Advokatfirman Delphi Sweden Sweden Elisabeth Legnerfält and Helene Andersson Advokatfirman Delphi Antitrust law Legal objective 1 What are the legal sources that set out the antitrust law applicable to 3 Is the only objective pursued by the law on vertical restraints vertical restraints? economic, or does it also seek to protect other interests? The national competition legislation applicable in Sweden is the Competition Act (2008:579) (the Act). The primary provisions applicable are chapter 2, section 1 (the national equivalent to article 81(1) EC) and chapter 2, section 2 (the national equivalent to article 81(3) EC). EC Regulation 1/2003 provides that the Swedish Competition Authority, and the Swedish courts must apply article 81 of the EC Treaty when the prohibition on anti-competitive agreements is applied to agreements which may affect trade between member states. There is a Swedish block exemption, the Act (2008:581) on block exemption for anti-competitive vertical agreements which refers back to Regulation 2790/1999. When a party holds a dominant position on a market to which the vertical agreement relates, chapter 2, section 7 of the Act or article 82 EC will also be relevant to the antitrust assessment of a given agreement in order to determine whether there is abuse of a dominant position. However, conduct falling within the article 82 prohibition is considered in Getting the Deal Through – Dominance and is therefore not covered here. Further guidance on assessment of vertical restraints in Sweden is found in case law from the Stockholm District Court and the Swedish Market Court as well as decisions from the Competition Authority. The aim of the Competition Act (chapter 1, section 1) is to eliminate and counteract obstacles to effective competition in the field of production of and trade in goods, services and other products, meaning that there is a consumer protection perspective. Types of vertical restraint Jurisdiction 2 List and describe the types of vertical restraints that are subject to 5 What is the test for determining whether a vertical restraint will antitrust law. Is the concept of vertical restraint defined in the antitrust law? According to chapter 2, section 1 of the Act, agreements between undertakings shall be prohibited if they have as their object or effect to prevent, restrict or distort competition in the market to an appreciable extent. Vertical agreements are defined in section 1 of the Swedish Block Exemption as agreements entered into between two or several undertakings which, within the framework of the agreement, are active at different levels in the production or distribution chain and which regulates the conditions for the parties’ purchase, sales or resale of certain goods or services. Vertical restrains are defined (section 2) as vertical agreements containing restraints on competition. Vertical agreements that may be subject to competition rules include distribution, franchise, purchase, licensing and subcontractor agreements. www.gettingthedealthrough.com Responsible agencies 4 What agency is responsible for enforcing prohibitions on anticompetitive vertical restraints? Where there are multiple responsible agencies, how are cases allocated? Do governments or ministers have a role? The competition authorities in Sweden are the Competition Authority, the Stockholm District Court and as last instance, the Market Court. The Competition Authority may issue prohibitive orders but may not impose fines. In order to impose fines the Competition Authority must petition the Stockholm District Court. The judgment of the Stockholm District Court may be appealed to the Market Court as last instance. Leave for appeal is required. The government and the ministers do not have a role in the enforcement of the competition rules but only in the legislative process. be subject to antitrust law in your jurisdiction? Has the law in your jurisdiction regarding vertical restraints been applied extraterritorially? The prohibition on anti-competitive agreements in chapter 2, section 1 of the Act applies where an agreement has an effect on trade within Sweden. Where an agreement also has an effect on trade between EU member states, the Competition Authority and Swedish courts must apply article 81 concurrently. In addition there needs to be impact or enforcement of the vertical restraint in the Swedish territory to an appreciable extent. There is so far no case law on extraterritorial application of Swedish competition law to vertical restraints. Agreements concluded by public entities 6 To what extent does antitrust law apply to vertical restraints in agreements concluded by public entities? The prohibition on anti-competitive agreements in chapter 2, section 1 of the Act applies to ‘undertakings’. The term ‘undertaking’ can cover any kind of entity, regardless of its legal status or the way in which it is financed, provided such entity is engaged in an ‘economic 259 Sweden activity’ when carrying out the activity in question. Thus, public entities may qualify as undertakings when carrying out certain of their more commercial functions. It