Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Evolution and Market Behavior with Endogenous Investment Rules Giulio Bottazzia a Pietro Dindoa,b,1 Istituto di Economia, Scuola Superiore Sant’Anna, Pisa b Department of Economics, Cornell University ASSET 2014, Aix-en-Provence November 7, 2014 1 Pietro Dindo is supported by a Marie Curie International Outgoing Fellowship within the 7th European Community Framework Programme Conclusion Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Research Question Market selection and long-run asset prices in a dynamic competitive exchange economy with heterogeneous traders. In particular • • • • • Does the Market Selection Hypothesis hold? Fitness measure? Is agents’ heterogeneity persistent and non-generic? When so, what are the consequences for asset pricing? Does it exist a never vanishing rule? We provide answers in a analytically tractable model (yet stochastic, behaviorally rich, equilibrium prices), by studying the local stability of representative agent equilibria. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Research Question Market selection and long-run asset prices in a dynamic competitive exchange economy with heterogeneous traders. In particular • • • • • Does the Market Selection Hypothesis hold? Fitness measure? Is agents’ heterogeneity persistent and non-generic? When so, what are the consequences for asset pricing? Does it exist a never vanishing rule? We provide answers in a analytically tractable model (yet stochastic, behaviorally rich, equilibrium prices), by studying the local stability of representative agent equilibria. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Research Question Market selection and long-run asset prices in a dynamic competitive exchange economy with heterogeneous traders. In particular • • • • • Does the Market Selection Hypothesis hold? Fitness measure? Is agents’ heterogeneity persistent and non-generic? When so, what are the consequences for asset pricing? Does it exist a never vanishing rule? We provide answers in a analytically tractable model (yet stochastic, behaviorally rich, equilibrium prices), by studying the local stability of representative agent equilibria. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Research Question Market selection and long-run asset prices in a dynamic competitive exchange economy with heterogeneous traders. In particular • • • • • Does the Market Selection Hypothesis hold? Fitness measure? Is agents’ heterogeneity persistent and non-generic? When so, what are the consequences for asset pricing? Does it exist a never vanishing rule? We provide answers in a analytically tractable model (yet stochastic, behaviorally rich, equilibrium prices), by studying the local stability of representative agent equilibria. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Some Background Market selection, “as if” hypothesis: Blume and Easley (1992) Evolution and Market Behavior. Irrational rules may dominate rational rules. In background work on log-optimal portfolio (Kelly, Breiman). Representative agent limit is generic. Optimal rules: Sandroni (2000, 2005), Blume and Easley (2006, 2009), Jouini-Napp (2007), Yan (2008). In complete markets, among expected utility maximizers with perfect foresight, only time-preferences and beliefs accuracy matter. Representative agent limit is generic. Evolutionary Finance: Work of Amir, Evstigneev, Hens, Schenk-Hoppe’ (2005-2009). Characterize the portfolio rule (named Generalized Kelly) that dominates among non price-dependent adapted rules. The rule is not log-optimal. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Some Background Market selection, “as if” hypothesis: Blume and Easley (1992) Evolution and Market Behavior. Irrational rules may dominate rational rules. In background work on log-optimal portfolio (Kelly, Breiman). Representative agent limit is generic. Optimal rules: Sandroni (2000, 2005), Blume and Easley (2006, 2009), Jouini-Napp (2007), Yan (2008). In complete markets, among expected utility maximizers with perfect foresight, only time-preferences and beliefs accuracy matter. Representative agent limit is generic. Evolutionary Finance: Work of Amir, Evstigneev, Hens, Schenk-Hoppe’ (2005-2009). Characterize the portfolio rule (named Generalized Kelly) that dominates among non price-dependent adapted rules. The rule is not log-optimal. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Some Background Market selection, “as if” hypothesis: Blume and Easley (1992) Evolution and Market Behavior. Irrational rules may dominate rational rules. In background work on log-optimal portfolio (Kelly, Breiman). Representative agent limit is generic. Optimal rules: Sandroni (2000, 2005), Blume and Easley (2006, 2009), Jouini-Napp (2007), Yan (2008). In complete markets, among expected utility maximizers with perfect foresight, only time-preferences and beliefs accuracy matter. Representative agent limit is generic. Evolutionary Finance: Work of Amir, Evstigneev, Hens, Schenk-Hoppe’ (2005-2009). Characterize the portfolio rule (named Generalized Kelly) that dominates among non price-dependent adapted rules. The rule is not log-optimal. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Some Background Market selection, “as if” hypothesis: Blume and Easley (1992) Evolution and Market Behavior. Irrational rules may dominate rational rules. In background work on log-optimal portfolio (Kelly, Breiman). Representative agent limit is generic. Optimal rules: Sandroni (2000, 2005), Blume and Easley (2006, 2009), Jouini-Napp (2007), Yan (2008). In complete markets, among expected utility maximizers with perfect foresight, only time-preferences and beliefs accuracy matter. Representative agent limit is generic. Evolutionary Finance: Work of Amir, Evstigneev, Hens, Schenk-Hoppe’ (2005-2009). Characterize the portfolio rule (named Generalized Kelly) that dominates among non price-dependent adapted rules. The rule is not log-optimal. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Framework and Findings • K Short-lived assets • I traders with general investment rules (endogenous, CRRA included) • Sequential trade in discrete time (Random Dynamical System) • No perfect foresight on prices (markets are not dynamically complete) We show that: • Expected log-growth rate of wealth determines fitness. • A never vanishing rule exists (S-rule). It is log-optimal and relative distance to this rule is what matters for survival. • Relative distance depends on prices and on rules of all traders. • Long-run heterogeneity is generic and leads to persistent price fluctuations. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Framework and Findings • K Short-lived assets • I traders with general investment rules (endogenous, CRRA included) • Sequential trade in discrete time (Random Dynamical System) • No perfect foresight on prices (markets are not dynamically complete) We show that: • Expected log-growth rate of wealth determines fitness. • A never vanishing rule exists (S-rule). It is log-optimal and relative distance to this rule is what matters for survival. • Relative distance depends on prices and on rules of all traders. • Long-run heterogeneity is generic and leads to persistent price fluctuations. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Framework and Findings • K Short-lived assets • I traders with general investment rules (endogenous, CRRA included) • Sequential trade in discrete time (Random Dynamical System) • No perfect foresight on prices (markets are not dynamically complete) We show that: • Expected log-growth rate of wealth determines fitness. • A never vanishing rule exists (S-rule). It is log-optimal and relative distance to this rule is what matters for survival. • Relative distance depends on prices and on rules of all traders. • Long-run heterogeneity is generic and leads to persistent price fluctuations. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Framework and Findings • K Short-lived assets • I traders with general investment rules (endogenous, CRRA included) • Sequential trade in discrete time (Random Dynamical System) • No perfect foresight on prices (markets are not dynamically complete) We show that: • Expected log-growth rate of wealth determines fitness. • A never vanishing rule exists (S-rule). It is log-optimal and relative distance to this rule is what matters for survival. • Relative distance depends on prices and on rules of all traders. • Long-run heterogeneity is generic and leads to persistent price fluctuations. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Framework and Findings • K Short-lived assets • I traders with general investment rules (endogenous, CRRA included) • Sequential trade in discrete time (Random Dynamical System) • No perfect foresight on prices (markets are not dynamically complete) We show that: • Expected log-growth rate of wealth determines fitness. • A never vanishing rule exists (S-rule). It is log-optimal and relative distance to this rule is what matters for survival. • Relative distance depends on prices and on rules of all traders. • Long-run heterogeneity is generic and leads to persistent price fluctuations. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Framework and Findings • K Short-lived assets • I traders with general investment rules (endogenous, CRRA included) • Sequential trade in discrete time (Random Dynamical System) • No perfect foresight on prices (markets are not dynamically complete) We show that: • Expected log-growth rate of wealth determines fitness. • A never vanishing rule exists (S-rule). It is log-optimal and relative distance to this rule is what matters for survival. • Relative distance depends on prices and on rules of all traders. • Long-run heterogeneity is generic and leads to persistent price fluctuations. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Assets Discrete time. At each t ∈ Z, S states of the world {1, . . . , S }, σ = {..., s0 , . . . , st , . . .} ∈ Σ, σt history till t. (Σ, F , ρ) is a probability space with ρ ergodic. Benchmark: ρ generated by i.i.d. Bernoulli trials with π. Repeated exchange of K ≤ S short-lived assets in exogenous unitary supply. Trade starts in t = 0 and Pk,t is price of asset k at time t. Dk (σ) is measurable w.r.t. F0 and asset k pays Dk,t (σ) = Dk (θ t σ) units of the numeráire good at time t. Benchmark: Dk (σ) = Dk,s1 is the dividend matrix. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Assets Discrete time. At each t ∈ Z, S states of the world {1, . . . , S }, σ = {..., s0 , . . . , st , . . .} ∈ Σ, σt history till t. (Σ, F , ρ) is a probability space with ρ ergodic. Benchmark: ρ generated by i.i.d. Bernoulli trials with π. Repeated exchange of K ≤ S short-lived assets in exogenous unitary supply. Trade starts in t = 0 and Pk,t is price of asset k at time t. Dk (σ) is measurable w.r.t. F0 and asset k pays Dk,t (σ) = Dk (θ t σ) units of the numeráire good at time t. Benchmark: Dk (σ) = Dk,s1 is the dividend matrix. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Assets Discrete time. At each t ∈ Z, S states of the world {1, . . . , S }, σ = {..., s0 , . . . , st , . . .} ∈ Σ, σt history till t. (Σ, F , ρ) is a probability space with ρ ergodic. Benchmark: ρ generated by i.i.d. Bernoulli trials with π. Repeated exchange of K ≤ S short-lived assets in exogenous unitary supply. Trade starts in t = 0 and Pk,t is price of asset k at time t. Dk (σ) is measurable w.r.t. F0 and asset k pays Dk,t (σ) = Dk (θ t σ) units of the numeráire good at time t. Benchmark: Dk (σ) = Dk,s1 is the dividend matrix. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Prices and Wealth Dynamics At time t agent i ∈ I invests on asset k a fraction αik,t of his wealth Wti and consumes a fraction 1 − δti . Intertemporal budget constraint gives wealth dynamics (∑ αik,t +1 + 1 − δt )Wti+1 k =∑ k where αik,t Wti Dk,t +1 Pk,t ∑ αik,t = δti . k Prices Pt are fixed by Walrasian market clearing (implicit equation) 1= ∑ i αik,t Wti ⇔ Pk,t = Pk,t ∑ αik,t Wti . i Note: Dividends, wealth, and prices can be normalized by total dividends in each period, {W , P, D } → {w , p, d }. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Prices and Wealth Dynamics At time t agent i ∈ I invests on asset k a fraction αik,t of his wealth Wti and consumes a fraction 1 − δti . Intertemporal budget constraint gives wealth dynamics (∑ αik,t +1 + 1 − δt )Wti+1 k =∑ k where αik,t Wti Dk,t +1 Pk,t ∑ αik,t = δti . k Prices Pt are fixed by Walrasian market clearing (implicit equation) 1= ∑ i αik,t Wti ⇔ Pk,t = Pk,t ∑ αik,t Wti . i Note: Dividends, wealth, and prices can be normalized by total dividends in each period, {W , P, D } → {w , p, d }. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Prices and Wealth Dynamics At time t agent i ∈ I invests on asset k a fraction αik,t of his wealth Wti and consumes a fraction 1 − δti . Intertemporal budget constraint gives wealth dynamics (∑ αik,t +1 + 1 − δt )Wti+1 k =∑ k where αik,t Wti Dk,t +1 Pk,t ∑ αik,t = δti . k Prices Pt are fixed by Walrasian market clearing (implicit equation) 1= ∑ i αik,t Wti ⇔ Pk,t = Pk,t ∑ αik,t Wti . i Note: Dividends, wealth, and prices can be normalized by total dividends in each period, {W , P, D } → {w , p, d }. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Prices and Wealth Dynamics At time t agent i ∈ I invests on asset k a fraction αik,t of his wealth Wti and consumes a fraction 1 − δti . Intertemporal budget constraint gives wealth dynamics (∑ αik,t +1 + 1 − δt )Wti+1 k =∑ k where αik,t Wti Dk,t +1 Pk,t ∑ αik,t = δti . k Prices Pt are fixed by Walrasian market clearing (implicit equation) 1= ∑ i αik,t Wti ⇔ Pk,t = Pk,t ∑ αik,t Wti . i Note: Dividends, wealth, and prices can be normalized by total dividends in each period, {W , P, D } → {w , p, d }. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Endogenous Investment Rules We name (αit , δi ) the investment rule of trader i and assume Assumption Investment rules are time-independent function of current and past prices αk,t = αk (p ) k = 1, . . . , K , where p = (pt , pt −1 , . . .). P1 Each agent invests a positive amount of wealth, or ∑K k =1 αk (p ) = δt ∈ (0, 1]; P2 Portfolios are maximally diversified, or ∑K k =1 αk (p )Dk ( σ ) /pk > 0 a.s.. Benchmark: myopic CRRA with beliefs π i and risk-preferences γi Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Endogenous Investment Rules We name (αit , δi ) the investment rule of trader i and assume Assumption Investment rules are time-independent function of current and past prices αk,t = αk (p ) k = 1, . . . , K , where p = (pt , pt −1 , . . .). P1 Each agent invests a positive amount of wealth, or ∑K k =1 αk (p ) = δt ∈ (0, 1]; P2 Portfolios are maximally diversified, or ∑K k =1 αk (p )Dk ( σ ) /pk > 0 a.s.. Benchmark: myopic CRRA with beliefs π i and risk-preferences γi Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Endogenous Investment Rules We name (αit , δi ) the investment rule of trader i and assume Assumption Investment rules are time-independent function of current and past prices αk,t = αk (p ) k = 1, . . . , K , where p = (pt , pt −1 , . . .). P1 Each agent invests a positive amount of wealth, or ∑K k =1 αk (p ) = δt ∈ (0, 1]; P2 Portfolios are maximally diversified, or ∑K k =1 αk (p )Dk ( σ ) /pk > 0 a.s.. Benchmark: myopic CRRA with beliefs π i and risk-preferences γi Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Endogenous Investment Rules We name (αit , δi ) the investment rule of trader i and assume Assumption Investment rules are time-independent function of current and past prices αk,t = αk (p ) k = 1, . . . , K , where p = (pt , pt −1 , . . .). P1 Each agent invests a positive amount of wealth, or ∑K k =1 αk (p ) = δt ∈ (0, 1]; P2 Portfolios are maximally diversified, or ∑K k =1 αk (p )Dk ( σ ) /pk > 0 a.s.. Benchmark: myopic CRRA with beliefs π i and risk-preferences γi Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Endogenous Investment Rules We name (αit , δi ) the investment rule of trader i and assume Assumption Investment rules are time-independent function of current and past prices αk,t = αk (p ) k = 1, . . . , K , where p = (pt , pt −1 , . . .). P1 Each agent invests a positive amount of wealth, or ∑K k =1 αk (p ) = δt ∈ (0, 1]; P2 Portfolios are maximally diversified, or ∑K k =1 αk (p )Dk ( σ ) /pk > 0 a.s.. Benchmark: myopic CRRA with beliefs π i and risk-preferences γi Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Market Dynamics is (locally) well defined Given an initial condition (w0 , p0 ) we want to study (wt , pt )(σt ) = M(σt ) ◦ . . . ◦ M(σ2 ) ◦ M(σ1 )(w0 , p0 ). Proposition Let x = (w , p ) a state and assume further that all rules i ∈ {1, . . . , I } are continuously differentiable in a neighborhood of p, αi ∈ C 1 (p ). If H is non-singular, then there exists a neighborhood X of x where prices are positive the dynamics is locally well-defined. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Market Dynamics is (locally) well defined Given an initial condition (w0 , p0 ) we want to study (wt , pt )(σt ) = M(σt ) ◦ . . . ◦ M(σ2 ) ◦ M(σ1 )(w0 , p0 ). Proposition Let x = (w , p ) a state and assume further that all rules i ∈ {1, . . . , I } are continuously differentiable in a neighborhood of p, αi ∈ C 1 (p ). If H is non-singular, then there exists a neighborhood X of x where prices are positive the dynamics is locally well-defined. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Market Dynamics is (locally) well defined Given an initial condition (w0 , p0 ) we want to study (wt , pt )(σt ) = M(σt ) ◦ . . . ◦ M(σ2 ) ◦ M(σ1 )(w0 , p0 ). Proposition Let x = (w , p ) a state and assume further that all rules i ∈ {1, . . . , I } are continuously differentiable in a neighborhood of p, αi ∈ C 1 (p ). If H is non-singular, then there exists a neighborhood X of x where prices are positive the dynamics is locally well-defined. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Market Selection Equilibria Representative agent limit Focus on market states x where one or a group of traders gain all the wealth and (normalized) asset prices are positive and constant: Market Selection Equilibria (MSE). Definition The state x ∗ = (w ∗ , p ∗ ) is a Market Selection Equilibrium if for almost all σ ∈ Σ it holds (w ∗ , p ∗ ) = M(σ1 )(w ∗ , p ∗ ) Note: At a Market Selection Equilibrium where i dominates w i∗ = 1 , w j∗ = 0 for all j 6= i , and p ∗ = αi (p ∗ ) . (1) Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Market Selection Equilibria Representative agent limit Focus on market states x where one or a group of traders gain all the wealth and (normalized) asset prices are positive and constant: Market Selection Equilibria (MSE). Definition The state x ∗ = (w ∗ , p ∗ ) is a Market Selection Equilibrium if for almost all σ ∈ Σ it holds (w ∗ , p ∗ ) = M(σ1 )(w ∗ , p ∗ ) Note: At a Market Selection Equilibrium where i dominates w i∗ = 1 , w j∗ = 0 for all j 6= i , and p ∗ = αi (p ∗ ) . (1) Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Market Selection Equilibria Representative agent limit Focus on market states x where one or a group of traders gain all the wealth and (normalized) asset prices are positive and constant: Market Selection Equilibria (MSE). Definition The state x ∗ = (w ∗ , p ∗ ) is a Market Selection Equilibrium if for almost all σ ∈ Σ it holds (w ∗ , p ∗ ) = M(σ1 )(w ∗ , p ∗ ) Note: At a Market Selection Equilibrium where i dominates w i∗ = 1 , w j∗ = 0 for all j 6= i , and p ∗ = αi (p ∗ ) . (1) Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Market Selection Equilibria Representative agent limit Focus on market states x where one or a group of traders gain all the wealth and (normalized) asset prices are positive and constant: Market Selection Equilibria (MSE). Definition The state x ∗ = (w ∗ , p ∗ ) is a Market Selection Equilibrium if for almost all σ ∈ Σ it holds (w ∗ , p ∗ ) = M(σ1 )(w ∗ , p ∗ ) Note: At a Market Selection Equilibrium where i dominates w i∗ = 1 , w j∗ = 0 for all j 6= i , and p ∗ = αi (p ∗ ) . (1) Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Local Stability and Expected Growth Rates Given ρ and d, the expected log-growth rate of trader j at x = (w , p ) is j µ (p ) = Z Σ d ρ(σ) log ∑ K αjk (p ) dk ( σ ) pk Proposition The MSE x ∗ = (w ∗ , p ∗ ) where i dominates, w i ∗ = 1 and p ∗ = αi (p ∗ ), is a) asimptotically stable if every j 6= i has negative expected log-growth rate at x ∗ , i.e. µj (p ∗ ) < 0 ; b) unstable if there exists j 6= i with positive expected log-growth rate at x ∗ , i.e. µj (p ∗ ) > 0 . Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Local Stability and Expected Growth Rates Given ρ and d, the expected log-growth rate of trader j at x = (w , p ) is j µ (p ) = Z Σ d ρ(σ) log ∑ K αjk (p ) dk ( σ ) pk Proposition The MSE x ∗ = (w ∗ , p ∗ ) where i dominates, w i ∗ = 1 and p ∗ = αi (p ∗ ), is a) asimptotically stable if every j 6= i has negative expected log-growth rate at x ∗ , i.e. µj (p ∗ ) < 0 ; b) unstable if there exists j 6= i with positive expected log-growth rate at x ∗ , i.e. µj (p ∗ ) > 0 . Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Local Stability and Expected Growth Rates Given ρ and d, the expected log-growth rate of trader j at x = (w , p ) is j µ (p ) = Z Σ d ρ(σ) log ∑ K αjk (p ) dk ( σ ) pk Proposition The MSE x ∗ = (w ∗ , p ∗ ) where i dominates, w i ∗ = 1 and p ∗ = αi (p ∗ ), is a) asimptotically stable if every j 6= i has negative expected log-growth rate at x ∗ , i.e. µj (p ∗ ) < 0 ; b) unstable if there exists j 6= i with positive expected log-growth rate at x ∗ , i.e. µj (p ∗ ) > 0 . Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion The S-rule A price dependent generalization of the Kelly rule We define the S-rule as the rules that maximizes the expected log-growth rate for all possible prices (log-optimality). Theorem On the set of p ∈ ∆K + for which there are no arbitrages the S-rule α? (p ) := argmax {µα (p )} α∈A0 is a well defined function of p. Moreover α? (p ) is of class C 1 , K ? ? satisfies R ∑k =1 αk (p ) = 1, and α (p ) = p if and only if pk = Σ d ρ(σ)dk (σ) for every k = 1, . . . , K . Note: if arbitrages, the S-rule is unbounded. (2) Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion The S-rule A price dependent generalization of the Kelly rule We define the S-rule as the rules that maximizes the expected log-growth rate for all possible prices (log-optimality). Theorem On the set of p ∈ ∆K + for which there are no arbitrages the S-rule α? (p ) := argmax {µα (p )} α∈A0 is a well defined function of p. Moreover α? (p ) is of class C 1 , K ? ? satisfies R ∑k =1 αk (p ) = 1, and α (p ) = p if and only if pk = Σ d ρ(σ)dk (σ) for every k = 1, . . . , K . Note: if arbitrages, the S-rule is unbounded. (2) Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion The S-rule A price dependent generalization of the Kelly rule We define the S-rule as the rules that maximizes the expected log-growth rate for all possible prices (log-optimality). Theorem On the set of p ∈ ∆K + for which there are no arbitrages the S-rule α? (p ) := argmax {µα (p )} α∈A0 is a well defined function of p. Moreover α? (p ) is of class C 1 , K ? ? satisfies R ∑k =1 αk (p ) = 1, and α (p ) = p if and only if pk = Σ d ρ(σ)dk (σ) for every k = 1, . . . , K . Note: if arbitrages, the S-rule is unbounded. (2) Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Evolutionary stability of the S-rule Theorem Consider a set of rules E with α? ∈ E . All MSE x ∗ = (w ∗ , p ∗ ) where α? vanishes are unstable. Moreover, there exists at least one stable MSE in Rwhich α? survives and sets long-run asset prices are equal to p ∗ = Σ d ρ(σ)d (σ). Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Evolutionary stability of the S-rule Theorem Consider a set of rules E with α? ∈ E . All MSE x ∗ = (w ∗ , p ∗ ) where α? vanishes are unstable. Moreover, there exists at least one stable MSE in Rwhich α? survives and sets long-run asset prices are equal to p ∗ = Σ d ρ(σ)d (σ). Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion 2 diagonal assets, 2 CRRA myopic agents, no consumption In every t trader i = 1, 2 with (π i , γi ) uses the rule αi that solves 1− γi i w α i ( pt ) : = argmax ∑ πsi t +1 1t +−1 γi i i α (pt )+α (pt )=1 st +1 =1,2 1 2 Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion 2 diagonal assets, 2 CRRA myopic agents, no consumption 1 0.8 E2 α(p) 0.6 0.4 E1 0.2 0 γ=4, πe=0.3 γ=0.25, πe=0.6 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 p 0.8 1 Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Stability of log-rules Blume and Easley (1992) 1 0.8 E2 α(p) 0.6 E1 0.4 0.2 0 γ=1,πe=0.4 γ=1,πe=0.7 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 p Note: µ 2 ( E1 ) = − µ 1 ( E 2 ) 0.8 1 Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Stability of log-rules Blume and Easley (1992) 1 0.8 U2 0.6 α(p) Iπ(α2) Iπ(α1) 0.4 S1 0.2 0 S-rule γ=1,πe=0.4 γ=1,πe=0.7 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 p Note: µ 2 ( E1 ) = I π ( α 1 ) − I π ( α 2 ) = − µ 1 ( E2 ) 1 Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Coexistence of Stable Market Selection Equilibria 1 0.8 S-rule γ=1,πe=0.25 e γ=0.5,π =0.65 S2 α(p) 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 S1 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 p 0.8 1 Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Coexistence of Unstable Market Selection Equilibria 1 0.8 U2 α(p) 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 U1 0 0.2 S-rule γ=2,πe=0.25 γ=1,πe=0.65 0.4 0.6 p 0.8 1 Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Coexistence of Unstable Market Selection Equilibria 1 Wealth share 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 w1 w2 50 100 150 200 250 Time 300 350 400 450 500 Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Coexistence of Unstable Market Selection Equilibria 0.8 0.7 Price 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 p1 0.2 p2 50 100 150 200 250 Time 300 350 400 450 500 Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Vanishing of the informed trader? Blume and Easley (1992) 0.6 0.6 α(p) 1 0.8 α(p) 1 0.8 0.4 0.4 S-rule γ=1, πe=0.6 γ=0.2, πe=0.5 0.2 0 0 0.2 S-rule γ=1, πe=0.6 γ=2, πe=0.5 0.2 0.4 0.6 p 0.8 1 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 p Figure : Dominance of the uninformed trader (left panel). Long-run coexistence of uninformed and informed traders (right panel). In both examples D1 = 2, D2 = 1, and π = (0.5, 0.5). 1 Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Generalized Kelly Rule and S-rule Amir et al (2005) JME, Evstigneev et al (2009) 1 S-rule α1(p) α2(p) α3(p) 0.8 0.6 α(p) E1 E3 0.4 0.2 E2 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 p Figure : d1 = (1/2 , 0), d2 = (1/2 , 1), and π = (2/3, 1/3). Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Generalized Kelly Rule vs S-rule Consider a two-asset market with • two traders trading according to αGKR and αS respectively, • a “noise” trader investing according to a random constant rule in α0 ∈ (0, 1), • if the wealth of the noise trader is small, w 0 < 0.05, he is replaced by a new noisy trader with random wealth in (0.05, 01) and random strategy in (0, 1). Conclusion Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Generalized Kelly Rule vs S-rule 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 wk/ws quadratic approx. 0 500 100015002000250030003500400045005000 t 0.3 0.7 Figure : D = , π1 = 0.5, π2 = 0.5 0.7 0.3 Conclusion Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Conclusions • We have established sufficient conditions for local stability and instability of representative agent equilibria (expected log-growth rates rule). • The S-rule (highest expected log-growth rate for all prices) never vanishes and always sets prices. It is log-optimal and differs from the generalized Kelly rule. • Distance to S-rule is what matters, it depends on prices. • Coexistence of stable and unstable equilibria is possible and generic. The latter leads to persistent prices and wealth fluctuations. Heterogeneity is not transient. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Conclusions • We have established sufficient conditions for local stability and instability of representative agent equilibria (expected log-growth rates rule). • The S-rule (highest expected log-growth rate for all prices) never vanishes and always sets prices. It is log-optimal and differs from the generalized Kelly rule. • Distance to S-rule is what matters, it depends on prices. • Coexistence of stable and unstable equilibria is possible and generic. The latter leads to persistent prices and wealth fluctuations. Heterogeneity is not transient. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Conclusions • We have established sufficient conditions for local stability and instability of representative agent equilibria (expected log-growth rates rule). • The S-rule (highest expected log-growth rate for all prices) never vanishes and always sets prices. It is log-optimal and differs from the generalized Kelly rule. • Distance to S-rule is what matters, it depends on prices. • Coexistence of stable and unstable equilibria is possible and generic. The latter leads to persistent prices and wealth fluctuations. Heterogeneity is not transient. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Conclusions • We have established sufficient conditions for local stability and instability of representative agent equilibria (expected log-growth rates rule). • The S-rule (highest expected log-growth rate for all prices) never vanishes and always sets prices. It is log-optimal and differs from the generalized Kelly rule. • Distance to S-rule is what matters, it depends on prices. • Coexistence of stable and unstable equilibria is possible and generic. The latter leads to persistent prices and wealth fluctuations. Heterogeneity is not transient. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Conclusions • We have established sufficient conditions for local stability and instability of representative agent equilibria (expected log-growth rates rule). • The S-rule (highest expected log-growth rate for all prices) never vanishes and always sets prices. It is log-optimal and differs from the generalized Kelly rule. • Distance to S-rule is what matters, it depends on prices. • Coexistence of stable and unstable equilibria is possible and generic. The latter leads to persistent prices and wealth fluctuations. Heterogeneity is not transient. Introduction The Model Formal Results Examples Conclusion Conclusions • We have established sufficient conditions for local stability and instability of representative agent equilibria (expected log-growth rates rule). • The S-rule (highest expected log-growth rate for all prices) never vanishes and always sets prices. It is log-optimal and differs from the generalized Kelly rule. • Distance to S-rule is what matters, it depends on prices. • Coexistence of stable and unstable equilibria is possible and generic. The latter leads to persistent prices and wealth fluctuations. Heterogeneity is not transient. Introduction The Model Thank You! Formal Results Examples Conclusion
© Copyright 2024 Paperzz