Nessun titolo diapositiva

Gruppo CNR di economia internazionale
Torino, 22-23 Febbraio 2007
“The decline in Italian productivity: new
econometric evidence” by S. Fachin & A. Gavosto
Discussion by Carlo Altomonte (Università Bocconi)
The main contributions of the paper
• The paper address the source of the productivity slowdown in Italy
through panel cointegration methods
• Three relevant contributions:
1. The use of panel cointegration methods allows to relax the
assumption of CRS and perfect competition in factor markets,
typical of the growth accounting approach
2. The use of a flexible form for the production function (Kmenta
linearisation of the CES) allows to discuss the relevance of the
labour/capital elasticity of substitution
3. The results are comparable with other, more traditional studies, as in
their Figure 6, and thus more prone to a generalisation
1. Panel cointegration methods - I
• The authors start from the labour productivity equation
• They assume that technical progress pit can be decomposed as:
pit = q t + i i
and thus they can write:
where the industry-specific technological progress is incorporated in a’
• But if the shock is not entirely separable (i.e. not every industry follows the same growth rate of
technological progress over time), then the term becomes:
pit = q t + ii + hit
and thus eit in (3) should incorporate the term hit, leading to an error term potentially correlated
with the input choices (simultaneity bias).
1. Panel cointegration methods - II
• They implicitly discuss this issue by estimating
• Here they assume that the term φ in (4) captures not only the trend in the technical progress but
also the effect of any other random shock.
• As a result, they have to impose an assumption on the distribution of these shocks: they are
(log) additive and generated by a symmetric distribution, so that qs = E(φs| t=s) and φ can be
estimated non-parametrically
• However, again they implicitly assume that the shocks are entirely separable across industries,
which in the panel structure is not likely
 openly discuss the issue of simultaneity bias
 elaborate more on the actual restrictiveness of the assumptions on q, and the potential
correlation of shocks across time/industries (e.g. by discussing the characteristics of the
VCov Matrix of their panel estimation)
2. Capital-labour elasticity of substitution
• Their equation for log labour productivity (2) does not impose a unitary K/L
elasticity of substitution r = 1 as in Cobb-Douglas
• And yet, they cannot reject but for one industry (Rubber) the null of r = 1,
although the confidence intervals of the point estimates are rather large
• This result mimics Balistreri, McDaniel and Wang (2003) for the US economy
(1947-1998, 28 industries), but the authors are still skeptical on r = 1
• Large confidence intervals are really caused by different underlying elasticity of
substitution, or by the model design ?
• One implication of aggregate equations like (2) is that, with r = 1, any
redistribution of inputs across plants (i.e. any linear combination of b’x) results in
the same aggregate output, which is not true: if firms are heterogeneous in
productivity levels and new inputs flow to the most productive firms, different
linear combinations would yield different results => “noise” in the estimates
• Here the assumption on the elasticity of substitution is relaxed, but a potential bias
from the aggregation problem persists => large confidence intervals could be due to
the aggregation bias, while r = 1 holds.
3. Relevance of the results
• If r = 1 (i.e. a Cobb-Douglas specification) cannot be excluded, what do we learn
from the Kmenta specification ? Would the results dramatically change using a
Cobb-Douglas ? And a translog ?
• The broad dynamics of TFP recovered through the panel cointegration are similar
to standard growth accounting analyses, but the order of magnitude is rather
different: more than double of the growth rate in the period 1986-90 and almost a
third in 1991-95:
•
Is this due to the fact that TFP estimates in this paper are valid only for the
long-run ?
•
If this is the case, how big is the error incurred in trying to use these estimates
in order to explain the business cycle ?
•
If TFP estimates are ok also for the short run, how to explain the much higher
volatility of the business cycle implied by these TFP figures ?