is, however, provided that public undertakings are not considered as undertakings when fulfilling their public tasks; see chapter 1, section 5 of the Act. Sector-specific rules 7 Do particular laws or regulations apply to the assessment of vertical restraints in specific sectors of industry? Please identify the rules and the sectors they cover. There is a specific block exemption relating to vertical agreements in the motor vehicle sector (the Act (2008:584)). This block exemption does not contain any material differences as compared with the corresponding EC block exemption (1400/2002). Other industry-specific block exemption regulations exist but none of these is targeted specifically at vertical restraints. General exceptions 8 Are there any general exceptions from antitrust law for certain types of vertical restraints? If so, please describe. The Competition Authority has issued guidelines on agreements of minor importance that are not covered by the prohibition in chapter 2, section 1 of the Act (KKVFS 2009:1) where the concept of appreciable extent under Swedish competition law is defined. The guidelines refer to the de minimis rules laid down by the European Commission. For further information on the Swedish guidelines, see question 13. Agreements 9 Is there a definition of ‘agreement’ – or its equivalent – in the antitrust law of your jurisdiction? When assessing vertical restraints under antitrust law does the agency take into account that some agreements may form part of a larger, interrelated network of agreements or is each agreement assessed in isolation? There is no definition of agreement in the legislation, but EC case law on the definition of agreement applies. Parent and related-company agreements 10 In what circumstances do the vertical restraints rules apply to agreements between a parent company and a related company (or between related companies of the same parent company)? The principle on economic entity is applicable in accordance with EC case law, and thus intra-group transactions are as a general rule not subject to the competition rules. The decisive factor is the parent company’s level of control over its subsidiary. If the parent company has such control over the subsidiary that it is not able to act independently the principle on economic entity applies. However, if the subsidiary is able to act independently, the competition rules apply. Agent–principal agreements 11 In what circumstances does antitrust law apply to agent–principal agreements in which an undertaking agrees to perform certain services on a supplier’s behalf for a commission payment? In general, the prohibition in chapter 2, section 1 of the Competition Act will not apply to any agreement between a ‘principal’ and its ‘genuine agent’ (ie, one who bears no substantial financial risk in respect of the transactions in which it acts as agent) insofar as the agreement relates to contracts negotiated or concluded by the agent for its principal. In this regard, the application of the prohibition mirrors that of article 81 (see EU chapter). 260 Advokatfirman Delphi Intellectual property rights 12 Is antitrust law applied differently when the agreement containing the vertical restraint also contains provisions granting intellectual property rights (IPRs)? The Swedish Block Exemption refers to the EC Vertical Block Exemption, providing that agreements which have as their ‘centre of gravity’ the licensing of IPRs will fall outside the Vertical Block Exemption. In such cases, the antitrust analysis is different. The relevant considerations include the application of the European Commission’s Technology Transfer Block Exemption (Regulation 772/2004). Analytical framework for assessment 13 Explain the analytical framework that applies when assessing vertical restraints under antitrust law. A vertical agreement must be assessed in its legal and economic context. It is thereby assessed whether it is aimed at, or will result in, an appreciable prevention, restriction or distortion of competition on the Swedish market or a substantial part of it. Both intrabrand and inter-brand competition is taken into consideration and the agreement is assessed from a short-term as well as a long-term perspective. In case there is a restriction on competition it is thereafter assessed whether the agreement is covered by the Swedish Block Exemption. The Swedish Block Exemption applies if the supplier does not have a market share exceeding 30 per cent on the relevant market (if it is question of an exclusive supply agreement the market share of the buyer is instead considered) and provided that the agreement does not contain any hard-core restrictions. If the agreement is covered by the Swedish Block Exemption, it is automatically exempted from the prohibition in chapter 2, section 1 of the Act and no further assessment is required. If the agreement is not covered by the Swedish Block Exemption it is assessed whether the exemption regarding agreements of minor importance (KKVFS 2009:1) is applicable to the agreement. This is in particular of relevance in relation to non-compete obligations exceeding