and pressure politics in the 26 workplaces. And there were also crucial transformative outcomes: that popular representation in sectoral public policy development and implementation facilitated stronger and unified popular organisations which could take part in it as well as control and thus also trust in public institutions. Third, the popular movements and interest organisations soon opted for demanding social, welfare and labour market reforms that would be to the benefit of all affected people and not just their own members through state policies rather than via their own organisations and self-help civil society groups. The price for this was weaker popular organisations but the benefit was that the popular movements themselves were able to contain ‘special interests’ in favour of the ‘common good’, to gain support from popular majorities, and to not just include workers but also the unemployed, peasants, small business actors and civil servants. One lesson is thus that transformative democratic politics can not just be built from below. There is a need for enlightened leadership to foster labour communes for the deliberation and coordination of the demands and actions of popular movement based parties and other political organisations. Sectoral interest based representation (social corporatism) strengthened broad and unified popular organisations, contained abuse of public resources and fostered trust in public institutions. Demands for universal social security and other public policies as well as social pacts by way of state policies and facilitation fostered even stronger organisations as well as welfare based economic growth. Such nodes for improvements may be given priority to and gain special support in international cooperation between actors that are interested in transformative democratic politics. Conclusion The ‘old’ left in Indonesia but also the Philippines and partly in India too failed by not making democratisation an integral part in the struggle to control primitive accumulation and the rise of capital. Although the new Indonesian generation gave priority to democratisation against Suharto, it focused on rights that did not call for popular representation in a context of mass based politics for social and economic welfare and growth. It was assumed that by establishing a liberal political space and a well entrenched culture of civil rights the necessary preconditions would be provided for class-related mass politics. Even after 1998, when much of this ‘space’ was at hand, there were, however, no sustained attempts to connect the two and influence the direction of democratic politics. Several socially and politically marginalised democracy groups have recently tried to go more ‘political’, but their politics still reflect old priorities and organisational practices. Thus the problems of democratic representation in the relations between the groups themselves as well as in their links to organised politics and the state remain unresolved. There are no major attempts to combine the focus on civil rights with 27 questions of social and economic welfare and growth that call for mass politics, viable political parties, or broad interest-based organisations. Similar problems have been important in the different contexts of the Philippines and the Indian state of Kerala too even if the conditions vary and even though there have been more advanced and pioneering attempts to move ahead here. This indicates that the problems are more about politics than structure. Meanwhile, the weaknesses of the Indonesian pro-democracy movements have provided space for a pattern of elite-based, shallow democratisation. And unfortunately this holds true for the Philippines and the deterioration of the Kerala model and politics too. At best shallow and elitist democracy can contain demands for the restoration of ‘politics of order’, but it is potentially unstable and incapable of fostering genuine representation, welfare-based growth, and fighting corruption. When these problems in the democracy movement are analysed in comparative theoretical perspective such as with reference to the historical Scandinavian experiences, it is clear that the challenges can not only be solved on the grassroots level among the organisations and movements themselves. To a large extent there is also a need for enlightened demands from below for transformative politics from above such as for sectoral interest based representation and universal public welfare policies which may both facilitate broader popular organising as well as social pacts on economic growth. References Anderson, B (1988). ‘Cacique Democracy in the Philippines: Origins and Dreams’, New Left Review No 169, May-June Aspinall, E. (2005), Opposing Suharto: Compromise, Resistance, and Regime Change in Indonesia Stanford: Stanford University Press,. – (2010), ‘The Irony of Success’, Journal of Democracy, Vol. 21:2, April. Beetham, D. (1999). Democracy and Human Rights. Oxford: Polity Press. Bourchier, D. and Legge J. (Eds.) (1994). Democracy in Indonesia. 1950s and 1990s. Clayton: Monash Asia Institute. Budiman, A, and Törnquist, O. (2001), Aktor Demokrasi: Catatan Tentang Gerakan Perlawanan di Indonesia, Jakarta: ISAI. Chatterjee, P. (2008). ‘Democracy and Economic Transformation’, in Economic and Political Weekly, April 19. Corbridge, S. and Harriss, J. (2000). Reinventing India: Liberalization, Hindu Nationalism and Popular Democracy. Cambridge: Polity Press. Crouch, H. (1994). ‘Democratic Prospects in Indonesia’, in Bourchier, D. and Legge J. (Eds.) (1994). Democracy in Indonesia. 1950s and 1990s. Clayton: Monash Asia Institute CSDS (2007). Centre for the Study of Developing Societies, State of Democracy in South Asia, New Delhi: Oxford University Press Ford, M. (2009). Workers and intellectuals: NGOs, trade unions and the Indonesian labour movement. Singapore and Honolulu: National University of Singapore and University of Hawaii Press. George, K. K. (1993). Limits to Kerala model of development: An analysis of fiscal crisis and its implications. Thiruvananthapuram: Centre for Development Studies. George, K.K. (2011). Kerala economy: Growth, structure, strength and weakness. Working paper no. 25, Centre for Socio-economic & Environmental Studies (CSES), Kochi, India 28 Harriss-White, B. (2003). India Working: Essays on Society and Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Heller, P. (2005). ‘Reinventing public power in the age of globalization: The transformation of movement politics in Kerala’ in R. Ray and M. Katzenstein (eds.) Social movements in India: Poverty, power and politics. New York: Rowman and Littlefield. Heller, P., Harilal, K. N., and Chaudhuri, S. (2007). ‘Building local democracy: Evaluating the impact of decentralization in Kerala, India.’ World Development 35(4). Huntington, S. (1965). “Political development and political decay”, World Politics, 17, 3. Isaac, T. M . T. with Franke, R . W. (2000). Local democracy and development. People’s campaign for decentralized planning in Kerala. Delhi: Left Word Books. Lane, M. (2008). Unfinished Nation: Indonesia before and after Suharto, London and New York: Verso. – (2010). Catastrophe in Indonesia, London, New York and Calcutta: Seagull. Mansfield, E.D. and Snyder, J. (2007). ‘The sequencing “fallacy”’. Journal of Democracy, 18(3): 5-9. van Klinken, G. (2007). Communal violence and democratization in Indonesia: Small town wars. London: Routledge. Klinken, van, G. (2009). ‘Patronage democracy in provincial Indonesia’, in Törnquist, O, Webster, N, and K. Stokke, (eds.) (2009). Rethinking popular representation. New York: Palgrave. Nordholt, H.S. (2004). ‘Decentralisation in Indonesia: Less State, More Democracy?’ in Harriss, J, Stokke, K, and Törnquist, O (eds.) Politicising democracy. The new local politics of democratisation, Houndmills, Basingstoke: Palgrave, Nordholt, H. S. and van Klinken, G. (eds.) ( 2007). Renegotiating Boundaries: Local Politics in Post-Suharto Indonesia. Leiden: KITLV Press. Prasetyo, A. S., Priyono, A.E. and Törnquist, O. with Birks, T. (Eds.) (2003). Indonesia’s Post-Suharto Democracy Movement. Jakarta and Copenhagen: Demos and NIAS. Priyono, A.E, Samadhi, W.P. and Törnquist, O. with Birks, T. (2007). Making Democracy Meaningful. Problems and Options in Indonesia. Jakarta and Singapore: Demos and ISEAS Quimpo, N. (2004). Contested democracy and the left in the Philippines after Marcos. Canberra: Australian National University. Robison, R. (1996). The Middle Class and the Bourgeoisie in Indonesia‟ in Robison R. (Ed.) The New Rich in Asia: Mobile Phones, McDonalds and Middle-Class Revolution. London: Routledge. Robison, R. and Hadiz, V.R. (2004). Reorganising Power in Indonesia: the Politics of Oligarchy in an Age of Markets. London: Routledge Curzon. Rocamora, J. (2004). ‘More than difficult, short of impossible: Party building and local governance in the Philippines’ in Harriss, J, Stokke, K and Törnquist, O.(eds.) Politicising democracy. The new local politics of democratisation. Houndmills: Palgrave. Roosa, J ( 2006).Pretext for mass murder. The September 30th Movement and Suharto’s coup d’etat in Indonesia, Wisconsin: The University of Wisconsin Press. Samadhi, W. P. and Warouw, N. (Eds.) (2009). Building Democracy on the Sand. Advances and Setbacks in Indonesia. Jakarta, Jogjakarta and Singapore; Demos, PCD Press, ISEAS (2nd edition 2009). Sanyal, K. K. (2007). Rethinking capitalist development: primitive accumulation, governmentality and post-colonial capitalism. Routledge Sidel, J. T. (1999). Capital, coercion, and crime: Bossism in the Philippines. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Sidel, J.T. (2004) ‘Bossism and democracy in the Philippines, Thailand and Indonesia: Towards an alternative framework for the study of “local strongmen”’ in Harriss, J, Stokke, K, and Törnquist, O. (eds.) Politicising democracy. The new local politics of democratisation. Houndmills: Palgrave Tharakan, P . K . M ( 1998). ‘Socio-religious reform movements, process of democratization and human development: The case of Kerala, South-West India’ in Rudebek, L. and Törnquist, O. with Rojas, V. 29 (eds.) Democratisation in the Third World: Concrete cases in comparative and theoretical perspective. London: Macmillan and St. Martin’s Press. Tharakan, P. K . M (2004). ‘Historical hurdles in the course of the people’s planning campaign in Kerala’ in Harriss,J, Stokke, K and Törnquist, O.(eds.) Politicising democracy. The new local politics of democratisation. Houndmills: Palgrave. Törnquist, O. (1984). Dilemmas of Third World Communism. The Destruction of the PKI in Indonesia. London, Zed Books, 1984. (First published in Swedish 1982.) – (1984a). Struggle for Democracy - a New Option in Indonesia? Uppsala: Uppsala University, The Akutseries no. 33. – (1989).What’s Wrong with Marxism? Vol 1: On Capitalists and State in India and Indonesia, New Delhi: Manohar. – (1991). What’s Wrong with Marxism? Vol 2: On Peasants and Workers in India and Indonesia, New Delhi: Manohar. – (1991a). ‘Communists and democracy in the Philippines’. in Economic and Political Weekly, 6–13 July, 20 July. – (1993). ‘Democratic “empowerment” and democratisation of politics: radical popular movements and the May 1992 elections in the Philippines’, Third World Quarterly, 14(3) – (1996) From New to Human Order in Indonesia? in NIAS nytt , no. 3, October 1996 and Economic and Political Weekly, October 5, 1996, and (in briefer Swedish version) in Svenska Dagbladet med titeln “Den enda vägen är den smala vägen”, September 22, 1996. – (1997). ‘Civil Society and Divisive Politicisation: Experiences from Popular Efforts at Democratisation in Indonesia, in Özdalga, E.; Persson, S. (Ed.): Civil Society, Democracy and the Muslim World, Istanbul: Swedish Research Institute & Curzon Press. – (1998). ‘Popular Politics of Democratisation: Philippine Cases in Comparative and Theoretical Perspective’, in Mohanty, M. and Mukherji, P.N. with Törnquist, O (eds.), People’s Rights: Social Movements and the State in the Third World, Delhi: Sage. – (2000). ‘Dynamics of the Indonesian Democratisation’, Third World Quarterly, Vol. 21, No. 3; also in Economic and Political Weekly, April 29. – (2002). Popular development and democracy: Case studies with rural dimensions in the Philippines, Indonesia and Kerala. Geneva and Oslo: UNRISD and SUM. – (2004) Labour and democracy: reflections on the Indonesian impasse, Journal of Contemporary Asia, Vol. 34:3. – (2004). ‘ The political deficit of substantial democratisation’ in Harriss, J, Stokke, K and Törnquist, O. (eds.) Politicising democracy. The new local politics of democratisation. Houndmills: Palgrave. – (2009). ‘The Problem is Representation! Towards an Analytical Framework’ in Törnquist, O., Webster. N., and Stokke, K. Rethinking Popular Representation, New York: Palgrave. – (2011). ‘Is social democracy being undermined?’ in Economic & Political Weekly April 9, vol xlvi no. 15. – (2012 forthcoming). Assessing democratisation: A critical handbook. Scaling up Indonesian experiences in comparative perspective. Törnquist, O. with Tharakan, P. K. M. (1996). ‘Democratisation and the radical political project in Kerala.’ Economic and Political Weekly 31(28, 29, 30) Törnquist, O, Prasetyo S.A, and Birks T, (eds.) (2011). Aceh: The role of democracy for peace and reconstruction, 2nd ed. Yogyakarta and Singapore: PCD Press with ISEAS (2nd edition with update) Törnquist, O, Tharakan, P.K.M. (with Chathukulam, J.), and Quimpo, N. (2009). ‘Popular politics of representation: New lessons from the pioneering projects in Indonesia, Kerala, and the Philippines’, in Törnquist, O., Webster. N., and Stokke, K. Rethinking Popular Representation, New York: Palgrave. Törnquist, O and Stokke, K (2012). ‘On Transformative Politics’, in Stokke, K and Törnquist, O (eds) Democratisation in the global South: The importance of transformative politics, Houndmills: Palgrave (forthcoming). 30
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz