The Concept of Additionality under the UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol: Implications for Environmental Integrity and Equity Charlotte Streck 1. Introduction The concept of additionality is a recurrent theme in discussions of international and domestic climate legislation and investments. Additionality in the context of the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) 1 refers to an effort that is supplemental to the business-as-usual (BAU) scenario in at least two areas: (i) the additionality of financial contributions of developed countries to mitigate climate change in developing countries; and (ii) the additionality of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions generated by mitigation activities. Additionality of financial resources is the price that developing countries demand for their participation to resolve global environmental problems in the context of the UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol (KP) 2 . 3 While the additionality of finance is difficult to establish, it is less controversial than GHG additionality, in particular where such emission reductions are used to offset emissions in developed countries. Over the last decade the definition of additionality of GHG reductions has become increasingly restrictive. Today, additionality most commonly refers to the causality between international financial support for an activity and the extent to which the activity would have happened in the absence of such support. Where a GHG reducing activity would have been implemented in the absence of carbon finance, the project or program disqualifies as non-additional, regardless of the number of emission reductions it yields. Despite a decade of attempts to define additionality, the concept continues to be poorly understood and its application contested. The most important reason for the controversies around additionality lies in its counterfactual nature that makes it impossible to ever prove additionality. The testing of additionality generally involves the establishment counterfactual reference scenario against which reality is gauged. Unfortunately, international negotiations have rarely defined guidelines for the establishment of reference scenarios and the application of the additionality criterion has proven treacherous in practice. The desire not to compromise environmental integrity of GHG emission reductions has led to extensive elaboration of the application of additionality under the Kyoto Protocol’s clean development mechanism (CDM). The CDM’s governing body, its executive board, advocates a strict interpretation of additionality and requires the project-specific proving that carbon finance is causal for a project. An increasingly restrictive interpretation of additionality reduces the supply of offsets from the CDM, a political goal that has been welcomed to stimulate emission reductions in the industrialized world. However, the restrictive interpretation of additionality under the CDM also reduces the funding of the GHG reducing projects in the developing world. While financial flows under the CDM have effectively been restricted by additionality, additionality of finance of contributions of developing countries to international climate В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В UN Doc Distr General A/AC.237/18 (Part II)/Add.1, 15 May 1992. FCCC/CP/1997/L.7/Add.1,Decision 1/CP.3 Adoption of the Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, Annex, reprinted in (1998) 37 International Legal Materials (ILM) 22. 3 Andrew Jordan, Jacob Werksman, Additional Funds, Incremental Costs and the Global Environment, RECIEL, Volume 3, Numbers 2/3, pg.81-87, 83. 1 2 1В В funds has rarely been checked. Neither has the environmental risks of offsetting of emissions in developed countries through land-use activities received much attention. The negotiations of the architecture of a post-2012 climate agreement call for a reform existing mechanisms, such as the CDM, and require the design of new and effective institutions to govern significant financial flows into the low carbon development of developing countries. While the concept remains contentious, additionality is likely to continue to be an important criterion for climate finance beyond 2012. The ongoing climate negotiations therefore provide an important opportunity to clarify the application of additionality in finance as well as with respect to GHG reducing activities. This paper aims at informing the ongoing negotiations by summarizing the main arguments underlying the debate around additionality in the CDM. The argument supported by this paper is that establishing additionality is inherently political. Instead of trying to make the case for additionality in each single case through the application of quasi-scientific criteria, it is argued that the testing of additionality should consist in a testing against a list of eligibility criteria. Such criteria would enable policy makers to exclude certain, non-additional activities from carbon finance, while creating transparency and predictability for all stakeholders. The paper argues that the establishment of additionality through clearly defined and objective requirements will lead to better and more predictable outcomes than the current project-specific additionality test of the CDM executive board and strengthen the overall legitimacy of the mechanism. This paper is organized into three parts. The first part summarizes the evolution of the concept of additionality under the UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol. The second part reviews the discussion around the additionality concept and refutes some common errors about the additionality debate. The third part reviews and proposes methods to establish additionality of GHG reductions with a view of creating an applicable and acceptable concept that mutes the persisting controversy on additionality. 2. Defining Additionality in International Climate Policy 2.1. Financial Additionality The 1992 UN Conference on Environment and Development (UNCED) marked a shift in the history of international environmental law. For the first time, consideration of development was explicitly introduced into international environmental policy. 4 Complex environmental problems such as climate change require engagement with developing countries for long-term sustainable management of natural resources. However, developing countries refused responsibility for global problems they attributed that were the tainted legacy of developed countries’ historical patterns of industrialization and consumption. Consequently, developing countries made their actions conditional on the availability of new and additional resources for global environmental action from developed counties (financial additionality). 5 Since the early 1990s, the access to “new and additional” funds has been a central demand of developing countries’ negotiation strategy in international environmental talks. 6 As such, the term “additional” refers В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В 4 В Dan Bodansky (2010), The Art and Craft of International Environmental Law, Harvard University Press. В The 1990 London Amendment of the Montreal Protocol, for example, expressly state that fund contributions “shall be additional to other financial transfers to” developing countries Report of the Second Meetings of the Parties to the Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer, U.N. Doc UNEP/OzL.Pro.2/3 (June 29, 1990), Annex II, art. 10, para. 6; http://ozone.unep.org/Ratification_status/london_amendment.shtml (accessed 22 September 2010). 6 Jordan, Werksman, p. 82. 5 2В В to funding supplemental to existing financial transfers of existing development aid. 7 / 8 Establishing the additionality of finance remains challenging; so far no clear criteria have been defined to distinguish “new” budget allocations from the diversion of existing official development funds. Until today, it remains unclear how much of the financial contributions of developed to developing countries under the UNFCCC is indeed additional. 9 Nevertheless, the current discussions of a post-2012 climate agreement and the need for enhanced resources for climate change mitigation and adaptation have revived the discussion of additionality of finance. The 2009 Copenhagen Accord negotiated at the 15th session of the conference of the parties to the UNFCCC (CP) reads: The collective commitment by developed countries is to provide new and additional resources, […] through international institutions, approaching USD 30 billion for the period 2010 –2012. 10 To ensure the availability of finance for mitigation and adaptation, developing countries demand the measurement, reporting and verification (MRV) of financial support next to the MRV of mitigation action in developing countries. 11 However additionality of finance is not only relevant at the point of mobilizing resources. It is equally difficult to grasp at the point of delivery. The transfer of financial resources to developing countries under the UNFCCC was proposed to offset the various costs of implementing the Convention’s general commitments as well as to compensate for the costs of adaptation. 12 While the Convention makes the contribution of financial resources to developing countries mandatory, it does not identify specific level of funding. According to Article 4.3 and 4.7 of the UNFCCC as well as Article 11.2 (a) and 13.4 (g) of the Kyoto Protocol, the implementation of climate change mitigation measures by В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В UNEP, Interpretations of Phrases “Adequate, New and Additional”, “New and Additional” and “Adequate and Additional” Financial Resources, Note by the Secretariat, UNEP, Bio.Div./N4/Inc2, Forth Session of the Intergovernmental Negotiating Committee for a Convention on Biological Biodiversity, Nairobi 23 September – 2 October 1991. 8В In 1999, EU commission had issued guidance to CDM investors by stating that “official development finance and GEF should only be supplementary to private funding.[...] ODA within the framework of [the] CDM [...] would have to be targeted to areas where the public sector has a comparative advantage over private investment and where additional social benefits are to be expected.” But the Commission made also clear that ODA should not be used to finance the acquisition of certified emission reductions (CERs). (EU Commission (1999), EC economic and development co-operation responding to the new challenge of climate change, Brussels: Working document of 3 November 1999, p. 11 and 12.) The result was understood to be in many cases equivalent to the incremental cost approach of the GEF, though with a more transparent treatment of incremental benefits. See: Kenneth M. Chomnitz, Baselines for Greenhouse Gas Reductions: Problems, Precedents, Solutions; prepared for the Carbon Offsets Unit, World Bank, Draft for discussion: rev.1.4, 16 July 1998. During the negotiations of the Marrakesh Accords developed countries concurred – and ultimately prevailed – on a very broad definition of financial additionality. The CDM modalities and procedures states that “public funding for clean development mechanism projects from Parties in Annex I is not to result in the diversion of official development assistance and is to be separate from and not counted towards the financial obligations of Parties included in Annex I. Preamble of Decision 3/CMP.1 (CDM modalities and procedures), CMP 2005. 9 The European Union, through the European Council’s Economic and Financial Committee and Economic Policy Committee Joint Working Group on the Financial Aspects of Climate Change, is currently waging another attempt to formulate definitions to assess вЂ�additional’ international public finance for climate change. EU Presidency Questionnaire on fast start finance (2010) EFC EPC Joint Working Group on the economic and financial aspects of climate change, Brussels, 9 April, 2010. The Development Assistance Committee of the OECD has made several attempts to issue guidance on how to account for transfers of funds and achieving additionality, but the term remains vague and additionality of finance almost impossibly to prove. For a review of the various possible definitions, see: Jessica Brown, Neil Bird and Liane Schalatek (2010), Climate finance additionality: emerging definitions and their implications, Climate Finance Policy Brief No 2, Heinrich Boell Stiftung North America, http://www.boell.org/downloads/Schalatek_Climate_Finance_Additionality_6-2010.pdf (accessed 18 July 2010). 10 Copenhagen Accord, 2/CP15, FCCC/CP/2009/11/Add.1, 30 March 2010. 11В В [add source] 12 Daniel Bodansky (1993), The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change: A Commentary, Yale Journal of International Law, Vol. 18: 451-554, 523, 1993 7 3В В developing countries depends on the availability of finance provided by developed to the benefit of developing countries: They [developed countries] shall also provide such financial resources, including for the transfer of technology, needed by the developing country Parties to meet the agreed full incremental costs of implementing measures that are covered by paragraph 1 of this Article and that are agreed between a developing country Party and the international entity or entities referred to in Article 11, in accordance with that Article. (UNFCCC Article 4.3) 13 Eager to keep demands under control, developed countries traditionally have been careful to limit the size of payment to developing countries to the costs of complying with environmental treaties. The concept of incremental costs was introduced to exclude the financing of baseline costs and to limit claims to financing the benefits of the global environment. The underlying assumption of the incremental cost principle is that the relevant costs for complying with the UNFCCC are incremental rather than total. Using financial or behavioral methods, the activity that is eligible to receive financing is to be compared to the baseline scenario, to the activity it replaces or makes redundant. The difference in costs between the realization of the two activities is the incremental cost. 14 The incremental costs are not only the measure for eligible finance, they are also associated with the global environmental benefit of an activity, assuming that the incremental costs and the global environmental benefits are corresponding concepts. Although the general concept of incremental costs is fairly well understood, identifying the relevant costs associated with a particular activity, can be very difficult, in particular where there are no baseline costs from which to measure a country’s incremental costs. For that reason, the more pragmatic approach is to agree on specific categories of costs to be funded rather than on a detailed methodology to define “incremental costs”. 15 While the Global Environment Facility (GEF) that administers the financial mechanism of the UNFCCC has never established a positive list on incremental costs, such approach was taken under the London Amendments to the Montreal Protocol, where an enumerated list of incremental costs was adopted by a decision of the parties. 16 2.2. Mitigation Additionality Next to the financial additionality, Kyoto Protocol introduces a second meaning of “additionality”, namely the additionality of GHG emission reductions (mitigation additionality). As in the case of additionality of financial contributions of developed countries, measuring mitigation additionality requires the establishment of a baseline. When used in the context of evaluating and calculating GHG-reducing or removing activities, the requirement of additionality is expected to filter the positive net global environmental benefits associated with such activity. В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В 13 В Article 11.2 (a) of the Kyoto Protocol confirms that developed country Parties and other Parties included in Annex II to the Convention shall “provide new and additional financial resources to meet the agreed full costs incurred by developing country Parties in advancing the implementation of existing commitments under Article 4, paragraph 1(a), of the Convention that are covered in Article 10, subparagraph (a)”.В 14 GEF Council Document, GEF/C.4/10, Incremental Costs and Financing Modalities, 30 April 1995. 15 Daniel Bodansky, The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change: A Commentary, Yale Journal of International Law, Vol. 18: 451-554, 526, 1993 16 UNEP, Ozone Secretariat, Handbook for the Montreal Protocol on Substances That Deplete the Ozone Layer 96 (1991); J.M. Patlis (1992),The Multilateral Fund of the Montreal Protocol, Cornell International Law Report, vol. 25 no. 1 , p. 181-230. 4В В Mitigation additionality is mentioned in Article 3.4 (relating to using land-use emission reductions to offset industrial emissions in developed countries), 17 Article 6.1 (relating to joint implementation (JI) and the transfer of emission reductions generated by investments in developed countries among those countries), 18 and Article 12.5 (relating to the CDM and the creation of transferable emission reductions generated by investments in developing countries to developed countries) of the Kyoto Protocol. In all three cases, additionality refers to an activity reducing emissions (Art. 3.4) or the actual reduction in emissions (Art.6.1 and 12.5) that need to be additional to what would happen in the absence of the activity. The Kyoto Protocol refers to additionality both with respect to activities implemented in developed (Art.3.4 and 6.1) as well as in developing (Art. 12.5) countries. The concept has gained most prominence in the context of the CDM. In comparison, it has received comparatively little attention with respect to JI and, surprisingly taking into account the relevance for the integrity of the Kyoto Protocol, almost none with respect to using emission reductions and removals from land-use activities within industrialized countries. In the CDM, in contrast, additionality has become the key concept defining the environmental integrity of the mechanism. 2.2.1. Defining Additionality in the CDM The Kyoto Protocol mandates that each certified emission reduction (CER) issued for a CDM project should represent a real, measurable and additional emission reduction. Emission reductions under the CDM must be “additional to any that would occur in the absence of the certified project activity”. 19 The test of additionality is thus not identical and congruent with or fully covered and encompassed by the requirement of “real, measurable, and long-term benefits” as mandated by Article 12.5 (b) Kyoto Protocol; it is supplemental. Such testing mandates the establishment of a baseline scenario and the assessment of emission reductions against that scenario. The mitigation benefits of a CDM activity have to be measured against the counterfactual case of a world in which the activity or project would not take place. Additional emission reductions (or removals) therefore describe the climate benefits of the relative activity compared to the effects of displacement and leakage that relate to carbon effects outside of the established boundary of the activity and which have to be deducted from the measured emission reductions. The 1997 Kyoto Protocol defines the concept of additionality but fails to operationalize it. The first interpretations of additionality where brought forward by project proponents who developed early CDM projects in anticipation of the Protocol entering into force. Early project proponents, in particular the World Bank through its carbon funds and the Government of the Netherlands through its emission reduction purchase tenders, read the CDM provisions and the additionality criterion as mandate to establish a conservative BAU scenario (the baseline). On top of this, they applied the traditional concept of financial additionality to CDM projects, which meant that no public money that would have been spent anyway on climate-related action in developing countries could be relabeled as CDM. They did not think that a separate additionality test was required. 20 This view seemed to be supported by interpretations of the EU Commission that had issued guidance in 1999 clarifying that ODA should not be used to finance the acquisition of certified emission reductions (CERs). 21 The Commission also stated that “official В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В 17….“how, and which, additional human-induced activities related to changes in greenhouse gas emissions by sources and removals by sinks in the agricultural soils and the land-use change and forestry categories shall be added to, or subtracted from, the assigned amounts for Parties included in Annex I..” Article 3.4 Kyoto Protocol. 18 …“Any such project provides a reduction in emissions by sources, or an enhancement of removals by sinks, that is additional to any that would otherwise occur;..” Article 6.1 (b) Kyoto Protocol. 19 Article 12(5)(c) Kyoto Protocol.В 20 Terms of Reference, CER Purchase Tender (CERUPT), 1 November 2001. 21В EU Commission (1999), EC economic and development co-operation responding to the new challenge of climate change, Brussels: Working document of 3 November 1999, p. 11 and 12. 5В В development finance and GEF should only be supplementary to private funding.[...] ODA within the framework of [the] CDM [...] would have to be targeted to areas where the public sector has a comparative advantage over private investment and where additional social benefits are to be expected.” 22 The result was understood to be in many cases equivalent to the incremental cost approach of the GEF, though with a more transparent treatment of incremental benefits. 23 In 2001 the CP interpreted additionality in the context of the Marrakech Accords that formulate, among others, a set of decisions that guide the implementation of the CDM . 24 / 25 The Accords diverge in their definition from the additionality concept of Article 12(5) KP when they replace the reference to the additionality of the emission reductions of the Kyoto Protocol by a reference to the additionality of the individual CDM project activity: “A CDM project activity is additional if anthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases by sources are reduced below those that would have occurred in the absence of the registered CDM project activity”. 26 In the light of the language of the Kyoto Protocol and as further elaborated by the CDM modalities of the Marrakesh Accords, additionality can now be understood as the “requirement that the greenhouse gas emissions after implementation of a CDM project activity are lower than those that would have occurred in the most plausible alternative scenario to the implementation of the CDM project activity. This alternative scenario may be the business-as-usual case (that is, the continuation of current emission levels in the absence of the CDM project activity), or it may be some other scenario which involves a gradual lowering of emissions intensity.” 27 However, the most powerful influence on the interpretation of additionality had the CDM executive board, the body in charge of the daily administration of the mechanism. The executive board decided that in addition to generating emission reductions below the baseline, a project activity would have to demonstrate that it falls outside of the baseline scenario to be additional. 28 Project proponents have to prove that the CDM was causal for the decision to implement or finance a project. In 2004, the board adopted the “Tool for the demonstration and assessment of additionality” (the additionality tool, see Text Box 1) as a general framework for establishing additionality. 29 The project-based additionality test В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В 22В Ibid. p. 12. Kenneth M. Chomnitz, Baselines for Greenhouse Gas Reductions: Problems, Precedents, Solutions; prepared for the Carbon Offsets Unit, World Bank, Draft for discussion: rev.1.4, 16 July 1998. 24 The Marrakesh Accords were adopted by the 7th session of the UNFCCC COP held in Marrakesh, Morocco, in December 2001 and confirmed by the 1st session of the COP/MOP in Montreal in December 2005 FCCC/KP/2008/8/Add.1 Decision 3/CMP.1 (Modalities and procedures for a clean development mechanism as defined in article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol). 25 The limited provisions Article 12 KP do not provide sufficient guidance for the creation of an operational mechanism as complex as the CDM. Article 12(7) recognizes this by mandating the “The Conference of the Parties serving as the meeting of the Parties to this Protocol [CMP] shall, at its first session, elaborate modalities and procedures with the objective of ensuring transparency, efficiency and accountability through independent auditing and verification of project activities.” The CMP is an assembly of all the Parties to the Protocol which convenes annually and is the governing body of the Kyoto Protocol. The mandate of the CMP is broadly drafted. Article 13(4) of the Protocol states that the CMP “…shall keep under regular review the implementation of this Protocol and shall make, within its mandate, the decisions necessary to promote its effective implementation”. В 26 Decision 3/CMP.1, Annex, para. 43 (CDM modalities and procedures), CMP 2005. 27 Baker & McKenzie, CDM Rule Book, Additionality, page 84: http://cdmrulebook.org/84, accessed 18 July 2010. 28 EB 8, Annex 1. 29 EB 39, Annex 10. This version replaces EB 36, Annex 13 (Version 04), EB 29, Annex 5 (Version 03), EB 22, Annex 8 (Version 2) and EB 16, Annex 1 (Version 1). See Baker & McKenzie, CDM Rule Book, Establishing additionality – the additionality tool, page 86: http://cdmrulebook.org/86, accessed 18 July 2010. The latest version of the additionality tool (Version 05) was adopted at the 39th session of the executive board. 23 6В В devised by the CDM executive board is to net off emission reductions that form part of the BAU baseline but would happen also in the absence of the CDM. The investment analysis sits at the core of the board’s additionality test. It requires that project proponents demonstrate that the proposed project activity is economically less attractive than alternatives or a financial benchmark. Proving investment additionality turns the incremental cost argument on its head: Instead of establishing the incremental costs to quantify the size of the payment that developing countries may receive from industrialized countries for their contribution to restore and limit harm to the global environment, the investment analysis limits access to international payment if they are not essential for the project. The incremental cost calculation is thereby relative to the overall investment while the additionality test as required today implies a binary test which deprives non-additional projects and activities from the benefit of international climate finance. Text Box 1: The CDM Additionality Tool The additionality tool sets out the following steps to demonstrate and assess additionality: 30 п‚· Step 1: Identification of alternatives to the project activity Step 1 involves two sub-steps. Sub-step 1(a) is directed towards the identification of realistic and credible alternatives to the project scenario. In particular, project participants are required to identify realistic and credible alternative(s) available to the project participants or similar project developers that provide outputs or services comparable with the proposed CDM project activity. Sub-step 1(b) is directed towards ensuring compliance with all mandatory laws and regulations. This sub-step does not consider national and local policies that do not have legally-binding status. Where analysis shows that there is widespread non-compliance in a country or region with mandatory laws and policies, then a scenario involving non-compliance is a valid one which may be considered. п‚· Step 2: Investment analysis The investment analysis serves to determine that the proposed project activity is either (a) not the most economically or financially attractive or (b) not economically or financially feasible. Step 2 involves determining whether the proposed project activity without the revenue from the sale of CERs is either (a) not the most economically or financially attractive or (b) not economically or financially feasible. Undertaking the investment analysis involves several substeps (e.g. selection simple cost analysis, investment comparison analysis or benchmark analysis, and the comparison of the financial indicators of the proposed project activity and the alternatives identified in step 1; as well as a sensitivity analysis). A project activity will only satisfy the requirements of step 2 (investment analysis) if it can be shown that implementation of the project would not be the most financially/economically attractive option in any case. п‚· Step 3: Barrier analysis Step 3 involves determining whether the proposed project activity faces barriers that: -prevent the implementation of this type of proposed project activity; and -do not prevent the implementation of at least one of the alternatives (EB 39, Annex 10). В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В 30 В Adapted from: Baker & McKenzie, CDM Rule Book, Establishing additionality – the additionality tool, page 86: http://cdmrulebook.org/86, accessed 18 July 2010.В 7В В In order for a project activity to meet the requirements of this step, these barriers must prevent the project from being implemented unless it is registered under the CDM. п‚· Step 4: Common practice analysis Step 4 complements steps 1, 2 and 3 (as applicable) with an analysis of the extent to which the proposed project type (e.g. technology or practice) has already diffused in the relevant sector and region. This step is a credibility check, in that if similar activities are widely observed and commonly carried out, it calls into question the claim that the proposed project activity is financially/economically unattractive or faces barriers. The evaluation of investment barriers or existing incentive structures and common-practices are auxiliary tools to establish project additionality. The CP serving as the meeting of the Parties of the Kyoto Protocol (CMP), the supreme body of the Kyoto Protocol, has been skeptical from the start towards the board’s approach to additionality. It has repeatedly stressed that the additionality tool is not mandatory in its application and called for alternative interpretations. 31 Complying with the CMP mandate, the executive board has encouraged project participants to present clear and precise ways to propose alternatives to establish additionality as a part of proposed new methodologies. 32 Being aware of the executive board’s reluctance to reduce the applicability of the additionality test, project proponents have refused to take the risk of developing alternative methods to prove additionality. The general sluggishness of the CDM approval process, the tense relationship between verifiers and the executive board, the unpredictability of decisions of the board and the evaluation practice of the review panels of the CDM 33 limit the appetite for additional risks-taking among project proponents. Consequently, the application of the additionality tool, and the application of the investment analysis as its core, has become de facto mandatory in the vast majority of CDM project activities and - as the CDM administration become more and more overwhelmed and critical reports in the press picked up - has increased in stringency over time. 34 Applying the additionality tool reflects a low risk choice and project developers are not willing to take the risk of submitting alternative additionality approaches. In the absence of project developer activity, the executive board has -in a top down approach - considered benchmarks as additionality test for energy-efficient refrigerators. 35 В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В Decisions 7/CMP.1, paras 25-28, The CMP “Confirms that, as stipulated in decision 12/CP.10, the use of the "tool for the demonstration and assessment of additionality" is not mandatory for project participants, and that in all cases the project participants may propose alternative methods to demonstrate additionality for consideration by the Executive Board, including those cases where the "tool for the demonstration and assessment of additionality" is attached to an approved methodology” (7/CMP.1, paragraph 28); and decision 1/CMP.2 para 16(c). 7/CMP.1, paragraph 28 confirms that the use of the tool for the demonstration and assessment of additionality is not mandatory. 32 EB 28, paragraph 21. 33 Charlotte Streck (2007), The governance of the Clean Development Mechanism – the case for strength and stability in David Freestone and Charlotte Streck (eds), “The Kyoto Protocol – current legal status of carbon finance and the flexible mechanisms”, Special Issue Environmental Liability Journal, vol. 15, Issue 2, 2007, p. 91. See also IETA, “2006 State of the CDM”, IETA Position on the CDM for COP/MOP2, available at http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php?docID=1931 (accessed 18 July 2010). 34 Axel Michaelowa (2009), Interpreting the Additionality of CDM Projects: Changes in Additionality Definitions and Regulatory Practices over time, in, David Freestone and Charlotte Streck (Eds.), Legal Aspects of Carbon Trading: Kyoto, Copenhagen and Beyond (Oxford University Press, 2009), p. 248-271, 254, 255. The mandatory character of the tool has however repeatedly been rejected by the CMP. Decision 12/CP. 10, paras 9. 28; decision 7/CMP.1 35 See Approved Methodology (AM) 0070 (http://cdm.unfccc.int/methodologies/PAmethodologies/approved.html accessed 9 September 2010). 31 8В В 3. Critical Review of Additionality in the CDM 3.1. Environmental Integrity and the CDM Additionality Test Additionality has become a matter of concern because of BAU emission reductions which may not be contributable to the individual project and the climate finance component of it. 36 These emission reductions that may be real and measurable are causally not linked to the CDM and part of the BAU scenario. Taking into account the offsetting character of the CDM, it has been concluded that “those cases where projects would have taken place anyway, the end result is an overall rise in global GHG emissions” 37 and only a strict interpretation of project additionality would address the risk of creating “fictitious CERs”. 38 Other than in the case of JI, CERs are newly created trading units and not covered by an allowance to emit from the host country’s assigned amount. The cap-and-trade architecture of the Kyoto Protocol is target based and international emission trading allows the exchange of assigned amount units within the capped system. This is generally considered harmless and it is not tested whether the system results in real emission reductions or not. The CDM however operates outside established absolute emission limitations. CDM baselines are therefore establishing project-level reference cases that try to model what would happen in the absence of the mechanism. There is a concern if emission reductions in developing countries are not additional they lead to an increase of the overall cap of emissions established by commitments of developed country (Annex I) Parties to the Kyoto Protocol. The CDM executive board has responded to these concerns with devising the additionality test. But the test has not protected the CDM against further blame. Among the many complaints about the CDM, 39 those that claim that a large number of non-additional projects had been registered over time and that these projects create fake, fraudulent, or non-genuine emission reductions have received particular attention. 40 Reacting to these reports, the CDM executive board set up the “registration and issuance В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В 36 Benito Mueller (2009), Additionality in the Clean Development Mechanism, Why and What?, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies EV 44, March 2009, p.8. 37 Mark C. Trexler, D.J. Broekhoff, L.H. Kosloff (2006), A statically-driven approach to offset-based GHG additionality determinations: What can we learn? Sustainable Development Law & Policy, 4 (2), p. 30-30; Johannes Alexew, Linda Bergset, Kristin Meyer, Juliane Petersen, Lambert Schneider, Charlotte Unger, 2010, An analysis of the relationship between the additionality of CDM projects and their contribution to sustainable development, Int Environ Agreements DOI 10.1007/s10784-010-9121-y, published online on 3 March 2010. 38 Axel Michaelowa, 2009, Interpreting the Additionality of CDM Projects: Changes in Additionality Definitions and Regulatory Practices over time, in, David Freestone and Charlotte Streck (Eds.), Legal Aspects of Carbon Trading: Kyoto, Copenhagen and Beyond (Oxford University Press, 2009), p. 248-271, 249. 39 Ben Pearson, Yin Shao Loong (2003), The CDM: Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions or Relabeling Business as Usual?, CDM Watch, Third World Network, http://www.twnside.org.sg/title/cdm.doc (accessed 18 July 2010); A. Michaelowa and P. Purohit, “Additionality Determination of Indian Projects, Can Indian CDM Project Developers Outwit the CDM Executive Board?”, 2007, available at http://medias.lemonde.fr/mmpub/edt/doc/20070608/920594_additionality_determination_of_indian_cdm_proje cts.pdf. In 2007, there has been an intense media debate on additionality and sustainability benefits of the CDM. Download articles in the "Guardian" at http://www.guardian.co.uk/frontpage/story/0,,2093837,00.html and http://environment.guardian.co.uk/climatechange/story/0,,2093815,00.html, "Le Monde" (French) at www.lemonde.fr/web/article/0,1-0@2-3244,36-920043,0.html, "Tagesanzeiger" (German) at http://tages-anzeiger.ch/dyn/news/print/ausland/758571.html and the comment by the International Emission Trading Association (hereinafter “IETA”) on the Guardian article at http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php?docID=2408. The Stockholm Environment Institute has also compiled a list of publications that that criticize the CDM for its lack of additionality (compiled by Barbara Haya). http://www.co2offsetresearch.org/PDF/AdditionalityLackCDM.pdf (all accessed 18 September 2010). 40 Axel Michaelowa, Pallaw Pundit, 2007, Additionality determination of Indian CDM projects. Can Indian project developers outwit the CDM Executive Board? Discussion Paper CDM-1, Climate Strategies, London, 2007; Lambert 9В В team” and the UNFCCC secretariat hired more dedicated CDM staff to review project applications with a particular focus on the credibility of the additionality argument. By 2008, lack of additionality accounted for the absolute majority of all rejections of projects submitted for registration. 41 But the restrictions of access to the CDM through the tightening of the additionality testing has still not muted those that see the CDM as principally flawed. While indisputably restricting access to CDM finance, there are many concerns with the environmental argument backing the executive board’s additionality test: п‚· п‚· п‚· The current additionality test relies on assumptions that hardly can be verified. 42 It is hence subjective and creates unpredictable outcomes. Demonstrating the intent of project developers is impossible and beyond the mandate given by the CMP. 43 The establishment of project additionality is generally ill suited to take into account the political economy of the host country, in particular in non-liberalized economies, which implement and systematically support economic decisions according to national planning processes. 44 The conversion of additionality in a binary eligibility tool that assumes that causality between the project sponsor’s decision to realize a project and the CDM eliminates degrees of additionality. 45 Proponents of the executive board’s approach to additionality testing defend the quantitative nature of testing investment additionality as more objective than qualitative tests of investment barriers 46 and environmentally more rigorous than benchmarks. Those criticizing the test argue the opposite: they condemn the subjective nature of establishing the reasons for an investment decision. 47 As early as 1999, В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В Schneider (2007), Is the CDM fulfilling its environmental and sustainable development objectives? An evaluation of the CDM and options for improvement. Oeko Institut: Berlin 2007. Michael W. Wara, David G. Victor (2008), A Realistic Policy on International Carbon Offsets, Stanford Unviersity, Energy and Sustainable Development Working Paper #74, April 2008, available at: http://pesd.stanford.edu/publications/a_realistic_policy_on_international_carbon_offsets/ (accessed 22 September 2010). [PLUS MAINSTREAM PRESS] 41 UNFCCC website: http://cdm.unfccc.int/Projects/rejected.html (accessed 22 September 2010). 41 K. Umamaheswaran, Axel Michaelowa,2006, Additionality and Sustainable Development Issues Regarding CDM Projects in Energy Efficiency Sector, HWWA Discussion Paper 346, Hamburg 2006, Axel Michaelowa, 2009, Interpreting the Additionality of CDM Projects: Changes in Additionality Definitions and Regulatory Practices over time, in, David Freestone and Charlotte Streck (Eds.), Legal Aspects of Carbon Trading: Kyoto, Copenhagen and Beyond (Oxford University Press, 2009), p. 248-271, 257. 42 Joelle de Sepibus (2009), The environmental integrity of the CDM mechanism – A legal analysis of its institutional and procedural shortcomings, nccr trade regulation, swiss national center of competence in research, Working Paper No 2009/24. 43 IETA, 2007, Submission to the UNFCCC regarding the best practice examples on the demonstration of additionality to assist the development of project design documents, in particular for small-scale project activities, 2007, http://cdm.unfccc.int/public_inputs/dev_PDDs/index.html; IETA objects to the additionality which exposes every project “to a highly subjective assessment of its CDM eligibility and allows for secondguessing by the EB” (accessed 8 September 2010). 44 Michael W. Wara, 2008, Measuring the Clean Development Mechanism’s Performance and Potential, Stanford Law School, Working Paper Series, available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1086242 (accessed 10 May 2010). 45 H.W. Au Yong, 2009, Technical Paper: Investment Additionality in the CDM, ecometrica paper, January 2009. 46 Sandra Greiner; Axel Michaelowa, (2003): Defining Investment Additionality for CDM projects practical approaches, in: Energy Policy, 31, p. 1007-1015; H.W. Au Yong (2009), Technical Paper: Investment Additionality in the CDM, ecometrica paper, January 2009; Johannes Alexeew, Linda Bergset, Kristin Meyer, Juliane Petersen, Lambert Schneider, Charlotte Unger, 2010, An analysis of the relationship between the additionality of CDM projects and their contribution to sustainable development, Int Environ Agreements DOI 10.1007/s10784-0109121-y, published online on 3 March 2010. 47 В IETA Position on Additionality, Position Paper of the International Emission Trading Organization, http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/download.php?docID=1243 (accessed 18 July 2010); Catrinus Jepma (2003): Credits for Mozart, in: Joint Implementation Quarterly, 9, 1, p. 1; Mark C. Trexler, D.J. Broekhoff, L.H. Kosloff 10В В the subjectivity of investment additionality has been identified and it was suggested to refer “behavioral” additionality instead, since it is the behavior of the actors that is at issue. 48 The conduction of independent financial analysis requires the disclosure of information, which companies may be as reluctant as governments to disclose. The reliance on aggregated information provided by the project sponsors makes independent review difficult and may open more opportunity for cheating. 49 The additionality testing of GHG activities is therefore prone to commit two types of errors: approval of nonadditional and exclusion of valid activities. 50 Today, additionality testing has become an вЂ�arms race’ between the project proponents and the regulators. Regulators learn to understand and detect arguments that have low credibility while project participants try to find loopholes and weaken the rules. 51 In such atmosphere, the objectivity of the testing has become secondary. While the additionality test limits the number of overall CER supply, it is almost impossible to say whether the projects that pass the test are all additional. This is particularly true as even supporters of the current additionality test concede that the executive board’s tendency to follow вЂ�fashions’ of rejecting certain project types without prior warning, gives reasons for concern. 52 Almost 15 years after the adoption of the Kyoto Protocol, the investment analysis still waits to be replaced by more objective evaluation methods. 3.2. Equity Implications of the CDM Additionality Test Additionality concerns in the CDM are based on the argument that the CDM as offsetting mechanism does not create any additional environmental benefits over the reductions mandated by the Kyoto Protocol in industrialized countries. The CDM is thus described as вЂ�zero sum’ game for the atmosphere. This argument implies that emission reductions taken by measures applied within the cap are contributing to the overall reduction of GHG emissions, while those outside of the cap do not. Those that fear that CERs could have an inflationary effect on the emissions budget of the entire Kyoto system 53 start from the assumption that the integrity of activities implemented within the context of the emission caps established by the Kyoto systems is higher than those implemented without that system. This is however only true if the overall cap on emissions is п‚· ambitious enough to lead to an overall reduction of emissions; В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В (2006), A stasticallt-driven approach to offset-based GHG additionality determinations: What can we learn? Sustainable Development Law & Policy, 4 (2), p. 30-30.В 48 Stephen Meyers (1999), Additionality of Emissions Reductions From Clean Development Mechanism Projects: Issues and Options for Project-Level Assessment; LBNL-43704, work supported by the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency through the U.S. Department of Energy under Contract No. DE-AC03-76SFOO098. 49 It is important to note that the risk of cheating is not new to the Kyoto Protocol whether applying to finance or GHG emissions. The lack of good-faith requirements governing funding requests has also been identified as risk under the Montreal Protocol. J.M. Patlis (1992),The Multilateral Fund of the Montreal Protocol, Cornell International Law Report, vol. 25 no. 1 , p. 181-230, 205. 50 Kenneth Chomitz, 1998, Baselines for Greenhouse Gas Reductions: Problems, Precedents, Solutions, prepared for the World Bank Carbon Offsets Unit, Development Research Group, World Bank, Washington, DC. 51 Axel Michaelowa, 2009, Interpreting the Additionality of CDM Projects: Changes in Additionality Definitions and Regulatory Practices over time, in, David Freestone and Charlotte Streck (Eds.), Legal Aspects of Carbon Trading: Kyoto, Copenhagen and Beyond (Oxford University Press, 2009), p. 248-271, 270. 52 Axel Michaelowa, 2009, Interpreting the Additionality of CDM Projects: Changes in Additionality Definitions and Regulatory Practices over time, in, David Freestone and Charlotte Streck (Eds.), Legal Aspects of Carbon Trading: Kyoto, Copenhagen and Beyond (Oxford University Press, 2009), p. 248-271, 270. [check] 53 Axel Michaelowa, 2009, Interpreting the Additionality of CDM Projects: Changes in Additionality Definitions and Regulatory Practices over time, in, David Freestone and Charlotte Streck (Eds.), Legal Aspects of Carbon Trading: Kyoto, Copenhagen and Beyond (Oxford University Press, 2009), p. 248-271, 249. 11В В п‚· п‚· real, enforceable and likely to incentivize compliance among Annex-B Kyoto parties; the offsets created and traded among Annex I parties need to be real and additional. These conditions are not fulfilled in the current Kyoto commitment period where a hefty overallocation of assigned amount units to economies in transition, most notably Ukraine and the Russian Federation creates an overall surplus of assigned amounts. Canada, an Annex I party, has openly stated that it would not meet its Kyoto target. 54 The absence of a strict enforcement mechanism may leave such instance of willing and planned incompliance unsanctioned. Whether the offsets created within Annex-B Kyoto parties, in particular those created under Article 3.4 of the Kyoto Protocol are real and measurable remains also doubtful. There is a risk that large amount of non-additional offsets from land-use activities are counted towards Annex I targets. 55 The overallocation of assigned amount units, the lack of enforcement mechanisms, and loosely controlled land-use offsets create serious problems for the environmental integrity of the Kyoto system. These problems do justify not any largesse with respect to individual CDM projects, but they at least allow raising the question of double standards. It seems that emission reductions in developing countries are required to be of a much higher environmental quality than those in developed countries. Such finding is at a minimum surprising in the light of the accepted principle of common-but-differentiated responsibilities; the polluter pays principle; and the mandated additionality of finance. While environmental integrity has to be at the core of any emission trading system, the current interpretation of additionality in the CDM puts into question the premise of the Kyoto Protocol that developing countries would be exempt from emission reduction targets. BAU emissions in developing countries are permitted under the Kyoto Protocol and hence legitimate objects for offsetting activities. 56 The CDM additionality test establishes that BAU emission reductions could not serve as offsets for Annex I countries. By not crediting these emission reductions, the current CDM practice introduces de facto a crediting baseline as developing country target. The fact that developing countries have not adopted emission reduction targets influences the debate on CDM and additionality since there seems to be a sentiment among many that countries that have not adopted (whatever lose) target should not profiteer from the CDM, in particular not when the projects are stake are very profitable or have few obvious sustainable development benefits. 4. Way Forward The negotiations of a post-2012 climate agreement open the door for a reform of the existing mechanisms and the definition of new incentive mechanisms for emission reductions in developed and developing countries. At this point it is uncertain on whether the CDM in its current form will survive beyond 2012. It is strongly supported by developing countries, but receives harsh critique from many industrialized countries, in particular the within the US. 57 But with or without CDM, the discussion on additionality of emission reductions (and finance) is almost certain to continue. The current negotiations under the В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В 54В Canada is unable to achieve this level of greenhouse gas reduction, then Environment Minister Rona Ambrose said В at a 2006 United Nations meeting in Nairobi, Kenya. В 55 The complete absence of a discussion around the application of Article 3.4 Kyoto Protocol remains surprising. Article 3.4 regulates the offsetting emissions within the Annex I cap by Annex I emission reductions from the land-use sector generated outside the cap. It deals also with possibly large quantities of emissions burdened by measurements plagued by inconsistencies and errors. 56 Benito Mueller, Additionality in the Clean Development Mechanism, Why and What?, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies EV 44, March 1999, p.9. 57 В [add source]В 12В В UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol therefore open the door for a critical review and reform of additionality testing. There is no uniform or proven way to test additionality. Existing mandatory and voluntary carbon standards apply at least dozen different interpretations, tests and criteria for proving the additionality of emission reductions. 58 Regulators and private standard organizations have adopted and adapted the additionality principle and testing of the CDM to their particular requirements, needs and world view. The various types of additionality reflect the attempt to ensure that climate benefits are supplemental and real, but they also reflect the choice and preference of a standard towards particular project types. Table 1 summarizes the most common forms of addititionality. 59 Different standards apply subsets of the list in combination or as alternative. TableВ 1В AdditionalityВ Tests Category Environmental aspects Type of additionality GHG additionality Unit additionality Project additionality Financial and investment aspects Investment additionality Sales or capital additionality Legal, regulatory and institutional aspects applying to regulators and states Legal, regulatory and institutional aspects applying to non-state actors Reporting additionality Compliance additionality Incentive additionality Technological additionality Barrier additionality Common-practice additionality Test Activity results in GHG emission reductions or removals compared to the baseline scenario Activity reduces GHG emissions below levels of technologies normally used to produce the same product Activity happens because of carbon finance Activity needs to be economically viable, or an attractive investment proposition, only when taking carbon finance into account Activity would not have been undertaken without revenues from the sale of carbon credits Accounting on national level avoids double crediting of emission reductions or removals Activities need to be additional to statutory requirements. Activities need to go beyond existing incentives (eg subsidies) Activities need to apply a particular technologies Activity overcomes particular implementation barriers Activity employs technologies or practices that are not already in common use. В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В Gregory Valatin, Carbon Additionality: A review , Discussion Paper, Forest Research, November 2009. The table is based on the categorization of Gregory Valatin, Carbon Additionality: A review, Discussion Paper, Forest Research, November 2009. It has been updated and modified by the author. 58 59 13В В Institutional additionality Date additionality Jurisdiction additionality Activity is undertaken outside of statutory emission reduction targets Activities starts after a particular date Activities is implemented in a particular area or by a particular group The criteria of the various standards reflect less a proven truth but policy choices that steer behavior and investments into a particular direction. Additionality is therefore always a reflection of political choices. Additionality testing plays a crucial role in determining every aspect of market supply (i.e. the nature and supply of recognized reductions or GHG credits), including: п‚· п‚· п‚· п‚· The quantity of supply of offsets available to the market; The costs of the offsets available; The nature of projects that qualify for offset finance; The quantity of “non-additional” emission reductions in the final supply pool and the quantity of real emission reductions not eligible for offset supply. At the end, there is no right way to test additionality. The example of the CDM shows that policy makers cannot bypass this obligation by simply directing a technical body to design additionality standards. 60 Recognizing that the testing of additionality is inherently political, allows the regulator to apply political considerations that steer investment into offsets and open new sources of supply. Other than in the current CDM, where additionality pretends to be objective while the CDM executive board may reduce supply through the tightening of review and interpretation of additionality, an open discussion about CDM project criteria and supply control would introduce transparency and objectivity into the debate around additionality. There are various paths that potentially lead improving the current system of GHG additionality testing: The WWF has proposed to make the additionality tool mandatory (confirming positively the current status quo), to tighten the test further and provide clear guidance of the requirements. 61 The International Emissions Trading Organization (IETA) on the other hand advocates the idea of establishing sectoral benchmarks, which should be used to demonstrate additionality as well as defining the baselines in the CDM. IETA claims that benchmarks would bring objectivity, transparency and integrity in the demonstration of additionality, the setting of the baseline and validation of projects. 62 Benito Mueller proposes to rely on historic trend interpretation that would define permissible emissions and any В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В 60 Mark C. Trexler, Derik J. Broekhoff, Laura Kosloff (2006), Statistically-Driven Approach to Offset-Based GHG Additionality Determinations: What Can We Learn, Vol 6 Sustainable Dev. L. & Pol'y 30 (2005-2006), p. 30. 61 Axel Michaelowa, 2007, Submission to the UNFCCC regarding the best practice examples on the demonstration of additionality to assist the development of project design documents, in particular for small-scale project activities, 2007, http://cdm.unfccc.int/public_inputs/dev_PDDs/index.html (accessed 8 Mat 2010, submission y Kirsty Clough for the WWF). Some of such requirements fall however outside of what is realistically possible to provide by project participants. Such as the requirement of providing written proof from the three largest commercial banks in the host country and one international commercial bank that they are not willing to provide a loan or other financing to the project despite its high IRR. Experience shows that banks are generally reluctant to provide such letter. 62 http://cdm.unfccc.int/public_inputs/dev_PDDs/index.html (Catherine Sachweh for IETA). 14В В reduction below that integrity baseline would be defined be additional. 63 The main difference between that method and the “what would happen otherwise” approach is that the forecast can be assessed with regards to their accuracy, once the future has happened, as it were. The superior transparency of such approach would probably even outweigh receiving less CERs in cases which would be additional under both interpretations. 64 All proposed methods have their particular problems associated with it. However, the establishment of criteria establishing positive additionality of particular technologies, project types or groups is easy to implement and, if applied conservatively, less prone to continuous controversy than the project-by-project additionality testing. Standardized approaches are, if generally accepted, less controversial in their implementation than project specific testing methods. An example for a clearly regulated additionality test could be found in the cap-and-trade system discussed in the context of the proposal for an American Clean Energy and Security Act (ACESA) from the year 2009. 65 ACESA mandates the development of a standardized additionality test based on the following criteria: To qualify as offsets under ACESA, GHG activities are п‚· п‚· п‚· п‚· not required by or undertaken to comply with any law, including any regulation or consent order; were (generally) not commenced prior to January 1, 2009; are not receiving support of particular subsidies; and exceed the activity GHG baseline. 66 ACESA would have required a qualified test of GHG additionality by adding the requirement of a specific project start date and regulatory additionality. Such additionality testing is less vague and puts emphasis on standardized testing methods. 67 Standardized approaches have the advantage of streamlining the process and increasing transparency. 68 The disadvantage of standardized approaches is that they are less flexible do not allow site specific conditions to be taken into account. 5. Conclusions The UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol use additionality in difference contexts, but neither of the two treaties bothers to define the term. The UNFCCC requires additionality of financial support for developing countries; the Kyoto Protocol adds the demand of additionality of emission reductions for their eligibility to offset emissions that fall under the target of developed country parties. In both cases the requirement is vague and hard to operationalize. But the question whether the financial resources of developed countries are truly additional has never received the same level of attention, intellectual and ideological engagement as the question on whether CDM emission reductions are truly additional. В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В Benito Mueller, Additionality in the Clean Development Mechanism, Why and What?, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies EV 44, March 1999, p.15. 64 Benito Mueller, Additionality in the Clean Development Mechanism, Why and What?, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies EV 44, March 1999, p.16. 65 В The American Clean Energy and Security Act, which was passed by the U.S. House on Friday, June 26th; http://energycommerce.house.gov/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=1560&Itemid=1 (accessed 18 July 2010).В 66 ACESA, Sec. 734. 67 В Generally, positive lists and clear standards point towards an easier and less controversial establishment of additionality (see also the London Amendments to the Montreal Protocol).В 68 В Climate Leaders, Climate Action Registry, CCX, RGGI and NSW GGAS are among the programs and protocols that rely more heavily on standardized approaches.В 63 15В В The failure to apply clear definitions has proven to be more damaging in the context of the concrete investments of the CDM than in relation to public budgeting, which remains discretionary and beyond reach of the international and national audiences. Investments and projects in contrary are tangible. They relate to actors and action which evoke feelings, opinions, and sentiments (Who wants a chemical giant make money out of slightly less contaminating practice by claiming carbon credits?); short subjectivity. The CDM’s relative transparency compared to the opaque budgeting processes of developed country governments makes the struggle to come to a satisfactory solution only more obvious; and the CDM more prone and vulnerable to criticism. The establishment of clear criteria for CDM additionality would address the insecurities that are associated with the current additionality testing. Project proponents have generally argued in favour of GHG additionality. 69 Their concerns do not relate so much to the testing per-se, but to a process that has become increasingly lengthy and unpredictable. 70 Provided that criteria for additionality are sufficiently conservative, they would safeguard the environmental integrity of offsets and could even generate a surplus for the atmosphere. At the same time, predictability would remove investment risk and channel more funds into emission reducing activities, a win-win for development and the global climate. В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В В IETA, 2005, Position on Additionality, Geneva 2006. Matthias Krey and Heike Santen, 2009, Trying to Catch up with the Executive Board: Regulatory Decision-Making and its Impact on CDM Performance, in: David Freestone and Charlotte Streck (Eds.), Legal Aspects of Carbon Trading: Kyoto, Copenhagen and Beyond (Oxford University Press, 2009), p. 232-257, 232. 69 70 16В В
© Copyright 2024 Paperzz