five years or of an interminable duration, which are allowed for under the de minimis rules. These rules apply if neither party has a market share above 15 per cent, provided that the agreement does not contain any hard-core restrictions. The hard-core restrictions are the same as under the EC de minims notice. If neither the Swedish Block Exemption nor the de minimis rules are applicable the agreement or the clause is not per se illegal but it must be assessed whether the vertical restraint is in breach of chapter 2, section 1 of the Act. Chapter 2, section 1 of the Act, which corresponds to article 81(1) EC, provides that agreements between undertakings shall be prohibited if they have as their object or effect, to prevent, restrict or distort competition in the market to an appreciable extent. Even if a vertical agreement is considered to fall under the prohibition in chapter 2, section 1 of the Act, it may be exempted according to the ‘legal exemption’ in chapter 2, section 2 of the Act, which corresponds to article 81(3) EC. Chapter 2, section 2 of the Act may be considered as a kind of rule of reason, ie, a balancing between the positive and the negative effects of a restrictive agreement. The economic advantages of the agreement must objectively outweigh the negative effects on competition in order for the exemption to apply. It is the undertakings concerned that must prove that the conditions for exemption are fulfilled. In case the supplier or the buyer under the agreement may be considered to hold a dominant position an assessment has to be Getting the Deal Through – Vertical Agreements 2009 Advokatfirman Delphi Sweden made whether the dominant party acts in breach of the prohibition in chapter 2, section 7 of the Act, which prohibits abuse of dominant position, see Getting the Deal Through - Dominance. 14 To what extent does the agency consider market shares, market structures and other economic factors when assessing the legality of individual restraints? Does it consider the market positions and conduct of other suppliers and buyers in its analysis? The following circumstances are taken into consideration in the assessment of vertical agreements: •market shares and market influence of the relevant undertakings, also over time; •market shares and market influence by competitors, also over time; •structure of the market (eg concentration) and the maturity of the market; •the occurrence of entry barriers including similar cooperations (network effect) and brand loyalty; •characteristics of the products, extent of the cooperation and levels of the distribution chain; and •duration of the relevant vertical restraint. Block exemption and safe harbour 15 Is there a block exemption or safe harbour that provides certainty to companies as to the legality of vertical restraints under certain conditions? If so, please explain how this block exemption or safe harbour functions. 17 Have there been any developments in your jurisdiction in relation The Swedish Block Exemption, the Act (2008:581) on block exemption for anti-competitive vertical agreements refers back to the EC Block Exemption for vertical agreements (Regulation 2790/1999). The hard-core restrictions are the same as in Regulation 2790/1999. The Swedish Block Exemption corresponds in most respects to Regulation 2790/1999. The Competition Authority has not issued any guidelines as regards vertical agreements but takes guidance from the guidelines issued by the EC Commission (2000/C291/01). Agreements that fall under the Swedish Block Exemption are automatically exempted. Vertical agreements that are not covered by the Swedish Block Exemption are not presumed to be illegal, but instead subject to an individual assessment. Types of restraint 16 How is restricting the buyer’s ability to determine its resale price assessed under antitrust law? As under EC law retail price maintenance is not covered by the Block Exemption, including minimum prices and fixed prices. In addition it is not permissible for the supplier to either encourage (through discounts, etc) or discourage (through refusal of supply, withdrawal of discounts, etc) the buyer to stick to the recommended prices or maximum prices. However, maximum or recommended prices are permissible. In case MD 2002:5 , Svenska bokhandlareföreningen v Månadens Bok et al, the Market Court found that a recommended retail price on paperbacks was considered to constitute an outflow of a cooperation or concerted practice between various publishers, in breach of section 6 (now chapter 2, section 1) of the Competition Act. The Market Court ordered Månadens Bok et al, under penalty of a fine of 500,000 Swedish kronor, to cease printing recommended retail prices or other price information on paperbacks in the Månpocket series. The relevant market was defined as publishing of paperbacks in Sweden. Månadens Bok was considered to have a market share of at least 25 per cent. As to the anti-competitive behaviour, the Market Court acknowledged that the recommended retail price in question www.gettingthedealthrough.com was not binding for the buyers and that Månadens Bok would not undertake any action against a buyer who applied its own prices. Nevertheless, the Market Court stressed that competition could be affected. A buyer that wanted to apply a different price had to undertake active measures in order to show the customer which price was the actual price. That led to additional work for the buyer. During the proceedings, it had been demonstrated that the recommended retail price to a large extent was applied by the buyers. The Market Court found that the recommended retail prices thus lead to price rigidity and that it entailed a sales margin control as well as a retail price control for the individual distributor. As a result, competition was distorted for sales of Månpocket books on the relevant market. Since Månadens Bok had an appreciable market share, the distortion had an appreciable effect on the relevant market. The Market Court disregarded the claim from Månadens Bok that the recommended retail price had a positive effect for the consumers. Given the fact that Månadens Bok had not made an application for exemption under section 8 (now chapter 2, section 2) of the Act, the Market Court stated that it was not entitled to make such assessment. In 1993, the Competition Authority granted an exemption for retail price maintenance for a retail store franchise agreement (dnr 646/93). The Authority based its decision on the fact that it was a question of the establishment of a low-price chain and that it was possible for the franchisees to change the prices on the advertising material and the shelf price tags. to resale price maintenance restrictions in light of the landmark US Supreme Court judgment in Leegin Creative Leather Products Inc v PSKS Inc. If not, is any development in this area anticipated? Has there been any more general discussion by the relevant agency (or any other influential stakeholder) of the policy in your jurisdiction regarding resale price maintenance? There has not been any particular development in Sweden following the US Supreme Court judgment in Leegin, nor is any such development anticipated as far as we know. As mentioned in question 13, the ‘legal exemption’ in chapter 2, section 2 of the Act may be regarded as a sort of rule of reason, ie a balancing between the positive and the negative effects of a restrictive agreement. In this perspective, Swedish law is already in line with the basic principle laid down in Leegin which provides for a rule of reason approach. However, fixed minimum prices generally do not fulfil the conditions for exemption and are therefore essentially prohibited. 18 Have decisions relating to resale price maintenance addressed the possible links between such conduct and other forms of restraint? Have the decisions addressed the efficiencies that it is alleged can arise out of such restrictions? In case MD 2002:5, Svenska bokhandlareföreningen v Månadens Bok et al, it was also question of horizontal collusion between suppliers, see question 16. 19 How is restricting the territory into which a buyer may resell contract products assessed under antitrust law? In what circumstances may a supplier require a buyer of its products not to resell the products in certain territories? A restriction of the territory into which the buyer may sell the contract products or services is regarded as a hard-core restriction which prevents the application of the Swedish Block Exemption. It is, however, permissible under the Swedish Block Exemption to restrict the buyer from ‘active sales’ into markets that are granted to another 261 Sweden Advokatfirman Delphi distributor with exclusivity or which the supplier has reserved to itself. A prohibition on so-called passive sales, ie, unsolicited orders from a customer located in another territory is a hard-core restriction under the Swedish Block Exemption. •the relevant products have characteristics which motivate a selective distribution system (see question 24), and •the appointment of distributors is based on objective qualitative criteria, which are applied for all potential distributors. 20 Explain how restricting the customers to whom a buyer may Qualitative criteria for the appointment of distributors, such as the condition of the sale premises, presentation of the products, opening hours, qualification and further training of the staff, etc. are generally accepted. Also after-sales services, a prohibition on collection of the goods prices, a prohibition on mail-order sales or to sell products or apply a firm name that may undermine the prestige of a luxury trademark may be acceptable. Other acceptable restrictions relate to arrangements for wholesalers to control whether a customer is authorised and identify and document to whom the product has been sold. An assessment of the criteria has to been made taking into consideration the nature of the products. Quantitative criteria, ie, criteria limiting the number of distributors, turnover criteria, size of the stock and the product range etc. are normally prohibited but might qualify for an individual exemption. All distributors fulfilling the criteria must be accepted in the selective distribution system (requirement of non-discrimination). resell contract products is assessed under antitrust law. In what circumstances may a supplier require a buyer not to resell products to certain resellers or end-consumers? An absolute restriction of the customers to whom the buyer may sell the contract products is regarded as a hard-core restriction that prevents the application of the Swedish Block Exemption. However, the restriction of ‘active sales’ to an exclusive customer group reserved to the supplier or allocated by the supplier to another buyer is exempted, provided that such a restriction may not limit sales by the customers of the buyer. A supplier may also restrict a buyer operating at the wholesale level to sell directly to end-users. In selective distribution systems, the supplier may require that members of the system (authorised distributors) do not sell to unauthorised distributors. A supplier may also restrict the buyer’s ability to sell components that are supplied for the purpose of incorporation, to customers who would use them to manufacture the same types of goods as those produced by the supplier. Passive sales (ie, unsolicited orders resulting from a customer in a customer group reserved to someone else contacting the buyer in order to purchase the products or services) may, however, never be prohibited. 21 How is restricting the uses to which a buyer puts the contract products assessed under antitrust law? Provisions that prevent a buyer from reselling the products or oblige the buyer to only use the products in its own manufacturing process are generally considered problematic from a Swedish competition law point of view. However, such provisions may be permitted if they can be justified by objective reasons such as security or health reasons. Under the Swedish Block Exemption, a supplier may prevent the buyer from selling components which have been supplied for the purpose of incorporation to a customer who would use them to manufacture the same type of products as the supplier. The Block Exemption is neither applicable in relation to the restriction agreed between a supplier of components and a buyer who incorporates those components, which limits the supplier to selling the components as spare parts to end-users nor to repairers or other service providers not entrusted by the buyer with the repair or servicing of its goods. 22 How is restricting the buyer’s ability to generate sales via the internet assessed under antitrust law? Have the agencies issued decisions or guidance in relation to restrictions on internet selling? If so, what are the key principles? Internet sales are considered as passive sales in accordance with the EC Commission’s guidelines and may thus not be prohibited by the supplier. There are neither Swedish guidelines nor case law in this respect. 23 Briefly explain how agreements establishing ‘selective’ distribution systems are assessed differently under antitrust law. An undertaking that does not hold a dominant position may independently choose its distributors. However, if the distributor is prohibited from selling the products to non-authorised distributors, the antitrust rules will become applicable. Selective distribution systems have been considered to be consistent with chapter 2, section 1 of the Act in cases where: 262 24 Are selective distribution systems more likely to comply with antitrust law where they relate to certain types of product? If so, which types of product and why? The Competition Authority has in its practice considered that luxury products such as cosmetics and wristwatches and technically complicated products such as audio and video products, alpine ski equipment as well as complementary products such as sticks, backpacks, clothes and gloves, cars, computer servers, in-line skates, laser and ink-jet printers including accessories and consumable supplies, and online betting services are suitable products for selective distribution systems. On the other hand, the Competition Authority has not accepted selective distribution agreements for, eg, beds, bicycles, health food, high chairs, prams and wallpaper since these have been considered as neither luxury products nor technically complicated products. 25 Regarding selective distribution systems, are restrictions on internet sales by approved distributors permitted? If so, in what circumstances? Must internet sales criteria mirror offline sales criteria or would discrepancies be permitted? It follows from the EC Commission’s guidelines that the supplier may require quality standards for the use of the internet site to resell his goods, just as the supplier may require quality standards for a shop or for advertising and promotion in general. The latter may be relevant in particular for selective distribution. An outright ban on internet or catalogue selling is only possible if there is an objective justification. In any case, the supplier cannot reserve to itself sales or advertising over the internet. In our view internet sales criteria might differ from offline sales criteria since different conditions apply. However, the criteria must be applied in a non-discriminatory way. 26 Does the relevant agency take into account the possible cumulative restrictive effects of multiple selective distribution systems operating in the same market? A criterion for a selective distributions system to qualify for exemption is that there is workable inter-brand competition and that there is also not too much price rigidity. Getting the Deal Through – Vertical Agreements 2009 Advokatfirman Delphi Sweden 27 Has the agency taken decisions dealing with the possible links between selective distribution systems and resale price maintenance policies? If so, what are the key principles in such decisions? There are to our knowledge no such decisions. 28 How is restricting the buyer’s ability to obtain the supplier’s products from alternative sources assessed under antitrust law? These types of ‘exclusive purchase obligations’ should in our view be considered to be in breach of Swedish antitrust rules only if: •competitive suppliers have difficulties entering the market; and •the agreements made by the supplier and its distributors to an appreciable extent contributes to the foreclosure. problematic primarily if the buyer has a strong market position on the downstream market. Should the buyer have a limited market share on the downstream market, no negative effects for the consumers may be expected. However, if the buyer holds more than 30 per cent on the downstream supply market as well as on the upstream purchase market, potential negative effects should be analysed in detail in order to see whether the agreement qualifies for an individual exemption. Exclusive supply agreements of a shorter duration than five years entered into between non-dominant companies are often considered as lawful after a balancing of pro- and anti-competitive effects. 32 To what extent are franchise agreements incorporating licences of IPRs relating to trademarks or signs and know-how for the use and distribution of products assessed differently from ‘simple’ distribution This theory which is in line with ECJ case law should be applied by the Competition Authority. However, it may be noted that the Authority in its case law has stated that exclusive purchase agreements as such restrict competition and are deemed to be in breach of section 6 (now chapter 2, section 1) of the Act as soon as they were not covered by the Competition Authority’s previous guidelines on agreements of minor importance (KKVFS 1999:1). This practice has been criticised. 29 Explain how restricting the buyer’s ability to stock products competing with those supplied by the supplier under the agreement is assessed under antitrust law. Non-competition clauses are as a general rule exempted under the Swedish Block Exemption provided that the duration does not exceed five years or is indefinite. Nor must the duration of the clause exceed the duration of the agreement. The same rule applies to exclusive purchase obligations and purchase obligations that relate to more than 80 per cent of the buyer’s total need of the products or services. If the buyer sells the products or services from premises owned by the supplier, the duration of the non-competition clause may instead correspond to the period of the lease. After the term of the agreement, a non-compete obligation of up to one year may be permissible, provided that the obligation concerns products and services covered by the agreement and is indispensable for the protection of know-how transferred by the supplier to the buyer or distributor, and is limited to the point of sale from which the buyer or distributor operated during the term of the agreement. As for franchise agreements, non-compete obligations of an indefinite duration are permissible in order to protect the identity and know-how of the network. However, the non-compete obligation must not be longer than one year after termination of the agreement. In case the market share of the supplier is below 15 per cent the non-compete obligation is exempted under the de minimis exemption, see question 13, regardless of the duration of the agreement. 30 How is requiring the buyer to purchase from the supplier a certain amount or minimum percentage of the contract products assessed under antitrust law? Franchise agreements are in general considered to improve distribution at the retail level and thereby qualify for an exemption in accordance with chapter 2, section 2 of the Act. Since the franchisor establishes an identical business network that enables new undertakings, often small and medium-sized enterprises, to operate on the market. Knowledge and experience are transferred from the franchisor to the franchisee, which is cost-saving. Franchise agreements are thus in general considered to contribute to inter-brand competition. However, franchise agreements must nevertheless be drafted carefully to ensure that general principles of vertical restraints, such as rules on hardcore restrictions regarding resale price maintenance, are abided to. As explained under question 29 a more generous approach is taken towards non-competition clauses in franchise agreements. 33 Explain how a supplier’s warranting to the buyer that it will supply the contract products on the terms applied to the supplier’s most-favoured customer or that it will not supply the contract products on more favourable terms to other buyers is assessed under antitrust law. Would the analysis differ where the buyer commits to ‘most favoured’ terms in favour of the supplier? There is to our knowledge no Swedish case law as to whether provisions where the supplier warrants to the buyer that it will supply the contract product or services on the terms applied to the supplier’s most-favoured customer or that it will not supply the contract products on more favourable terms to other buyers are impermissible. Such a provision indicates that the buyer has a strong bargaining power in relation to the supplier. We believe that such provisions will normally be considered permissible under chapter 2, section 1 of the Act provided that they do not lead to discrimination. If the buyer has a dominant position, this kind of provision must be analysed in detail in order to assess that there is no abuse of dominant position. In cases where the buyer commits to ‘most favoured’ terms would in our view be considered to restrain competition and it is unlikely that such provision would qualify for an exemption since it would limit the buyer’s possibility to obtain the products or services for a lower price from alternative sources. Notifying agreements Exclusive purchase obligations and purchase obligations exceeding 80 per cent of the buyer’s total need of the products or services are considered to be non-competition clauses. See question 29. 31 Explain how restricting the supplier’s ability to supply to other resellers, or sell directly to consumers, is assessed under antitrust law. 34 Is there a formal procedure for notifying agreements containing vertical restraints to the agency? Is it necessary or advisable to notify it of any particular categories of agreement? If there is a formal notification procedure, how does it work? What type of ruling (if any) does the agency deliver at the end of the procedure? And how long does this take? Is a reasoned decision published at the end of the procedure? The main competition risk entailed by exclusive supply is the foreclosure of other buyers. Exclusive supply agreements are regarded as www.gettingthedealthrough.com agreements under antitrust law? No, it was abandoned 1 July 2004 following the Commission’s modernisation. 263 Sweden Advokatfirman Delphi Update and trends might be liable to pay damages to a third party due to a breach of the prohibition. The new Swedish Competition Act entered into force on 1 39 May the agency impose penalties itself or must it petition the courts November 2008. The new legislation means further harmonisation or another administrative or government agency? What sanctions and with EC competition rules and it also introduces a number of remedies can the agency or the courts impose when enforcing the new features in order to enhance cartel enforcement. One of the prohibition of vertical restraints? What notable sanctions or remedies new features is the introduction of trading prohibitions. The rules have been imposed? Can any trends be identified in this regard? regarding fines will become both clearer and stricter in an aim to enhance legal certainty. Furthermore, it will now become possible for companies to enter into settlement agreements with the Competition Authority. Agency guidance 35 If there is no formal procedure for notification, is it possible to obtain guidance from the agency as to the antitrust assessment of a particular agreement in certain circumstances? No. Complaints procedure for private parties 36 Is there a procedure whereby private parties can complain to the agency about alleged vertical restraints? All interested parties may complain to the Competition Authority. There is no specific time frame within which the Authority must take a decision. However, it has an obligation to close a case in which it decides not to take action by stating this in a decision. The Swedish Competition Act contains an unusual feature which is the subsidiary right for undertakings concerned to bring action claiming an injunction in case the Competition Authority decides not to take action. This so-called subsidiary right of action is provided for in chapter 3, section 2 of the Competition Act. However, the right is unavailable in case the Competition Authority has applied article 13 in Regulation 1/2003, which regulates the situation where a complaint is rejected due to the fact that a competition authority of a Member State or the Commission has received a complaint against an agreement, decision of an association or practice which has already been dealt with by another competition authority. In addition, the possibility of bringing action is reserved to undertakings and thus does not include individuals. Enforcement 37 How frequently is antitrust law applied to vertical restraints by the agency? What are the main enforcement priorities regarding vertical agreements? There are no statistics as regards how frequently antitrust law is applied to vertical restraints. However, the Competition Authority rarely intervenes against vertical restraints. The approximately 100 decisions regarding vertical restraints taken before 2004 are in the large majority of cases applications for negative clearance and/or exemption and only in a limited number of cases matters initiated by the Authority. The only case so far tried by the Market Court was brought by a private party under the subsidiary right of action (see question 16 above). 38 What are the consequences of an infringement of antitrust law for the validity or enforceability of a contract containing prohibited vertical restraints? Agreements that are in conflict with the prohibition on anti-competitive cooperation in chapter 2, section 1 of the Act are deemed null and void in accordance with chapter 2, section 6. Further, a company 264 The Competition Authority is not entitled to impose fines so must petition the Stockholm District Court to impose fines. The Competition Authority may issue an injunctive order or an interim injunction but to issue the order under penalty of a fine it must petition the Stockholm District Court The level of sanctions or remedies depends on the circumstances in each specific case. Fines have so far not been imposed in a case concerning vertical restraints but injunctions have been issued under penalty of a fine. In the Competition Act that entered into force 1 November 2008, the methods for calculation of fines were brought closer to the principles under EC law. The maximum fine under the Act is 10 per cent of the turnover of the company in question and not the whole group of companies. Investigative powers of the agency 40 What investigative powers does the agency have when enforcing the prohibition of vertical restraints? According to chapter 5, section 1 of the Act, the Competition Authority may, where it is necessary for the performance of its duties under the Act, require undertakings or other parties to supply information, documents and other material. Further, the Authority is entitled to require persons who are likely to be in a position to provide relevant information to appear at a hearing. The Stockholm District Court may upon request of the Competition Authority decide that the Authority is entitled to, in accordance with chapter 5, section 3 of the Act, carry out an investigation on the premises of a company to establish whether the company has infringed chapter 2, section 1 of the Act (a dawn raid). The requirements for such decision to be issued is that there is reason to believe that an infringement has been committed; the undertaking does not comply with an obligation imposed pursuant to chapter 5, section 1, point 1 or there is a risk of evidence being withheld or tampered with, and the importance of the action taken is sufficient to outweigh the interference or other inconvenience caused to the parties affected by it. Private enforcement 41 To what extent is private enforcement possible? Can non-parties to agreements containing vertical restraints obtain declaratory judgments or injunctions and bring damages claims? Can the parties to agreements themselves bring damages claims? What remedies are available? How long should a company expect a private enforcement action to take? As outlined in question 36, if the Competition Authority decides not to take action in relation to a complaint, a party affected by the infringement may according to chapter 3, section 2 of the Act make a claim for an injunction in the Market Court. A third party that suffers damage due to breach of the Swedish competition rules or articles 81 or 82 EC may instigate proceedings for damages in accordance with chapter 3, section 25 of the Act. Competitors as well as suppliers and buyers which are affected by an anti-competitive vertical restraint are entitled to claim damages. Also an individual or a company which is a party to the agreement may be entitled to damages. Damages may be awarded with the lost profit and interest in accordance with the Interest Act (1975:635). Getting the Deal Through – Vertical Agreements 2009 Advokatfirman Delphi Sweden A damages proceeding takes several years in the courts. However, in order to appeal a judgment from a District Court, leave for appeal is required. The main rule is that the loser pays principle applies, ie the successful party can recover its legal costs. Other issues 42 Is there any unique point relating to the assessment of vertical restraints in your jurisdiction that is not covered above? No. Elisabeth Legnerfält Helene Andersson [email protected] [email protected] Regeringsgatan 30-32 111 82 Stockholm Sweden Tel: +46 8 677 54 00 Fax: +46 8 20 18 84 www.delphi.se www.gettingthedealthrough.com 265 The article is reproduced with permission from Law Business Research. This article was first published in Getting the Deal Through – Vertical agreements 2009, (published in March 2009 – contributing editor Stephen Kinsella OBE). For further information please visit www.GettingTheDealThrough.com
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz