c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics Comparative statics 1 The maximum theorems max ๐ (x, ๐ฝ) xโ๐บ(๐ฝ) Let ๐ฃ(๐ฝ) = max ๐ (x, ๐ฝ) ๐(๐ฝ) = arg max ๐ (x, ๐ฝ) xโ๐บ(๐ฝ) Objective function Constraint correspondence Value function Solution correspondence Monotone maximum theorem Theorem 2.1 supermodular, increasing weakly increasing increasing increasing xโ๐บ(๐ฝ) Continuous maximum theorem Theorem 2.3 continuous Convex maximum theorem Theorem 3.10 concave Smooth maximum theorem Theorem 6.1 smooth continuous, compact-valued continuous convex compact-valued nonempty, uhc convex-valued smooth regular locally smooth locally smooth 2 The envelope theorems 2.1 Envelope theorem 1 ๐ฃ(๐ฝ) = max ๐ (x, ๐ฝ) โ ๐ฅ โ๐บ โ = ๐ (x (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ) so that ๐ฃ โฒ (๐ฝ) = ๐x โxโ + ๐๐ฝ โ๐ฝ The ๏ฌrst-order conditions determining xโ are ๐x = ๐๐x 1 concave c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics Moveover, xโ (๐ฝ) satis๏ฌes the constraint as a identity ๐(xโ (๐ฝ)) = 0 =โ ๐x โxโ =0 โ๐ฝ Substituting, we conclude that ๐ฃ โฒ (๐ฝ) = ๐๐ฝ Example 1 (Chip producer) It is characteristic of microchip production technology that a proportion of output is defective. Consider a small producer for whom the price of good chips ๐ is ๏ฌxed. Suppose that proportion 1 โ ๐ of the ๏ฌrmโs chips are defective and cannot be sold. Let ๐(๐ฆ) denote the ๏ฌrmโs total cost function where ๐ฆ is the number of chips (including defectives) produced. Suppose that with experience, the yield of good chips ๐ increases. How does this a๏ฌect the ๏ฌrmโs production ๐ฆ? Does the ๏ฌrm compensate for the increased yield by reducing production, or does it celebrate by increasing production? The ๏ฌrmโs optimization problem is ๐ฃ(๐) = max ๐๐๐ฆ โ ๐(๐ฆ) ๐ฆ = ๐๐๐ฆ โ โ ๐(๐ฆ โ) โ๐ฆ โ โ๐ฆ โ โ ๐โฒ (๐ฆ โ) ๐ฃ โฒ (๐) = ๐๐ฆ โ + ๐๐ โ๐ โ๐ โ โ๐ฆ = ๐๐ฆ โ + (๐๐ โ ๐โฒ (๐ฆ โ )) โ๐ But the ๏ฌrst-order condition de๏ฌning ๐ฆ โ (๐) is ๐๐ โ ๐โฒ (๐ฆ โ ) = 0 so that ๐ฃ โฒ (๐) = ๐๐ฆ โ > 0 Further, we can deduce that ๐ฆ โ (๐) = so that ๐ฃ โฒ (๐) ๐ ๐ฃ โฒโฒ (๐) โ๐ฆ โ (๐) = โฅ0 โ๐ ๐ since the pro๏ฌt function is convex. 2 c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics 2.2 Envelope theorem 2 ๐ฃ(๐ฝ) = โmax ๐ (x, ๐ฝ) ๐ฅ โ๐บ(๐ฝ) = ๐ (xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ) โxโ ๐ฃ โฒ (๐ฝ) = ๐x + ๐๐ฝ โ๐ฝ The ๏ฌrst-order conditions determining xโ are ๐x = ๐๐x Moveover, xโ (๐ฝ) satis๏ฌes the constraint as a identity ๐(xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ) = 0 =โ ๐x or โxโ + ๐๐ฝ = 0 โ๐ฝ โxโ = โ๐๐ฝ ๐x โ๐ฝ Substituting, we conclude that ๐ฃ โฒ (๐ฝ) = ๐๐ฝ โ ๐๐๐ฝ = ๐ฟ๐ฝ Example 2 (Consumer problem) ๐ฃ(p, ๐) = max ๐ข(x) (1) subject to p x = ๐ (2) xโ๐ ๐ ๐ฟ = ๐ข(x) โ ๐(p๐ x โ ๐) โ๐ฃ = ๐ฟ๐ = ๐ โ๐ โ๐ฃ = ๐ฟ๐๐ = โ๐๐ฅโ๐ โ๐๐ which leads immediately to Royโs identity xโ๐ (p, ๐) 3 =โ โ๐ฃ โ๐๐ โ๐ฃ โ๐ Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved 2.3 Smooth envelope theorem (Corollary 6.1.1) Assume that x0 is a strict local maximum of max ๐ (x, ๐ฝ) xโ๐บ(๐ฝ) where ๐บ(๐ฝ) = { x โ ๐ : g(x, ๐ฝ) โค 0 }. By the smooth maximum theorem, there exists a neighbourhood ฮฉ around ๐ฝ 0 and function xโ such that ๐ฃ(๐ฝ) = ๐ (xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ) for every ๐ฝ โ ฮฉ and ๐ฃ is di๏ฌerentiable. Applying the chain rule ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ฃ[๐ฝ] = ๐x xโ๐ฝ + ๐๐ฝ โ โ indirect direct What do we know of the indirect e๏ฌect? First If xโ is optimal, it must satisfy the Kuhn-Tucker conditions ๐x = ๐๐0 gx and ๐๐0 g(x, ๐ฝ) = 0 (3) at (x0 , ๐0 ) where ๐0 is the unique Lagrange multiplier associated with x0 . Second The solution xโ (๐ฝ) satis๏ฌes the constraint g(xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ) = 0 for all ๐ฝ โ ฮฉ. Another application of the chain rule gives gx xโ๐ฝ + g๐ฝ = 0 =โ ๐๐0 gx xโ๐ฝ = โ๐๐ g๐ฝ (4) Using (3) and (4), the indirect e๏ฌect is ๐x xโ๐ฝ = ๐๐0 ๐x xโ๐ฝ = โ๐๐ g๐ฝ and therefore ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ฃ[๐ฝ] = ๐๐ฝ โ ๐๐0 g๐ฝ = ๐ฟ๐ฝ (5) where ๐ฟ denotes the Lagrangean ๐ฟ(x, ๐ฝ, ๐) = ๐ (x, ๐ฝ)โ๐๐ g(x, ๐ฝ). This is the envelope theorem, which states that the derivative of the value function is equal to the partial derivative of the Lagrangean evaluated at the optimal solution (x0 , ๐0 ). In the special case in which the feasible set ๐บ is independent of the parameters, g๐ฝ = 0 and (5) becomes ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ฃ[๐ฝ] = ๐๐ฝ The indirect e๏ฌect is zero, and the only impact on ๐ฃ of a change in ๐ฝ is the direct e๏ฌect f๐ฝ . 4 Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved 2.4 General envelope theorem (Theorem 6.2) The assumptions required for Corollary 6.1.1 are stringent. Where the feasible set is independent of the parameters, a more general result can be given. Let xโ be the solution correspondence of the constrained optimization problem max ๐ (x, ๐ฝ) xโ๐บ in which ๐ : ๐บ × ฮ โ โ is continuous and ๐บ compact. Suppose that ๐ is continuously di๏ฌerentiable in ๐, that is ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ [x, ๐ฝ] is continuous in ๐บ × ฮ. Then the value function ๐ฃ(๐) = sup ๐ (x, ๐ฝ) ๐ฅโ๐บ is di๏ฌerentiable wherever xโ is single-valued with ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ฃ[๐] = ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ [x(๐ฝ), ๐ฝ]. Proof. To simplify the proof, assume that xโ is single-valued for every ๐ฝ โ ฮ Then ๐ฃ(๐ฝ) = ๐ (xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ) for every ๐ฝ โ ฮ For any ๐ฝ โ= ๐ฝ 0 โ ฮ ) ( ) ( ๐ฃ(๐ฝ) โ ๐ฃ(๐ฝ 0 ) = ๐ xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ โ ๐ xโ (๐ฝ 0 ), ๐ฝ0 ) ( ) ( โฅ ๐ xโ (๐ฝ 0 ), ๐ฝ โ ๐ xโ (๐ฝ 0 ), ๐ฝ0 = ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ [xโ (๐ฝ 0 ), ๐ฝ 0 ](๐ฝ โ ๐ฝ 0 ) + ๐(๐ฝ) โฅ๐ฝ โ ๐ฝ 0 โฅ with ๐(๐ฝ) โ 0 as ๐ฝ โ ๐ฝ 0 . On the other hand, by the mean value theorem ¯ โ (๐ฝ, ๐ฝ 0 ) such that (Theorem 4.1) there exist ๐ฝ ) ( ) ( ๐ฃ(๐ฝ) โ ๐ฃ(๐ฝ 0 ) = ๐ xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ โ ๐ xโ (๐ฝ 0 ), ๐ฝ0 ) ( ) ( โค ๐ xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ โ ๐ xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ 0 ¯ โ ๐ฝ0) = ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ [xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ](๐ฝ Letting ๐ฝ โ ๐ฝ 0 ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ [xโ (๐ฝ 0 ), ๐ฝ 0 ](๐ฝ โ ๐ฝ 0 ) ๐ฃ(๐ฝ) โ ๐ฃ(๐ฝ 0 ) ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ [xโ (๐ฝ 0 ), ๐ฝ 0 ](๐ฝ โ ๐ฝ 0 ) โค lim โค lim lim ๐ฝโ๐ฝ0 ๐ฝโ๐ฝ0 ๐ฝโ๐ฝ0 โฅ๐ฝ โ ๐ฝ 0 โฅ โฅ๐ฝ โ ๐ฝ 0 โฅ โฅ๐ฝ โ ๐ฝ 0 โฅ ๐ฃ is di๏ฌerentiable (Exercise 4.3) and ๐ท๐ฃ[๐] = ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ [xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ] where ๐ท๐ฝ ๐ [xโ (๐ฝ), ๐ฝ] denotes the partial derivative of ๐ with respect to ๐ฝ โก holding x constant at x = xโ (๐ฝ). 5 c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics โณ Note that there is no requirement in Theorem 6.2 that ๐ is di๏ฌerentiable with respect to the decision variables x, only with respect to the parameters. The practical importance of dispensing with di๏ฌerentiability with respect to x is that Theorem 6.2 applies even when the feasible set is discrete (See Example 6.2). โ ๐ฃ(๐) ๐ (๐ฅ1 , ๐) ๐ (๐ฅ2 , ๐) ๐ (๐ฅ3 , ๐) ๐ 3 Comparative statics of optimization models There are four di๏ฌerent approaches to comparative statics of optimization models โ Revealed preference approach โ Envelope theorem approach โ Monotone maximum theorem approach โ Implicit function theorem approach 3.1 Revealed preference approach A competitive ๏ฌrmโs optimization problem is to choose a feasible production plan y โ ๐ to maximize total pro๏ฌt max p โ y yโ๐ Consequently, if y1 maximizes pro๏ฌt when prices are p1 , then p1 โ y1 โฅ p โ y for every y โ ๐ Similarly, if y2 maximizes pro๏ฌt when prices are p2 , then p2 โ y2 โฅ p โ y for every y โ ๐ 6 c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics In particular p1 โ y1 โฅ p1 โ y2 and p2 โ y2 โฅ p2 โ y1 Adding these inequalities p1 โ y1 + p2 โ y2 โฅ p1 โ y2 + p2 โ y1 Rearranging p2 โ (y2 โ y1 ) โฅ p1 โ (y2 โ y1 ) and therefore (p2 โ p1 ) โ (y2 โ y1 ) โฅ 0 or ๐ โ (๐1๐ โ ๐2๐ )(๐ฆ๐2 โ ๐ฆ๐2 ) โฅ 0 (6) ๐=1 If prices change from p1 to p2 , the optimal production plan must change in such a way as to satisfy the inequality (6). For a change in the price of a single good ๐ (๐2๐ = ๐1๐ for every ๐ โ= ๐), (6) implies that (๐2๐ โ ๐1๐ )(๐ฆ๐2 โ ๐ฆ๐1) โฅ 0 or ๐2๐ > ๐1๐ =โ ๐ฆ๐2 โฅ ๐ฆ๐1 3.2 The envelope theorem approach Letting ๐ (y, p) = p โ y denote the objective function, the competitive ๏ฌrm solves max ๐ (y, p) yโ๐ Note that ๐ is di๏ฌerentiable with ๐ทp ๐ [y, p] = y. Applying the envelope theorem 6.2, the pro๏ฌt function ฮ (p) = sup ๐ (y, p) yโ๐ is di๏ฌerentiable wherever the supply correspondence yโ is single-valued with ๐ทp ฮ [p] = ๐ทp ๐ [yโ (p), p] = yโ (p) or (7) yโ (p) = โฮ (p) which is known as Hotellingโs lemma. โณ The practical signi๏ฌcance of Hotellingโs lemma is that, if we know the pro๏ฌt function, we can calculate the supply function by straightforward di๏ฌerentiation instead of solving a constrained optimization problem. 7 c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics โณ Its theoretical signi๏ฌcance is more important. Hotellingโs lemma enables us to deduce the properties of the supply function yโ from the already established properties of the pro๏ฌt function. In particular, we know that the pro๏ฌt function is convex (Example 3.42). From Hotellingโs lemma (7), we deduce that the derivative of the supply function is equal to the second derivative of the pro๏ฌt function ๐ทyโ [p] = ๐ท 2 ฮ [p] or equivalently that the Jacobian of the supply function is equal to the Hessian of the pro๏ฌt function. ๐ฝyโ (p) = ๐ปฮ (p) Since ฮ is smooth and convex, its Hessian ๐ป(p) is symmetric (Theorem 4.2) and nonnegative de๏ฌnite (Proposition 4.1) for all p. Consequently, the Jacobian of the supply function ๐ฝyโ is also symmetric and nonnegative de๏ฌnite. This implies for all goods ๐ and ๐ ๐ท๐๐ ๐ฆ๐โ [p] โฅ 0 ๐ท๐๐ ๐ฆ๐โ [p] = ๐ท๐๐ ๐ฆ๐โ[p] Nonnegativity Symmetry In a similar fashion, we can deduce โ Shephardโs lemma (Example 6.7) โ Royโs identity (Example 6.8) From the latter, we can easily derive the Slutsky equation (Example 6.9). 3.3 The implicit function theorem approach The ๏ฌrst-order conditions of an equality constrained optimization problem constitute a system of equations. ๐(x; ๐ฝ) = 0 Provided the Jacobian (๐ทx ๐[x; ๐ฝ]) of this system is non-singular, we can use the implicit function theorem to solve for xโ in terms of ๐ฝ. We illustrate by means of an example. 8 Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved Example Recall again the chip maker, whose optimization problem is max ๐๐๐ฆ โ ๐(๐ฆ) ๐ฆ The ๏ฌrst-order and second-order conditions for pro๏ฌt maximization are ๐(๐ฆ, ๐, ๐) = ๐๐ โ ๐โฒ (๐ฆ) = 0 and ๐ท๐ฆ ๐[๐ฆ, ๐, ๐] = โ๐โฒโฒ (๐ฆ) < 0 The second-order condition requires increasing marginal cost. Assuming ๐ is ๐ถ 2 , the ๏ฌrst-order condition implicitly de๏ฌnes a function ๐ฆ(๐). Di๏ฌerentiating the ๏ฌrst-order condition with respect to ๐, we deduce that ๐ = ๐โฒโฒ (๐ฆ)๐ท๐ฝ โ๐๐ก๐๐ฆ or ๐ท๐ ๐ฆ = ๐ ๐โฒโฒ (๐ฆ) which is positive by the second-order condition. An increase in yield ๐ is analogous to an increase in product price ๐, inducing an increase in output ๐ฆ. โณ Examples 6.15 and 6.16 apply the same technique to deduce the comparative statics of a competitive multi-input ๏ฌrm. 4 References โ Milgrom, P., and I. Segal (2000), Envelope Theorems for Arbitrary Choice Sets. Department of Economics, Stanford University: mimeo. โ Silberberg, E. (1990), The Structure of Economics: A Mathematical Analysis (2nd edition). New York, NY: McGraw-Hill. 9 c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics 5 Homework 1. Prove Proposition 5.2, that is if ๐ and g are ๐ถ 2 and ๐ท๐[xโ ] is of full rank, then the value function ๐ฃ(c) = sup{ ๐ (x) : g(x) = c } is di๏ฌerentiable with โ๐ฃ(c) = ๐, where ๐ = (๐1 , ๐2 , . . . , ๐๐ ) are the Lagrange multipliers associated with xโ . 2. Suppose that the cost function of a monopolist changes from ๐1 (๐ฆ) to ๐2 (๐ฆ) in such a way that 0 < ๐โฒ1 (๐ฆ) < ๐โฒ2 (๐ฆ) for every ๐ฆ > 0 Let ๐1 denote the pro๏ฌt maximizing price with the cost function ๐1 (๐ฆ) and let ๐ฆ1 be the corresponding output. Similarly let ๐2 and ๐ฆ2 be the pro๏ฌt maximizing price and output when the costs are given by ๐2 (๐ฆ). (a) Show that ๐2 (๐ฆ1 ) โ ๐2 (๐ฆ2 ) โฅ ๐1 (๐ฆ1 ) โ ๐1 (๐ฆ2 ) (8) (b) The โFundamental Theorem of Calculusโ states: If ๐ โฒ (๐ฅ) is a continuous function on [a,b], then โซ ๐ ๐ โฒ (๐ฅ)๐๐ฅ ๐ (๐) โ ๐ (๐) = ๐ Apply this to inequality (8) to deduce that ๐ฆ1 โฅ ๐ฆ2 and therefore that ๐1 โค ๐2 . (c) State concisely the proposition you have just proved. 3. Assume that a competitive ๏ฌrm produces a single output ๐ฆ from ๐ inputs x = (๐ฅ1 , ๐ฅ2 , . . . , ๐ฅ๐ ) according to the production function ๐ฆ = ๐ (x) so as to maximize pro๏ฌt ฮ (w, ๐) = max ๐๐ (x) โ w โ x x Assume that there is a unique optimum for every ๐ and w. Show that the input demand ๐ฅโ๐ (w, ๐) and supply ๐ฆ โ (w, ๐) functions have the following properties: ๐ท๐ ๐ฆ๐โ[w, ๐] โฅ 0 ๐ท๐ค๐ ๐ฅโ๐ [w, ๐] โค 0 ๐ท๐ค๐ ๐ฅโ๐ [w, ๐] = ๐ท๐ค๐ ๐ฅโ๐ [w, ๐] ๐ท๐ ๐ฅโ๐ [w, ๐] = โ๐ท๐ค๐ ๐ฆ โ[w, ๐] 10 Upward sloping supply Downward sloping demand Symmetry Reciprocity c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics Solutions 7 1 The Lagrangean for this problem is ( ) ๐ฟ = ๐ (x) โ ๐๐ g(x) โ c By Corollary 6.1.1 2 โ๐ฃ(c) = ๐ทc ๐ฟ = ๐ (a) With cost function ๐1 (๐ฆ1 ), the ๏ฌrms pro๏ฌt is ฮ = ๐๐ฆ โ ๐1 (๐ฆ) Since this is maximised at ๐1 and ๐ฆ1 (although the monopolist could have sold ๐ฆ2 at price ๐2 ) ๐1 ๐ฆ1 โ ๐1 (๐ฆ1 ) โฅ ๐2 ๐ฆ2 โ ๐1 (๐ฆ2 ) Rearranging ๐1 ๐ฆ1 โ ๐2 ๐ฆ2 โฅ ๐1 (๐ฆ1 ) โ ๐1 (๐ฆ2 ) Similarly (1) ๐2 ๐ฆ2 โ ๐2 (๐ฆ2 ) โฅ ๐1 ๐ฆ1 โ ๐2 (๐ฆ1 ) which can be rearranged to yield ๐2 (๐ฆ1 ) โ ๐2 (๐ฆ2 ) โฅ ๐1 ๐ฆ1 โ ๐2 ๐ฆ2 Combining the previous inequality with (1) yields ๐2 (๐ฆ1 ) โ ๐2 (๐ฆ2 ) โฅ ๐1 (๐ฆ1 ) โ ๐1 (๐ฆ2 ) (b) Applying the Fundamental Theorem of Calculus to both sides, this implies โซ ๐ฆ1 โซ ๐ฆ1 โฒ ๐2 (๐ฆ)๐๐ฆ โฅ ๐โฒ1 (๐ฆ)๐๐ฆ or ๐ฆ2 โซ ๐ฆ1 ๐ฆ2 ๐โฒ2 (๐ฆ) ๐โฒ2 (๐ฆ)๐๐ฆ โซ โ ๐ฆ2 ๐ฆ1 ๐ฆ2 ๐โฒ1 (๐ฆ)๐๐ฆ ๐โฒ1 (๐ฆ) โซ = ๐ฆ1 ๐ฆ2 (๐โฒ2 (๐ฆ) โ ๐โฒ1 (๐ฆ))๐๐ฆ โฅ 0 โ โฅ 0 for every ๐ฆ (by assumption), this implies that Since ๐ฆ2 โค ๐ฆ1 . Assuming the demand curve is downward sloping, this implies ๐2 โฅ ๐1 . 1 Lecture notes based on Foundations of Mathematical Economics c 2001 Michael Carter โ All rights reserved (c) There is an implicit requirement to utilize the Fundamental Theorem of Calculus, namely that ๐โฒ (๐ฆ) is continuous. With this proviso, we have shown that the monopoly price is increasing in marginal cost. Specifically we have shown: Assuming that a monopolistโs cost function is continously di๏ฌerentiable (in output), the pro๏ฌt maximizing monopoly price is an increasing (i.e. nondecreasing) function of marginal cost. 3 By Theorem 6.2 ๐ทw ฮ [w, ๐] = โxโ and ๐ท๐ ฮ [w, ๐] = ๐ฆ โ and therefore 2 ๐ท๐ ๐ฆ(๐, w) = ๐ท๐๐ ฮ (๐, w) โฅ 0 ๐ท๐ค๐ ๐ฅ๐ (๐, w) = โ๐ท๐ค2 ๐ ๐ค๐ ฮ (๐, w) โค 0 ๐ท๐ค๐ ๐ฅ๐ (๐, w) = โ๐ท๐ค2 ๐ ๐ค๐ ฮ (๐, w) = ๐ท๐ค๐ ๐ฅ๐ (๐, w) ๐ท๐ ๐ฅ๐ (๐, w) = โ๐ท๐ค2 ๐ ๐ ฮ (๐, w) = โ๐ท๐ค๐ ๐ฆ(๐, w) since ฮ is convex and therefore ๐ปฮ (w, ๐) is symmetric (Theorem 4.2) and nonnegative de๏ฌnite (Proposition 4.1). 2
© Copyright 2024 Paperzz